Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-m9kch Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-05-16T14:12:45.051Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Voting, or a Price System in a Competitive Market Structure

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 August 2014

Martin Shubik*
Affiliation:
Yale University

Extract

In this brief note it is demonstrated that if all the conditions for the existence of a competitive equilibrium are satisfied, then simple majority voting to determine the distribution of goods may be less efficient than a price system.

The argument here may be somewhat cryptic for those not familiar with the work of Anthony Downs. A considerably more discursive presentation of the background material is given in “A Two Party System, General Equilibrium and the Voters' Paradox.” The tax and public goods aspect of the voting problem have been discussed elsewhere in “Notes on the Taxonomy of Problems Concerning Public Goods.” The result presented here, nevertheless, stands by itself, hence is presented in this brief form.

The political system is modeled at its simplest. We assume the existence of two players called “political parties.” The goal of each player is to win an election by as large a vote as possible. A strategy for each player is to name a policy that it will carry out if it is elected. A policy is any point in the set of feasible distributions of final product. It follows immediately that, although any policy may be considered as a strategy, any non-Pareto optimal policies are dominated by some policy that is optimal. A discussion of the reasons for modeling a party in this simple manner is given in detail elsewhere. It is assumed that all voters are passive or “mechanistic,” i.e., they do not form groups but merely vote individually, selecting optimally between the two policies offered.

Type
Research Notes
Copyright
Copyright © American Political Science Association 1970

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 Downs, Anthony, An Economic Theory of Democracy (New York: Harper & Row, 1957)Google Scholar.

2 Shubik, Martin, “A Two Party System, General Equilibrium and the Voters' Paradox,” Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie, 28 (1968), 341354CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

3 Martin Shubik, “Notes on the Taxonomy of Problems Concerning Public Goods,” (Cowles Foundation Discussion Paper 208).

4 Two models can be considered, the first in which a party's goal is to win by as large a vote as possible, the second where its goal is just to win. In this example, the latter assumption appears to be the more reasonable.

5 Kenneth Arrow has pointed out that one must distinguish between the two cases where (1) the parties announce their (mixed) strategies to the public, or (2) randomize first and announce the the results of the randomization as their policies to the public. If we adopt the first interpretation, we may view the mixed strategy as being a “degree of belief” in the mind of the voter. He perceives some of the contradictions in the statements of the parties; hence he has only a tentative view of what their actions will be. In the second instance we assume that the parties polarize the issues for the voters. In the first case we must assume a cardinal utility scale for the voters who evaluate uncertain outcomes.

6 Gross, O. and Wagner, R., A Continuous Blotto Game (The RAND Corporation, RM-408. June 17, 1950)Google Scholar.

* Normalization reveals the value of this constant to be