Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-c47g7 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-16T21:40:24.165Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Explaining Party Positions on Decentralization

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  28 August 2013

Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Debates about decentralization raise cultural questions of identity and economic questions of redistribution and efficiency. Therefore the preferences of statewide parties regarding decentralization are related to their positions on the economic and cultural ideological dimensions. A statistical analysis using data from thirty-one countries confirms this: parties on the economic right are more supportive of decentralization than parties on the economic left, while culturally liberal parties favour decentralization more than culturally conservative parties. However, country context – specifically the degree of regional self-rule, the extent of regional economic disparity and the ideology of regionalist parties – determines whether and how decentralization is linked to the two dimensions. These findings have implications for our understanding of the politics of decentralization by showing how ideology, rooted in a specific country context, shapes the ‘mindset’ of agents responsible for determining the territorial distribution of power.

Type
Articles
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BYCreative Common License - NCCreative Common License - SA
The online version of this article is published within an Open Access environment subject to the conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial- ShareAlike licence . The written permission of Cambridge University Press must be obtained for commercial re-use
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2013

In recent decades, established democracies have transferred political power away from the national level. While much attention has been paid to supranational (particularly European) integration, in many states the decentralization of governance is an equally important phenomenon: over the past fifty years, the migration of authority to the regional level has been an unmistakable trend across developed countries that has led to important processes of constitutional reform.Footnote 1 As Marks et al. note, ‘Not every country has become regionalized, but where we see reform over time, it is in the direction of greater, not less, regional authority.’Footnote 2

Structural approaches to decentralization that privilege social, economic and historical factors can explain pressures to establish ‘congruence’ between the state and society. But given their focus on deeply rooted factors, these approaches overlook the role of political agency and thus cannot account for the timing, rhythm and scope of territorial reforms that transfer authority to regions.Footnote 3 Structural perspectives are valuable insofar as they set the stage for examining the role of partisan actors who incarnate social and territorial cleavages and take the decision to decentralize power and whose preferences are therefore central to understanding the dynamics of decentralization. Decentralization has in fact become an important issue of political debate and electoral competition: while some statewide political parties have endorsed the transfer of authority to regional governments, others have opposed it. What lies behind parties’ positions on this issue?

This question has so far received scant attention in the literature, in contrast to party positioning on European integration, which has been studied extensively.Footnote 4 So far, a cross-national analysis exists only for the salience of decentralization in Britain, Italy and FranceFootnote 5 ; another studyFootnote 6 considers Spain's Socialist and Conservative parties’ positions – and the importance they assign to the regionalist issue – during regional and state elections.

Understanding the positions of statewide parties on decentralization is important, since decentralization touches the core of politics: the power of the state to make and execute laws. However the study of multilevel governance has too often been a ‘party-free’ area of inquiry that has mainly studied the vertical and horizontal interactions of actors in the policy process.Footnote 7 Similarly, neoclassical approaches to the distribution of authority have treated decentralization as a depoliticized question, which is reducible to the establishment of an optimal number of territorial jurisdictions.Footnote 8 Yet the evidence from recent processes of constitutional reforms in different countries such as Belgium, Germany, Italy, Spain or the United Kingdom shows that the territorial distribution of authority is deeply contested by political parties.

In this article, we focus on statewide parties. Since they usually form the core of national governments, they strongly influence when and how changes to the territorial distribution of authority are implemented.Footnote 9 This means that the positions of statewide parties on jurisdictional questions are central to understanding political outcomes on decentralization. Thus as Marks and Hooghe argue, it is important to ‘place politics – contestation about the good society – at the centre of a theory of authority allocation’.Footnote 10

We ask what explains the positions of statewide parties on decentralization. Our central argument is that views on this issue are related to preferences on the two core ideological dimensions of party competition: the economy and culture.Footnote 11 This is because decentralization is a jurisdictional question related to the nature of governance that, following Hooghe and Marks's post-functionalist theory of integration, raises questions of efficiency and redistribution on the one hand, and questions of identity on the other.Footnote 12

Specifically, we argue that parties on the economic right should favour decentralization because it can improve the efficient production of public goods, while parties on the economic left should oppose decentralization because it hinders efforts to redistribute wealth. In contrast, culturally liberal parties should support decentralization because it recognizes diversity and local decision-making, while culturally conservative parties should be against decentralization because it erodes national unity and territorial integrity. For some parties, the two dimensions are consistent in determining positions on decentralization; for others, they may lead to internal ideological tensions. To understand the ideological foundations of a party's position on decentralization, we thus need to know its views on both key dimensions of political conflict. In this, party positions on decentralization are similar to views on European integration.Footnote 13

We test this claim using data for thirty-one countries from the Benoit and Laver expert survey supplemented with party- and country-level data.Footnote 14 We find strong support for our argument that, in general, decentralization taps into the logics of efficiency and redistribution on the one hand and identity on the other: overall, positions on the issue are clearly related to both the economic and cultural dimensions.

However we also argue that this general association should differ across countries, because each country has different institutional, structural or strategic characteristics that influence whether decentralization is seen primarily through an economic or a cultural lens. While questions of territorial authority always have the potential to address the logics of efficiency, redistribution and identity, how these logics shape actual party positions should therefore depend on country context. We suggest that decentralization positions are more influenced by economic ideology when regional self-rule and economic disparity are high, and our analyses confirm this. We also find evidence that the nature of ideological competition from regionalist parties can affect whether (and which) statewide parties support or oppose decentralization. Finally, the relationship of decentralization to the cultural dimension appears to depend little on country context.

This article is structured as follows. We start by elaborating our theoretical framework and presenting our expectations concerning party positions on decentralization and the effects of ideological and contextual factors. We then present the data and the statistical model before describing our results. We conclude by drawing implications for future research on the determinants of party positions on decentralization and of territorial reform processes.

Decentralization and Ideological Dimensions

Our argument that the positions taken by statewide parties on the issue of decentralization are related to the core ideological dimensions of competition builds on the post-functionalist theory of integration developed by Hooghe and Marks, which transcends the notion that the allocation of authority is an efficiency-oriented outcome driven by functional pressures and posits instead that it is a deeply political choice conditioned by domestic (non-economic) conflicts.Footnote 15 They note that ‘[g]overnance has two entirely different purposes’: the first is to supply public goods, for example by increasing efficiency and redistributing resources; the second is to express a sense of identity with a specific territorial political community.

This distinction highlights the notion that decentralization is a multidimensional concept.Footnote 16 The first goal of governance relates to material values; it is expressed through the economic dimension of party competition and implies a distributional logic of contestation. There are three institutional components of territorial autonomy that touch on questions of efficiency and redistribution: (1) legislative autonomy on an exclusive, concurrent or shared basis; (2) control over administrative resources such as personnel and agencies and (3) control over financial resources, either in the form of central transfers or ‘own’ revenues.Footnote 17

The second goal of governance relates to ‘pre-material’ values; it is expressed through the cultural dimension and implies an identity-based logic of contestation.Footnote 18 In practice, this cultural component of decentralization may be expressed through normative debates surrounding, for example, the definition of the political community or the recognition of national pluralism through symbolic gestures or asymmetric territorial autonomy. Decentralization is therefore a multifaceted process that can address questions of efficiency and redistribution linked to economic preferences as well as questions of identity linked to cultural preferences. We elaborate on this below.

