Skip to content
Publicly Available Published by De Gruyter October 1, 2021

The Startup Selection Process in Accelerators: Qualitative Evidence from Turkey

  • Berna Beyhan ORCID logo EMAIL logo , Semih Akçomak ORCID logo and Dilek Cetindamar ORCID logo

Abstract

Startup selection is an essential mechanism of how accelerators create value. Through in-depth case studies of 10 accelerators in Turkey, our research explores the selection process in accelerators. Our findings indicate that accelerators overcome their context’s extreme uncertainty by involving various actors in the selection process and reducing the information asymmetries for investors and startups. Accelerators tend to select effortlessly coachable startups, willing to collaborate with accelerators, mentors, or other actors, and passionate enough to overcome the pressure of creating a business at a fast pace. Our research also exhibits that the selection process serves startups by directing and training them to transmit the right signals to receivers, primarily investors. Accelerators prefer to work with entrepreneurial teams that are coachable, passionate, and collaborative to vibrate the right signals. Similarly, the accelerators’ selection process helps investors by decreasing signaling noise and mitigate information asymmetry. By doing so, accelerators contribute to a well-functioning and more effective entrepreneurship ecosystem.

1 Introduction

Accelerators are one of the intermediaries that nurture startups to access initial resources to pursue entrepreneurial endeavors. An accelerator is defined as “a fixed-term, cohort-based program for startups, including mentorship and/or educational components, that culminates in a graduation event” (Cohen et al. 2019, p. 1782). Recent research on accelerators focuses on mechanisms of accelerators or accelerators as a mechanism to support startups (Crişan et al. 2021; Shankar and Clausen 2020; Stayton and Mangematin 2019). These mechanisms mainly serve to test product-market fit, quick market entry, and achieving quick scalability. The motto of accelerators is “scale quickly or fail fast” (Shankar and Clausen 2020). In order to be successful accelerators, need to select their startups based on the requirements of these mechanisms. Hence, our research contributes to the research by analyzing the startup selection process in accelerators.

Previous research provides clues about the importance of the selection process in accelerators (Clarysse, Wright, and van Hove 2016; Pauwels et al. 2016; Prexl et al. 2019). However, to our best knowledge, the selection process is not examined by considering that the signals of legitimacy are collectively created and reproduced by accelerators, startups, and resource holders. This research paper aims to answer the following question: what selection process do accelerators use to select startups? In order to answer this question, we analyzed the data collected from transcribed semi-structured in-depth interviews with directors of accelerators, site visits, and archival data such as accelerators’ websites, blogs, newspapers, newsletters. All face-to-face interviews were conducted with 10 accelerators at their offices in Ankara and Istanbul from March 2016 to January 2017.

Our findings indicate that accelerators build selection committees consisting of many stakeholders, especially potential investors. During this process, accelerators select their startups based on entrepreneurial opportunity and how the team suits to execute the opportunity, as many previous studies have already indicated (Huang and Pearce 2015). However, our study underlines the quality of the team as the key in selection decisions. We find out that accelerators pick startups with latent qualities that would be appreciated by other stakeholders. Thus, the selected startups can access private funding. Startups that are effortlessly coachable, willing to collaborate with accelerators, mentors, or other actors, and passionate enough to overcome the pressure of creating a business at a fast pace possess such latent qualities.

Further, our findings show that the selection process is critical for accelerators to build a well-functioning acceleration process that serves startups and investors. Accelerators prefer to work with entrepreneurial teams which are coachable, passionate and collaborative to be trained to vibrate the right signals. By selecting such entrepreneurial teams that vibrate positive signals and by directing and training them to transmit the “right” signals to receivers, namely investors, accelerators support entrepreneurial teams access to external resources and scale quickly. Similarly, the research shows how the selection process helps investors by decreasing signaling noise and mitigate information asymmetry.

This paper is organized as follows. Section 2 reviews the theoretical underpinnings of startup selection and screening by focusing on signaling theory. Section 3 describes the data collection procedures and methodology. Section 4 reveals the main results of the research, and followed by a final section discussing the implications and limitations of the research and possible topics for future research.