Decentralization and the Economic Dimension

The two economic questions related to decentralization are thus: (1) how does it affect the efficiency of governance and (2) how does it affect the distribution of wealth and welfare? Those on the economic right often welcome decentralized decision making, as it can promote a more efficient form of government. In one view, policy making should be decentralized as far as is necessary for the production of public goods to reflect local preferences.Footnote 19 A related argument states that decentralized forms of government are conducive to ‘market-preserving federalism’Footnote 20 since they create economic competition between jurisdictions and limit the central government's ability to encroach on the market. This line of reasoning maintains that such features have positive effects on economic growth. These arguments resonate with right-wing economic ideology, as they suggest that minimizing the writ of central government is necessary to ensure efficiency in policy making and economic prosperity. They reflect the thinking of parties on the economic right, such as the German Liberal party and the US Republican party, which have consistently sought to restore or increase the autonomy of the federal states.

Because decentralization removes power from the central government, it may also hinder the extent to which a country can undertake redistribution between its citizens. As a result, decentralization may prevent the implementation of key policy goals of the economic left: inter-territorial and individual equality. As Wildavsky puts it, ‘federalism means inequality’Footnote 21 : decentralization can generate regional economic disparities in a variety of outcomes – such as economic growth, educational attainment or welfare state provision – because it limits the central government's ability to redistribute wealth and provide universal public services.Footnote 22 Just as the logic of efficiency means that the economic right may be in favour of decentralization, the logic of redistribution means that parties on the economic left, such as the Australian or British Labour parties, may oppose it.Footnote 23 Specifically, our resulting hypothesis is:

Hypothesis 1: The more economically right wing a party is, the more it will support decentralization.

Decentralization and the Cultural Dimension

The main cultural question related to decentralization is: how does it reflect the distribution of territorial identities and political communities across a country? Culturally liberal parties, including for instance most ecological parties, are likely to favour decentralization for two reasons. First, culturally liberal parties are often committed to fostering multiculturalism and defending political minorities, and decentralization allows a country's institutions to coincide with the distinct identities and aspirations of its different communities. In this, cultural liberals may be driven by their opposition to the positions of culturally conservative parties.Footnote 24 Secondly, the support of culturally liberal parties may also stem from post-materialist values; decentralization is seen as a way to improve the quality of democracy by enhancing civic participation, fostering political deliberation and augmenting the accountability of decision makers.Footnote 25 As Marks et al. note, the process of regionalization in the 1970s coincided with the cultural shift toward post-materialism, which challenged conventional norms such as ‘centralized decision-making’.Footnote 26

In contrast, culturally conservative parties, such as the Partido Popular in Spain or the Greater Romania Party, oppose the decentralization of power. Cultural conservatism implies a commitment to preserving the existing order on political, social and cultural issues. Parties with such views generally praise traditional values such as ‘the nation’, identify with a single national political community and regard the recognition of cultural diversity as a source of erosion of the integrity of the national community and democratic citizenship. They also emphasize the hierarchical nature of political authority and are thus suspicious of any mass involvement in (local) politics that may threaten political stability and elite-based decision making. In sum, our expectation is that culturally liberal parties will support decentralization, while culturally conservative parties will oppose it. More specifically, our hypothesis is:

Hypothesis 2: The more culturally liberal a party is, the more it will support decentralization.

Decentralization and Contextual Factors

The way in which decentralization raises questions of efficiency, redistribution and identity will vary across countries as a function of their social and territorial divisions, institutional setting and the structure of their political competition. Such factors will influence the sensitivity of individual parties to wealth creation and distribution as well as to identity claims, and thus shape how they interpret and position themselves on the issue of decentralization and determine how decentralization is linked to the economic or cultural dimension. Here we examine the effects of four potentially important differences between countries: the degree of self-rule, the degree of regional economic disparity, the presence of regionally based ethnic groups and the ideology of regionalist parties.

Degree of Regional Self-Rule

How the economic dimension determines party positions on decentralization may depend on the existing degree of regional self-rule. This is because the existing level of self-rule may affect whether the issue of decentralization is likely to raise questions of efficiency and redistribution. When a country has a high degree of regional self-rule, and when decentralization affects taxation powers and welfare functions, the issue may be seen largely through the lens of redistribution and efficiency, as was the case with Switzerland's 2001 fiscal equalization reforms or those of Germany in 2009. Economically right-wing parties endorse decentralization because they favour institutional changes that prevent the central government from imposing higher levels of taxation on richer regions and from interfering with regional governments’ economic policies. Economically left-wing parties oppose decentralization because they are critical of the effect of high levels of self-rule on the central government's ability to redistribute wealth and ensure uniform outcomes in social service provision. Thus our first contextual hypothesis is:

Hypothesis 3: The greater the level of regional self-rule, the stronger the association between the economic dimension and positions on decentralization.

Regional Economic Disparity

The influence of economic ideology on parties’ positioning may also depend on the degree of economic disparity between regions within a state. Economic production can be strongly regionalized, which can lead to substantial regional disparities in economic wealth.Footnote 27 For example, the success of wealthy powerhouses such as Baden-Württemberg, Catalonia, Lombardy and Rhône-Alpes contrasts with poorer regions of each country.Footnote 28 In countries with large economic disparities, decentralization raises questions of efficiency and redistribution. Economically strong regions may favour decentralization because it allows them to retain their wealth and their economic model, while weaker regions will plead for the redistribution of economic gains across the country.

We expect that in countries with such disparities, statewide parties will adopt positions on decentralization that reflect their attitudes toward wealth, redistribution and equality. Thus parties on the economic right are likely to welcome decentralization because it gives regions control over the resources necessary for encouraging growth – such as investment in human capital, communication and transport networksFootnote 29 – and because it is conducive to creating an optimal link between fiscal policy and the provision of public goods that reflects the ideal preference of the regional median voter.Footnote 30 Parties on the economic left will oppose decentralization, since they will support a tighter fiscal union that ensures redistribution from wealthy to poorer citizens and regions. For example, during Germany's reform of territorial financing in 2009, the Liberal and Christian Democratic parties supported decentralization to a greater extent than the sceptical Social Democratic party. Thus our second contextual hypothesis is:

Hypothesis 4: The greater the degree of regional economic disparity, the greater the association between the economic dimension and positions on decentralization.

Regionally Based Ethnic Groups

How decentralization links to the cultural dimension may depend on the presence of regionally based ethnic groups that display distinct cultural and political identities and articulate different policy preferences.Footnote 31 The presence of regionally based ethnic groups, such as the Scots in the UK, the Corsicans in France or the Basques in Spain, will enhance the appeal of the logic of identity. Thus decentralization may be an element of a broader ‘ethnicization’ of politics.Footnote 32 In such countries, decentralization deals mostly with the symbolic recognition of national pluralism and the establishment of structures of regional government that map onto national communities.

Statewide parties’ positions on decentralization depend on whether they support the aspirations of regionally based ethnic groups. Given our theoretical approach, we expect support for decentralization to be more closely linked to the cultural dimension. Culturally liberal parties will endorse decentralization because this may provide national minorities or stateless groups with group-based territorial rights, defuse conflict by ‘containing nationalism’Footnote 33 or decentralize political tensions.Footnote 34 In contrast, culturally conservative parties will be even more strongly opposed to decentralization, as recognizing and empowering regional groups may weaken national identity and the national community. Thus, our third contextual hypothesis is:

Hypothesis 5: Cultural liberalism is more strongly associated with support for decentralization when there is a regionally based ethnic group.

Regionalist Party Ideology

A final contextual factor is the ideology of regionalist parties. While such parties usually concentrate on the need for decentralization, they also adopt positions on the economic and cultural dimensions.Footnote 35 For example, the Scottish National Party (SNP) is traditionally on the economic left and culturally liberal, the Catalonian Convergencia i Unio (CiU) is relatively centrist in economic and cultural terms, and the Belgian Vlaams Belang is on the economic right and culturally conservative. Where they exist, regionalist parties may use their blackmail or coalition potential to persuade statewide parties to acknowledge and consider their demands for territorial autonomy, self-determination or independence.Footnote 36 Which parties are threatened by regionalist competitors will depend on each statewide party's economic and cultural policies and the area of the policy space it occupies.Footnote 37

Statewide parties may respond to this threat by strategically adopting positions on decentralization in order to maximize their share of the vote and to attain office, rather than out of ideological considerations.Footnote 38 A statewide party can respond to a threat from a regionalist party by adopting either an accommodative or adversarial strategy.Footnote 39 If it is directly threatened, a statewide party may adopt an accommodating strategy and take a pro-decentralization stance in order to challenge a regionalist party's ownership of the decentralization issue, recoup electoral losses and avoid losing future votes. If it is not directly threatened, but its statewide competitors are, it may adopt an adversarial strategy and take an anti-decentralization stance in order to distinguish itself from its statewide rival and raise the salience of decentralization, in the hope that regionalist parties continue to sap votes from its statewide rival. For example, if a regionalist party has a centre-left economic position, such as the Scottish and Welsh nationalists in the United Kingdom, then an economic left-wing statewide party would adopt an accommodative strategy, while an economically right-wing party would follow an adversarial strategy.Footnote 40 The opposite prediction would hold if the regionalist party were on the economic right. In essence, we thus argue that electoral strategies can overcome the associations between decentralization and the core ideological dimensions. Our next hypothesis is therefore:

Hypothesis 6: The closer a regionalist party's ideological position is to that of a statewide party, the more that statewide party will support decentralization.

Data and Model

Ideological Scales

To test our hypotheses, we need information on party positions on decentralization as well as on the economic and cultural dimensions. Our source of data in this article is the expert survey of party positions carried out by Benoit and Laver in 2002 and 2003.Footnote 41 This survey contains assessments of party ideology on economic and cultural matters as well as on decentralization. After excluding those countries not listed as fully ‘free’ by Freedom House in 2003Footnote 42 and four countries with missing values on key controls,Footnote 43 thirty-one countries remain in this dataset.Footnote 44 We present our results using this expert survey rather than the newer Hooghe et al. data, which also includes questions on these three issue areas, because the Hooghe et al. survey only covers EU countries.Footnote 45 We also ran all analyses and robustness checks using the Hooghe et al. data, and the results are consistent across these two datasets (details available from the authors).

As noted above, decentralization is a multifaceted process that may have various forms and meanings across countries; the term may refer either to different types of institutional change or different levels of governance (regional or local). For example, in multinational states such as Spain, decentralization includes both institutional and cultural components,Footnote 46 while in the United Kingdom the cultural component is less salient, at least for statewide parties. In homogeneous states such as Denmark, decentralization may simply mean the shift of administrative powers to regions or the transfer of expenditure powers to municipalities. This variation in the meaning of decentralization makes it difficult to obtain a single valid cross-national measure for the position of parties on decentralization. However, there is currently no better alternative measure of decentralization available.Footnote 47 This article aims to uncover differing interpretations of decentralization across countries by capturing the effects of the economic and cultural dimensions and contextual factors on party positioning.

In the Benoit and Laver survey, experts were asked to assess party positions on decentralization. Low values on this scale indicate that the party ‘opposes any decentralization of all administration and decision-making ‘ and high values indicate that the party ‘promotes decentralization of all administration and decision-making’.Footnote 48 A histogram and rug plot of party positions on decentralization are presented in Figure 1, which shows that non-regional parties differ substantially in their positions on this topic, though no such parties take particularly extreme views.

Fig. 1 Party positions on decentralization

Note: data from Benoit and Laver Reference Benoit and Laver2006. Countries included are listed in footnote 44; parties included are in Appendix 2.

To assess positions on the economic dimension, we use the public services versus taxes scale, in which low values mean that the party ‘promotes cutting public services to cut taxes’ and high values that it ‘promotes raising taxes to increase public services’.

Measuring the cultural dimension is less straightforward. In this article, we use party attitudes toward personal freedoms and traditional values. In the Benoit and Laver survey, this scale is called the ‘social policy’ dimension: low values signify that the party ‘opposes liberal policies on matters such as abortion, homosexuality and euthanasia’ and high values that it favours such policies.Footnote 49 This question only covers part of the issues that comprise the cultural dimension, as topics such as nationalism and immigration are not included.Footnote 50 To make sure that our results do not depend on how we measure the cultural dimension, we also ran all our analyses using the immigration or nationalism scale, where available, as well as with indices constructed by averaging the immigration/nationalism and social policy scales. Our results do not change when these alternative measures are used.

We model our dependent variable, decentralization, using linear regression. Since our data structure is best described as hierarchical (parties nested in countries), we run a multilevel model with country-level random intercepts. Crucially, setting up the model in this ways recognizes the potentially clustered nature of our observations while allowing us to include country-level controls and cross-level interaction effects. All models are run using the xtmixed command in Stata 11.Footnote 51

Contextual Factors

We argued above that the influence of the economic and cultural dimensions on decentralization positions may depend on a series of contextual factors. First, we measure the existing level of decentralization using the Marks et al. measure of self-rule, which is the extent to which sub-national units can run their own affairs independently of the central government.Footnote 52 We take the country-wide average for 2002–03, when the Benoit and Laver survey was carried out. Countries such as Belgium, Spain, Italy and Germany have high values on this variable, and countries such as the Baltic States, Bulgaria, Portugal and Slovenia have low values.

Secondly, we measure the regional disparity in economic prosperity using information on Nomenclature of Territorial Units for Statistics (NUTS)-2 regions for EU countriesFootnote 53 and on Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development-defined regions for all other countries.Footnote 54 For each country, we calculate the coefficient of variation (the standard deviation divided by the mean) of gross domestic product (GDP) per capita across all regions.Footnote 55 This variable captures the extent to which regional mean prosperity varies within a country.Footnote 56 Countries with notably high regional disparity include Belgium, Hungary, Romania, Slovakia and the United Kingdom; Australia, Japan and the Netherlands have low levels of inequality between regions.

Thirdly, we measure whether a country has a regionally based ethnic group using information provided in the Ethnic Power Relations dataset and its geographic supplement.Footnote 57 We code ethnopolitically relevant groups as regionally concentrated if they are either only or partly regionally based.Footnote 58 The resulting variable is 1 if the country has a regionally based ethnic group, and 0 if not.

Finally, we assess the extent to which regionalist parties take a stance on the statewide party's economic position. To measure this, we first classify parties as regionalist parties if they were given the equivalent party code in the Comparative Manifestos Project dataset or in the Hooghe et al. survey.Footnote 59 We then consolidate these codes given our own country-specific knowledge in order to remove statewide nationalist parties from this categorization. We then code the average position of regionalist parties as their mean position on each of the two ideological scales, weighted by their share of the vote in general elections.Footnote 60

Party-Level Controls

We include as controls three party-level variables that may strongly influence decentralization positions. First, parties that participate in government at the national level may be less likely to support decentralization: they have an incentive to maintain the status quo in the division of power between the different levels of governance in order to widen their room for manoeuvre. Devolving power to lower levels may also mean handing power to other parties that are sub-nationally strong.Footnote 61 We measure government participation at the time of the survey using information provided by Benoit and Laver directly.Footnote 62 We code parties as 1 if they were in government, 0 if not.

Secondly, parties may have a strategic incentive to take a position different to that of their competitors. In other words, the more the government (opposition) parties are in favour of decentralization, the more the opposition (government) parties will be against it. For example, this pattern was found in the rivalry between statewide parties in countries such as France and Greece, where Social Democratic parties favoured decentralization during their long spell in opposition to Conservative governing parties. We thus include a variable that measures the mean position of the government (for opposition parties) and of the opposition (for government parties), weighted by their vote share.

Finally, smaller parties may be more likely to support decentralization because they may want to ‘shake up the party system’ by taking a position in favour of change.Footnote 63 There is evidence that small parties are more likely to be Eurosceptic;Footnote 64 a similar pattern may exist for the decentralization issue. We measure party size using the most recent party vote share information provided in the Benoit and Laver dataset. The variable ranges from 0 to 1.

Country-Level Controls

We also include a series of country-level controls in all models. These include some of the contextual factors introduced above, namely the level of self-rule, the degree of regional economic disparity and the presence of regionally based ethnic groups. We also include as a control whether the party system includes a regionalist party, because the presence of such parties may polarize the positions of statewide parties, especially if the decentralization issue becomes very salient. Depending on the responses of statewide parties, we may see more positive or more negative stances on decentralization as a result. Though we are uncertain of the direction of a regionalist party's influence, this is nevertheless an important control variable.

Support for decentralization by statewide parties may also be greater in geographically and demographically large countries. A large country may have a greater heterogeneity of local conditions and voter preferences, and thus a greater need (and support) for locally tailored policies.Footnote 65 We coded the geographic size of a country (in km2) using the United Nations Demographic Yearbook.Footnote 66 The 2002 population of a country (in millions) is taken from Heston et al.Footnote 67 For both area and population, we use the natural logarithm of the raw values in our models.

Results

The results of our model are presented in Table 1. The dependent variable, which ranges from 1 to 20, is coded so that positive values indicate support for decentralization.

Table 1 Results from Multilevel Linear Regression Model Predicting Decentralization Positions

Note: the outcome variable in all regressions is party position on decentralization, scaled from 1 to 20, with 20 the most positive stance; standard errors in parentheses. ***p < 0.001, **p < 0.01, *p < 0.05.

Decentralization and Ideological Dimensions

Model 1 presents the simple results, without controls, for the influence of the two ideological dimensions on party positions on decentralization. In Model 2, we add the controls for government participation, the mean position of the government/opposition, party size, the presence of a regionalist party, the presence of a regionally based ethnic group, the level of self-rule, and the logged geographic area and population size.

We find strong support for the claim that decentralization raises questions of identity on the one hand and efficiency and redistribution on the other, since the core ideological dimensions of political contestation are clearly associated with parties’ positions on decentralization. We can see in Models 1 and 2 that positions on the cultural dimension affect party positions on decentralization in the expected manner: the more culturally conservative a party, the more it opposes decentralization. For the economic dimension, our findings indicate that the further parties are to the right, the more they support decentralization. The magnitude of the effect of the two dimensions is similar, although the economic dimension appears to have a somewhat stronger influence. We therefore find strong support for Hypotheses 1 and 2.

The effect of these two variables is shown in Figure 2 by plotting the predicted values on the decentralization issue according to the party's position on the economic and cultural dimensions (using the results from Model 2). All other variables are held at their mean except for government participation and the presence of a regionalist party, which are both set to 0. The darker the shaded portion of the graph, the more in favour of decentralization a party is predicted to be. We can see that an economically left-wing, culturally conservative party would be clearly against decentralization, while its ideological opposite – a culturally liberal, economically right-wing party – would be expected to strongly favour decentralization. Parties in the diagonal from the bottom left to the top right are expected to take relatively centrist positions on decentralization.

Fig. 2 Predicted decentralization positions by ideological dimension

Note: predicted values for party positions on decentralization on a 1–20 scale based on Model 2. Higher values indicate greater support for decentralization. Presence of a regional party, presence of a regionally based and disadvantaged ethnic minority, and government participation set to 0; all other variables held at their mean.

Of the control variables, we find effects for two of our party-level variables (party size and government-opposition rivalry). There is thus evidence that smaller parties tend to favour decentralization. We also find that there is an effect of government-opposition rivalry: the more the government (opposition) is in favour of decentralization, the more the opposition (government) will oppose it, and vice versa. This confirms the notion that decentralization is used strategically as an element of competition between statewide parties, both in and out of power, that wish to distinguish themselves from their main rival.Footnote 68 The presence of regionally based ethnic groups and regionalist parties also matters. If there is a regionally based ethnic group but no regionalist party, then statewide parties are, on average, slightly more favourable toward decentralization. If there is a regionalist party, then statewide parties are less supportive of decentralization. Interestingly, the only control variables close to significance are those that reflect statewide parties’ strategic considerations: their size and the positions and presence of competitors (in or out of office). Institutional and structural factors such as the level of self-rule, the presence of a regionally based ethnic group and regional economic disparity matter little. Decentralization is thus an issue that can be manipulated strategically for partisan advantage.

Contextual Factors

How does the influence of the two ideological dimensions vary based on contextual factors? Specifically, does it depend on the degree of self-rule, the degree of regional economic disparity or the presence of a regionally based ethnic group? We test our hypotheses by interacting our ideological scales with these country-level variables. Again, Table 1 presents the regression results.

To test Hypothesis 3, we interact the positions on the economic dimension with the level of self-rule. The results are presented in Model 3 in Table 1. The interaction effect is significant. Figure 3 plots the marginal effect of the economic dimension according to the level of self-rule.Footnote 69 The histogram underlying the graph shows the distribution of sample values of self-rule. The result is clear: the greater the level of self-rule, the more economic ideology is associated with positions on decentralization. The economic right is predicted to be more in favour of decentralization than the economic left mainly when the level of self-rule is relatively high. The effect of economic policy positions on decentralization positions is around 0.5 in countries with a high level of self-rule (around 20) but close to 0 in countries with low levels of self-rule (around 0). This means that we have strong support for Hypothesis 3.Footnote 70

Fig. 3 The effect of socio-economic position conditional on average self-rule

Note: based on Model 3. Graph shows predicted marginal effect of a one-unit increase (rightward shift) in a party's economic position conditional on a country's level of self-rule. Grey bars show the distribution of values of self-rule in the sample countries. ‘Pipes’ below histogram show individual country values of regional GDP disparity.

To test Hypothesis 4, we interact the positions on the economic dimension with the values for regional economic disparity. The results are presented in Model 4 in Table 1. Again, we plot the marginal effect of the economic dimension conditional on the degree of regional economic disparity (Figure 4). We find clear support for Hypothesis 4: the greater the level of economic disparity between a country's regions, the more economic positions are associated with decentralization positions.Footnote 71 At high levels of regional disparity (values of around 0.4) we expect a clear association between economic ideology and decentralization positions. In contrast, when regional disparity in GDP per capita is low, then we expect a weak association between views on the economic dimension and views on decentralization.Footnote 72

Fig. 4 The effect of socio-economic position conditional on regional GDP disparity

Note: based on Model 4. Graph shows predicted marginal effect of a one-unit increase (rightward shift) in a party's economic position conditional on a country's level of regional economic disparity in GDP per capita. Grey bars show the distribution of values of economic disparity in the sample countries. ‘Pipes’ below histogram show individual country values of regional GDP disparity.

To test Hypothesis 5, we interact positioning on the cultural dimensions with the presence of a regionally based ethnic group. The results, presented in Model 5, do not support our hypothesis. Instead, the association between positions on the cultural dimension and decentralization are, if anything, a little weaker when there is a regionally based ethnic group. However, this difference in association is not significant. Overall, there is clearly no evidence that the impact of the cultural dimension is greater when there is a regionally based ethnic group in the country.Footnote 73

Our final contextual effect (Hypothesis 6) concerned the effect of the ideology of regionalist parties and how this influences the strategic incentives of statewide parties. We test this hypothesis by adding two additional variables that measure the distance of the statewide party's position from the (weighted) mean position of regionalist parties on both the economic and cultural dimensions. Our sample is reduced to the twelve countries in which a regionalist party competes. Models 6 and 7 in Table 1 present the results; Model 6 re-runs the main model for the reduced sample and Model 7 adds the new distance terms.

Model 7 demonstrates that the ideological position of regionalist parties matters, but only on the economic dimension. We illustrate this in Figure 5, where we calculate predicted positions on decentralization as in Figure 1. In Figure 5, the statewide party's economic ideology is on the x-axis and the statewide party's distance from the weighted mean position of regionalist parties on economic ideology is on the y-axis. The area in the centre at the top is left blank, as these are arithmetically impossible values. For example, a party at 10.5 on the 1–20 scale can only ever be 9.5 units from other parties. When moving from left to right, the figure clearly reinforces the previous pattern: there is an association between right-wing economic views and support for decentralization. When moving from low to high values on the y-axis, we see that support for decentralization decreases as the distance from regionalist parties increases. In other words, when the average economic position of regionalist parties is close to that of the statewide party, the statewide party chooses a more accommodative strategy and supports decentralization more. When the regionalist parties are, on average, more distant ideologically, the statewide party chooses a more adversarial ideology, so supports decentralization less. This may help to explain patterns of party competition in the United Kingdom, where the Labour party, threatened by the left-wing SNP, endorsed devolution, a position that was rejected by the Conservative party. Similarly, the right-wing Flemish regionalist parties forced the Christian Democratic and Liberal parties to adopt more ardently decentralist stances that contrast with the resilient centralism of Belgium's Socialist party. Thus we find strong support for Hypothesis 6, but only for economic ideology.

Fig. 5 The effect of regionalist party positions

Note: predicted values for party positions on decentralization on a 0–10 scale based on Model 7. Higher values indicate greater support for decentralization. Presence of a regional party, presence of a regionally based and disadvantaged ethnic minority, and government participation set to 0; all other variables held at their mean.

Discussion and Conclusion

In this article, our aim has been to follow the encouragement of Marks and Hooghe to ‘bring politics into the study of institutional choice’Footnote 74 by focusing on how decentralization debates tap into questions of efficiency, redistribution and identity and by analysing how ideology shapes the views of statewide parties on the territorial allocation of authority. We have shown that the positions that statewide parties take on decentralization depend on their economic and cultural views. Parties on the economic right are more supportive of decentralization than parties on the economic left, while culturally liberal parties favour decentralization more than culturally conservative parties.

This finding is important because it highlights the need to go beyond the simple left-right dimension in order to understand party preferences on decentralization – an issue of jurisdictional architecture that, like European integration, taps into two separate logics. The two dimensions may reinforce each other: culturally liberal, economically right-wing parties are expected to be most in favour of decentralization, while their ideological opposites should be least supportive. Yet most parties, especially in Western Europe, do not combine the two dimensions in this way, as cultural liberalism tends to be associated with left-wing economic views and cultural conservatism with right-wing economic views.Footnote 75 Marks et al. have noted that this pattern can cause tension concerning whether or not to support European integration: for example, many right-wing parties are ‘rifted between nationalism and market liberalism’.Footnote 76 This characterization may also apply to decentralization, with culturally liberal parties on the economic left torn between redistribution and recognizing diversity, and culturally conservative parties on the economic right divided between economic efficiency and nationalism. Further research should investigate in detail the internal rifts that these contradictory ideological motivations may cause, and how they are managed by individual statewide parties.

In addition to these general patterns, we also hypothesized that the association between economic and cultural ideology and party views on decentralization depends on the individual country context. We found that this is true only for economic ideology, which is more associated with decentralization positions when economic disparity between regions or the level of self-rule is high. Statewide parties also react to the strategic incentives presented by regionalist parties’ economic positions. If regionalist parties take up a similar economic position to statewide parties, then the latter adopt an accommodative strategy to counter the threat; if regionalist parties take up a distant economic position, then statewide parties will pursue an adversarial strategy. Given the static nature of the analysis, we can only demonstrate a strong association; we cannot demonstrate the dynamic effect of competitive interactions on statewide party position over time. We found no evidence of contextual effects of the influence of the cultural dimension. These results show that the link between economic ideology and views on decentralization depends on the country context: the relationship of decentralization to the logics of efficiency and redistribution is moderated by individual country institutional, structural and strategic factors.

These findings have implications for our understanding of politics in systems of multilevel governance, and go some way toward building a causal theory of authority allocation by offering insight into how ideology, rooted in a specific country context, shapes the mindset of agents responsible for determining the territorial distribution of power. They also raise several questions that deserve further investigation.

First, this article has concentrated on party positions at a single point in time. Future work should introduce a dynamic element to the analysis to see if (and how) statewide parties change their positions on decentralization over time, and what lies behind these shifts in position. Further research should examine the effects of competitive interactions and the salience of decentralization on the changes in party positions over time and across countries:Footnote 77 when do parties change their position, when does decentralization become politicized and how does this influence decisions to reform the territorial allocation of power?Footnote 78

Secondly, research on the process of decentralization in different countries could benefit from an explicitly party-political approach to understanding the timing and tempo of territorial reforms.Footnote 79 Future research should examine how party- and country-specific factors – such as party organization, party competition and institutional arrangements – condition the effect of ideology and structure the incentives of statewide parties to either endorse or oppose decentralization.

Finally, the EU's jurisdictional architecture, particularly in monetary and fiscal affairs, is currently contested based on different views on efficiency, redistribution and identity.Footnote 80 Given the salience of such polarization, how do parties’ views on decentralization and European integration fit together? Are party positions on both topics driven by the same logics? Future work should investigate if (and how) party positions on the different levels of governance are connected.

Supplementary Material

To view supplementary material for this article, please visit http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/S0007123413000239.

Footnotes

*

Centro de Estudios Politicos y Constitucionales (email: simon.toubeau@cepc.es); Department of Methods in the Social Sciences, University of Vienna (email: markus.wagner@univie.ac.at). Both authors contributed equally to this article. Simon Toubeau's research on this project was funded by the ESRC (PTA-026-27-2270) and by the I.S.R.I.B. (BB2B2010-2-23), Brussels-Capital Region. Markus Wagner's research on this project was financed by the Austrian Science Fund under the ‘Austrian National Election Study’ project (AUTNES, S10902-G11). We thank Luis de la Calle, Jan Erk, Martin Ejnar Hansen, Gary Marks, Thomas Meyer, Arjan Schakel, Joost van Spanje, conference participants at the ECPR General Conference 2011 and seminar participants at a CEVIPOL seminar at the Université Libre de Bruxelles for comments on earlier drafts of this article. We thank Michael Tatzber-Schebach for research assistance. All errors remain our own. Data replication sets are available at http://dx.doi.org/doi:10.1017/S0007123413000239 and online appendices are available at http://dx.doi.org/doi:10.1017/S0007123413000239.

1 Behnke and Benz Reference Behnke and Benz2009; Gerber and Kollman Reference Gerber and Kollman2004; Marks et al. 2008; Rodden Reference Rodden2004.

2 Marks et al. 2008, 167.

6 Maddens and Libbrecht 2009.

7 Deschouwer Reference Deschouwer2003.

8 Alesina and Spolaore Reference Alesina and Spolaore1997; Bolton and Roland Reference Bolton and Roland1997.

9 Statewide parties are political parties that represent the ideology of one of the main party families (Communist, Social Democratic, Green/ecological, Liberal, Christian Democratic, Conservative, Radical Right) and that seek to gain polity-wide representation in elections, which they contest at all levels (central, regional, municipal) (Hopkin and Van Houten Reference Hopkin and Van Houten2009; Linz, Stepan, and Yadav Reference Linz, Stepan and Yadav2011; Swenden and Maddens Reference Swenden and Maddens2009). In contrast, regionalist parties have a limited territorial reach and may represent specific ethnic groups.

10 Marks and Hooghe Reference Marks and Hooghe2000, 811.

12 Hooghe and Marks Reference Hooghe and Marks2009.

14 Benoit and Laver Reference Benoit and Laver2006.

15 Hooghe and Marks Reference Hooghe and Marks2009, 2.

16 Benz and Broschek Reference Benz and Broschek2013; Benz and Colino Reference Benz and Colino2011.

18 The cultural dimension (Kriesi et al. Reference Kriesi, Grande, Lachat, Dolezal and Bornschier2008), has also been labelled the libertarian-authoritarian dimension (Kitschelt Reference Kitschelt1994) and the Green/Alternative/Libertarian versus Traditional/Authoritarian/Nationalist (gal/tan) dimension (Hooghe et al. Reference Hooghe, Marks and Wilson2002).

20 Montinola, Oian, and Weingast Reference Montinola, Oian and Weingast1995; Weingast Reference Weingast1995.

21 Wildavsky Reference Wildavsky1985.

22 Montinola, Oian, and Weingast Reference Montinola, Oian and Weingast1995; Weingast Reference Weingast1995.

23 The scope conditions of this argument are bound by the post-Second World War period. During the nineteenth century, economic liberals were centralist, spearheading the creation of national markets by abolishing internal tariffs and local fiscal privileges, establishing national standards and developing national transport and communication systems. In contrast, prior to the development of welfare states, the economic left was decentralist, as socialist movements endorsed a localized approach to organizing industry, establishing workers’ co-operatives and providing social relief.

24 Hooghe and Marks Reference Hooghe and Marks2009, 17.

25 Dahl and Tufte Reference Dahl and Tufte1974; Inglehart 1977.

26 Marks et al. 2008, 170.

27 Storper Reference Storper1997; Rodrigues-Pose and Ezcurra Reference Rodrigues-Pose and Ezcurra2010.

28 Newhouse Reference Newhouse1997.

30 Alesina and Spolaore Reference Alesina and Spolaore1997; Bolton and Roland Reference Bolton and Roland1997.

31 By regionally based ethnic group, we mean a group of people that is living in a territorially delimited space with a sense of commonality based on a belief in shared ancestry and a common culture and that is politically relevant insofar as it is represented in national politics by at least one political organization (Cederman and Girardin Reference Cederman and Girardin2007; Cederman et al. Reference Cederman, Wimmer and Min2010).

33 Hechter Reference Hechter2000.

34 Horowitz Reference Horowitz1985.

35 The stance that regionalist parties adopt on economic issues is influenced by: the deep-rooted historical factors that shape regions’ productive structures and class composition, the electoral strategies adopted by nationalist and mainstream political actors during ‘critical junctures’, and the incentives and constraints of party competition (Erk Reference Erk2005; Keating Reference Keating1992a; Massetti Reference Massetti2009; Van Houten Reference Van Houten2003).

36 Toubeau Reference Toubeau2011.

40 Meguid's third strategic reaction by parties, the dismissive strategy, relates to the salience of (rather than the position on) an issue, so is not relevant to this research question.

41 Benoit and Laver Reference Benoit and Laver2006. The cut-off period for our analysis is thus the early 2000s. We do not use information from the party documents that was hand coded by the Comparative Manifesto Project (Budge et al. Reference Budge, Klingemann, Volkens, Bara and Tanenbaum2001; Klingemann et al. Reference Klingemann, Volkens, Bara, Budge and McDonald2006). While these also measure the presence and direction of statements on decentralization, manifesto data is probably best suited to analyses of issue salience (cf. Mazzoleni Reference Mazzoleni2009).

42 These are: Albania, Belarus, Bosnia, Macedonia, Moldova, Russia, Serbia, Ukraine and Turkey. We also dropped Israel (due to missing information on the decentralization dimension), New Zealand (due to missing information on social policy) and Northern Ireland.

43 Specifically, we have no information on the level of regional self-rule for Cyprus, Iceland, Luxembourg and Malta. Our results hold if these four small countries are added to the sample.

44 The thirty-one countries are: Australia, Austria, Belgium, Bulgaria, Canada, Croatia, Czech Republic, Denmark, Estonia, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Hungary, Ireland, Italy, Japan, Latvia, Lithuania, Netherlands, Norway, Poland, Portugal, Romania, Slovenia, Slovakia, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, the United Kingdom and the United States. The full list of parties we include can be found in Appendix 2. Belgium is included in the analysis even though it has had no statewide parties since the late 1970s, when the party system bifurcated along linguistic lines. We focus specifically in this country on political parties that are not regionalist or separatist – that is, those that originated as parties with a polity-wide vocation, that represent one of the mainstream political ideologies and that tend to enter coalition governments together as party families comprising two ‘sister’ parties.

46 Maddens and Libbrecht Reference Maddens and Libbrecht2008.

47 There are a number of ongoing efforts to design coding schemes for party manifestos that distinguish explicitly between the institutional and cultural components of decentralization and measure position, salience, relevance, directional certainty and directional intensity (Libbrecht et al. Reference Libbrecht, Maddens, Swenden and Fabre2009; Maddens and Libbrecht Reference Maddens and Libbrecht2008).

48 We reversed the direction of the Benoit and Laver scale.

49 Benoit and Laver Reference Benoit and Laver2006.

50 While Benoit and Laver did ask about party positions on nationalism and immigration in some countries, only the social policy scale is available for all thirty-one countries.

51 Our results do not change if we run the models with robust standard errors clustered by country.

52 Marks, Hooghe, and Schakel Reference Marks, Hooghe and Schakel2010.

53 Eurostat 2012.

54 Organisation for Economic Co-Operation and Development 2011.

55 We use 2003 data for countries where we use Benoit and Laver data. The two exceptions are Denmark, where data is only available from 2005, and Switzerland, where the most recent data we found was from 1995. Available from http://cmsp.migration6.vbs.admin.ch/bfs/portal/de/index/themen/04/02/05/key/gesamtes_volkseinkommen.html, accessed 10 June 2013.

56 The three Baltic countries (Estonia, Latvia and Lithuania) are coded as having 0 regional disparity, as no separate regional values are provided by Eurostat.

58 We exclude the largest ethnopolitically relevant group, which is generally the dominant group (for example, the English in the United Kingdom).

60 See Appendix 1 for the specific country-level values of these contextual factors.

61 O'Neill Reference O'Neill2003.

62 Benoit and Laver Reference Benoit and Laver2006 (Appendix B).

63 Marks, Wilson, and Ray Reference Marks, Wilson and Ray2002, 588.

66 United Nations Statistics Division 2010.

67 Heston, Summers, and Aten Reference Heston, Summers and Aten2009.

68 O'Neill Reference O'Neill2003.

69 Brambor, Clark, and Golder Reference Brambor, Clark and Golder2006.

70 An interaction term between cultural ideology and the level of self-rule is not statistically significant. Thus the association between cultural ideology and decentralization positions does not differ by levels of self-rule. The influence of the logic of identity on the position of statewide parties is consistent across different types of states, whether unitary, regionalized or federal.

71 Running the analysis without the three Baltic countries, coded here as having 0 regional disparity in GDP per capita, does not affect our substantive results. While the interaction term is no longer significant, the change in the marginal effect is very similar in magnitude.

72 Countries with such levels of economic disparity include Belgium, the Czech Republic, Hungary, Romania, the United Kingdom and the United States. Countries with low levels of regional disparity (below 0.2) include Australia, Denmark, Greece, Japan, the Netherlands and Sweden.

73 Some of the regionally based ethnic groups in our sample are very small, such as Slovenes in Austria and Okinawans in Japan (see Appendix 1). If we only count ethnic groups that make up more than 5 per cent of the national population, then our results change only insofar as the effect of the cultural dimension is significantly lower in countries with large regionally based ethnic groups, thus providing even stronger evidence against our hypothesis.

74 Marks and Hooghe Reference Marks and Hooghe2000, 811.

77 This theoretical development, however, needs to be preceded by a significant data collection effort that aims to establish a time series of party position, salience, directional intensity and certainty, across the different dimensions of decentralization (see footnote 48).

78 Hooghe and Marks Reference Hooghe and Marks2009.

79 Cf. Massetti and Toubeau Reference Massetti and Toubeau2013.

80 Hooghe and Marks Reference Hooghe and Marks2009.

References

Alesina, Alberto Spolaore, Enrico. 1997. On the Number and Size of Nations. Quarterly Journal of Economics 112:10291056.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Behnke, Nathalie Benz, Arthur. 2009. The Politics of Constitutional Change between Reform and Evolution. Publius 39:213240.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Benoit, Kenneth Laver, Michael. 2006. Party Policy in Modern Democracies. London: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Benz, Arthur Colino, César. 2011. Introduction: Constitutional Change in Federations – A Framework for Analysis. Regional and Federal Studies 20 (2):250275.Google Scholar
Benz, Arthur Broschek, Jörg. 2013. Federal Dynamics: Introduction. In Federal Dynamics: Continuity, Change and Varieties of Federalism, edited by Arthur Benz and Jörg Broshek, 123. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bolton, Patrick Roland, Gérard. 1997. The Breakup of Nations: A Political Economy Analysis. Quarterly Journal of Economics 62:10571090.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brambor, Thomas, Clark, William R. Golder, Matt. 2006. Understanding Interaction Models: Improving Empirical Analyses. Political Analysis 14 (1):6382.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Budge, Ian, Klingemann, Hans-Dieter, Volkens, Andrea, Bara, Judith Tanenbaum, Eric. 2001. Mapping Policy Preferences: Estimate for Parties, Electors and Governments 1945–1988. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cederman, Lars-Erik, Wimmer, Andreas Min, Brian. 2010. Why do Ethnic Groups Rebel? New Data and Analysis. World Politics 62 (1):87119.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cederman, Lars-Erik, Min, Brian, Wimmer, Andreas. 2009. Ethnic Power Relations dataset. Available from http://hdl.handle.net/1902.1/11796, accessed 2 January 2013.Google Scholar
Cederman, Lars-Erik Girardin, Luc. 2007. Beyond Fractionalization: Mapping Ethnicity onto Nationalist Insurgencies. American Political Science Review 101 (1):173185.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dahl, Robert Tufte, Edward. 1974. Size and Democracy. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
De Vries, Michel S. 2000. The Rise and Fall of Decentralization: A Comparative Analysis of Arguments and Practices in European Countries. European Journal of Political Research 38 (2):193224.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Deschouwer, Kris. 2003. Political Parties in Multi-Layered Systems. European Urban and Regional Studies 10 (3):213226.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Erk, Jan. 2005. Sub-State Nationalism and the Left-Right Divide: Critical Junctures in the Formation of Nationalist Labour Movements in Belgium. Nations and Nationalism 11 (4):551570.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Erk, Jan. 2007. Explaining Federalism. State, Society and Congruence in Austria, Belgium, Canada, Germany and Switzerland. Abingdon: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eurostat. 2012. Statistics Database. Available from http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/portal/page/portal/statistics/search_database, accessed 2 January 2013.Google Scholar
Gerber, Elisabeth R. Kollman, Ken. 2004. Introduction-Authority Migration: Defining an Emerging Research Agenda. Political Science and Politics 27 (4):397400.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hechter, Michael. 2000. Containing Nationalism. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Heston, Alan, Summers, Robert, Aten, Bettina. 2009. Penn World Table Version 6.3. Center for International Comparisons of Production, Income and Prices at the University of Pennsylvania, August 2009. Available from https://pwt.sas.upenn.edu/php_site/pwt_index.php Google Scholar
Hix, Simon Lord, Christopher. 1997. Political Parties in the European Union. Basingstoke: Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hooghe, Liesbet, Marks, Gary Wilson, Carole J.. 2002. Does Left/Right Structure Party Positions on European Integration? Comparative Political Studies 35 (8):965989.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hooghe, Liesbet Marks, Gary. 2009. A Post-Functionalist Theory of European Integration: From Permissive Consensus to Constraining Dissensus. British Journal of Political Science 39 (1):123.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hooghe, Liesbet, Bakker, Ryan, Brigevich, Anna, De Vries, Catherine, Edwards, Erica, Marks, Gary, Rovny, Jan, Steenbergen, Marco Vachudova, Milada. 2010. Reliability and Validity of the 2002 and 2006 Chapel Hill Expert Surveys on Party Positioning. European Journal of Political Research 4:684703.Google Scholar
Hopkin, Jonathan Van Houten, Pieter. 2009. Decentralisation and State-Wide Parties: An Introduction. Party Politics 15 (2):131135.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Horowitz, Donald L. 1985. Ethnic Groups in Conflict. Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Keating, Michael. 1992a. Do the Workers Really Have No Country? Peripheral Nationalism and Socialism in the United Kingdom, France, Italy and Spain. In The Social Origins of Nationalist Movements, edited by John Coakley, 6180. London: Sage.Google Scholar
Keating, Michael. 1992b. Regional Autonomy in the Changing State Order: A Framework of Analysis. Regional Politics and Policy 2 (3):4561.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kitschelt, Herbert. 1994. The Transformation of European Social Democracy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klingemann, Hans-Dieter, Volkens, Andrea, Bara, Judith, Budge, Ian. McDonald, Michael D.. 2006. Mapping Policy Preferences II: Estimates for Parties, Electors, and Governments in Eastern Europe, European Union and OECD, 1990–2003. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kriesi, Hanspeter, Grande, Edgar, Lachat, Romain, Dolezal, Martin Bornschier, Simon. 2008. West European Politics in the Age of Globalization: Six Countries Compared. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Libbrecht, Lieselotte, Maddens, Bart, Swenden, Wilfred Fabre, Elodie. 2009. Issue Salience in Regional Party Manifestos in Spain. European Journal of Political Research 48 (1):5879.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Linz, Juan, Stepan, Alfred Yadav, Yogendra. 2011. Crafting State-Nations. India and Other Multinational Democracies. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Maddens, Bart Libbrecht, Lieselotte. 2008. How State-Wide Parties Cope with the Regionalist Issue: The Case of Spain; A Directional Approach. In Territorial Party Politics in Western Europe, edited by Wilfred Swenden and Bart Maddens, 204228. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
Marks, Gary Wilson, Carole. 2000. The Past in the Present: A Cleavage Theory of Party Response to European Integration. British Journal of Political Science 30:443459.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marks, Gary, Wilson, Carole Ray, Leonard. 2002. National Political Parties and European Integration. American Journal of Political Science 46 (3):585594.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marks, Gary, Hooghe, Liesbet, Nelson, Moira Edwards, Erica. 2006. Party Competition and European Integration in the East and West: Different Structures, Same Causality. Comparative Political Studies 39:155175.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marks, Gary Hooghe, Liesbet. 2000. Optimality and Authority: A Critique of Neoclassical Theory. Journal of Common Market Studies 38:795816.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marks, Gary, Hooghe, Liesbet Schakel, Arjan. 2010. The Rise of Regional Authority: A Comparative Study of 42 Democracies. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Marks, Gary Steenbergen, Marco. 2004. European Integration and Political Conflict. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Massetti, Emanuele. 2009. Explaining Regionalist Party Positioning in a Multi-Dimensional Ideological Space: A Framework for Analysis. Regional and Federal Studies 19 (4–5):501531.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Massetti, Emanuele Toubeau, Simon. 2013. The Party Politics of Territorial Reforms in Europe. West European Politics 36 (2):297316.Google Scholar
Mazzoleni, Martino. 2009. The Saliency of Regionalization in Party Systems: A Comparative Analysis of Regional Decentralization in Party Manifestos. Party Politics 15 (2):199218.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meguid, Bonnie M. 2005. Competition Between Unequals: The Role of Mainstream Party Strategy in Niche Party Success. American Political Science Review 99 (3):347359.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meguid, Bonnie M. 2008. Party Competition Between Unequals: Strategies and Electoral Fortunes in Western Europe. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Montinola, Gabriella, Oian, Yingyi Weingast, Barry R.. 1995. Federalism Chinese Style: The Political Basis for Economic Success in China. World Politics 48 (1):5081.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Newhouse, John. 1997. Europe's Rising Regionalism. Foreign Affairs 1:6784.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Newman, Saul. 1997. Ideological Trends Among Ethnoregionalist Parties in Post-Industrial Democracies. Nationalism and Ethnic Politics 3 (1):2860.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Oates, Wallace E. 1972. Fiscal Federalism. New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich.Google Scholar
Oates, Wallace E. 1999. An Essay on Fiscal Federalism. Journal of Economic Literature 37 (3):11201149.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
O'Neill, Kathleen. 2003. Decentralization as an Electoral Strategy. Comparative Political Studies 36 (9):10681091.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Organisation for Economic Co-Operation and Development. 2011. Regional Database. Available from http://stats.oecd.org/Index.aspx, accessed 2 January 2013.Google Scholar
Rodden, Jonathan. 2004. Comparative Federalism and Decentralization: On Meaning and Measurement. Comparative Politics 36 (4):481500.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rodrigues-Pose, Andrés Ezcurra, Roberto. 2010. Does Decentralization Matter for Regional Disparities? A Cross-Country Analysis. Journal of Economic Geography 10 (5):619644.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schakel, Arjan. 2010. Explaining Regional and Local Government: An Empirical Test of the Decentralization Theorem. Governance 23 (2):331355.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Scott, Allen J. 1998. Regions and the World Economy: The Coming Shape of Global Production, Competition and Political Order. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Storper, Michael. 1997. The Regional World: Territorial Structure in a Global Economy. New York: Guilford Press.Google Scholar
Strøm, Kaare. 1990. A Behavioral Theory of Competitive Political Parties. American Journal of Political Science 34 (2):565598.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Strøm, Kaare Müller, Wolfgang C., eds. 1999. Policy, Office or Votes? How Political Parties in Western Europe Make Hard Decisions. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Swenden, Wilfred Maddens, Bart. 2009. Territorial Party Politics in Western Europe. London: Palgrave Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Taggart, Paul. 1998. A Touchstone of Dissent: Euroscepticism in Contemporary Western European Party Systems. European Journal of Political Research 33:363388.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Toubeau, Simon. 2011. Regional Nationalist Parties and Constitutional Change in Parliamentary Democracies: A Framework for Analysis. Regional and Federal Studies 21 (4–5):427446.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
United Nations Statistics Division. 2010. Demographic Yearbook 2008. New York: United Nations.Google Scholar
Van der Brug, Wouter Van Spanje, Joost. 2009. Immigration, Europe and the ‘New Cultural Dimension’. European Journal of Political Research 48:309334.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Van Houten, Pieter. 2003. Globalisation and Demands for Regional Autonomy in Europe. In Governance in a Global Economy: Political Economy in Transition, edited by Miles Kahler and David A. Lake, 87109. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Warwick, Paul. 2002. Towards a Common Dimensionality in West European Policy Space. Party Politics 8 (1):101122.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weingast, Barry. 1995. The Economic Role of Political Institutions: Market-Preserving Federalism and Economic Development. Journal of Law Economic and Organisation 11:131.Google Scholar
Wildavsky, Aaron. 1985. Federalism Means Inequality. Society 22 (2):4249.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wucherpfennig, Julian, Weidmann, Nils B., Girardin, Luc., Cederman, Lars-Erik Wimmer, Andreas. 2011. Politically Relevant Ethnic Groups Across Space and Time: Introducing the GeoEPR Dataset. Conflict Management and Peace Science 20 (5):115.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Fig. 1 Party positions on decentralizationNote: data from Benoit and Laver 2006. Countries included are listed in footnote 44; parties included are in Appendix 2.

Figure 1

Table 1 Results from Multilevel Linear Regression Model Predicting Decentralization Positions

Figure 2

Fig. 2 Predicted decentralization positions by ideological dimensionNote: predicted values for party positions on decentralization on a 1–20 scale based on Model 2. Higher values indicate greater support for decentralization. Presence of a regional party, presence of a regionally based and disadvantaged ethnic minority, and government participation set to 0; all other variables held at their mean.

Figure 3

Fig. 3 The effect of socio-economic position conditional on average self-ruleNote: based on Model 3. Graph shows predicted marginal effect of a one-unit increase (rightward shift) in a party's economic position conditional on a country's level of self-rule. Grey bars show the distribution of values of self-rule in the sample countries. ‘Pipes’ below histogram show individual country values of regional GDP disparity.

Figure 4

Fig. 4 The effect of socio-economic position conditional on regional GDP disparityNote: based on Model 4. Graph shows predicted marginal effect of a one-unit increase (rightward shift) in a party's economic position conditional on a country's level of regional economic disparity in GDP per capita. Grey bars show the distribution of values of economic disparity in the sample countries. ‘Pipes’ below histogram show individual country values of regional GDP disparity.

Figure 5

Fig. 5 The effect of regionalist party positionsNote: predicted values for party positions on decentralization on a 0–10 scale based on Model 7. Higher values indicate greater support for decentralization. Presence of a regional party, presence of a regionally based and disadvantaged ethnic minority, and government participation set to 0; all other variables held at their mean.

Supplementary material: PDF

Wagner Supplementary Material

Data

Download Wagner Supplementary Material(PDF)
PDF 400.8 KB
Supplementary material: File

Wagner Supplementary Material

Data

Download Wagner Supplementary Material(File)
File 48.5 KB