2 Background

Y-Combinator, launched in 2005, is the first accelerator, and since then, 579 accelerators have started globally with investments in more than 11 thousand startups (Gust 2016). For a decade, scholarly attention to understanding accelerators and their impact has been significantly increasing (Crişan et al. 2021). Some of the previous research aims to understand and explain the phenomenon of an accelerator and its specificities (Cohen and Hochberg 2014; Hausberg and Korreck 2020). Some others investigate how an accelerator differs from incubation programs (Galbraith, McAdam, and Cross 2019; Hughes, Ireland, and Morgan 2007; Sansone et al. 2020). Nevertheless, several studies consider accelerators as a new form of organization with a diverse set of business models and operating in different contexts (e.g., university accelerator, social accelerator, corporate accelerator, ecosystem builder accelerator) (Pandey et al. 2017; Pauwels et al. 2016; Prexl et al. 2019). Further, some studies are interested in the impact of accelerators on cohort firms (Hallen, Cohen, and Bingham 2020; Stayton and Mangematin 2019) or entrepreneurship ecosystems (Goswami, Mitchell, and Bhagavatula 2018; Qin, Wright, and Gao 2019). However, as Shankar and Clausen (2020) underline, there is a dearth of studies in understanding the mechanisms of accelerators. This study focuses on the selection process at accelerators.

It is not easy to fully explain the rationale behind selection (Chen, Yao, and Kotha 2009; Hisrich and Jankowicz 1990; Navis and Glynn 2011). Navis and Glynn (2011) suggest that evaluators generally make their selection on gut feeling. The background and personality of entrepreneurs, the characteristics of management teams, and the chemistry between entrepreneurs and selectors are the main factors that influence gut feeling (Hisrich and Jankowicz 1990). Under extreme uncertainty and strong information asymmetries, quick decisions are made based on limited information hidden in various signals sent by startups (Busenitz, Fiet, and Moesel 2005; Huang and Pearce 2015; Kirsch, Goldfarb, and Gera 2009).

Signaling theory is used to explain the behaviors and actions of two parties – who have access to different information – that are taken to decrease the asymmetries between themselves (Connelly et al. 2011). In the entrepreneurship literature, signaling theory is used to understand how new ventures signal the possible future outcomes that they can achieve (Busenitz, Fiet, and Moesel 2005; Connelly et al. 2011; Gimmon and Levie 2010; Higgins and Gulati 2006; Yang, Kher, and Newbert 2020). Entrepreneurial teams have better knowledge about team capabilities, the product they developed, the embedded technology, and possible market entry outcomes. Outsiders (i.e., investors) do not have the same information. In such an environment with information asymmetry, startups (signalers) take actions (signals) to communicate their value to investors (receivers) (Busenitz, Fiet, and Moesel 2005; Connelly et al. 2011; Gubitta, Tognazzo, and Destro 2016). For example, a startup in an accelerator could use its prototype as a signal to show investors the level of readiness of the idea or pass the reality test of the idea by showing its working sample, model, or just a simulation of the actual product (Yin and Luo 2018).

Not all signals are effective; efficacious signals are observable and costly (Connelly et al. 2011). Signal observability refers to how signals are noticeable by the outsiders, and the signal cost is linked to the associated costs of vibrating a signal (Connelly et al. 2011). In the case of accelerators, demo days increase the signal observability for each startup and their signaling costs because only the startups that have achieved certain milestones are allowed to present in demo days. Signals are created, sent, received, and interpreted in a social context (in our case, the entrepreneurial ecosystem). Therefore, whether signals are observable to receivers, and whether the signaler sends these signals to the receiver in forms that are easily observed and interpreted deserves further discussion.

New organizations can signal organizational legitimacy to affect the decisions of resource holders (Busenitz, Fiet, and Moesel 2005; Higgins and Gulati 2006; Kirsch, Goldfarb, and Gera 2009). In an ideal situation, both signalers and receivers share common understandings of valuable signals. However, under extreme uncertainty, decision-makers rely on signals that mimic familiar, appropriate, and acceptable (DiMaggio and Powell 1983; Kirsch, Goldfarb, and Gera 2009). Zacharakis and Shepherd (2001) suggest that VCs are more confident with decisions based on information framed familiarly. When decision-makers need to decide fast under extreme uncertainty, they categorize the actions and activities of new ventures by using some relevant templates, norms, and guidelines which point out some shared typifications regarding what is appropriate and acceptable (Barley and Tolbert 1997; Navis and Glynn 2011; Suchman 1995).

Nonetheless, every signal that startups vibrate does not easily fit into typical categories. Decision-makers can be blind to such signals, or, in some cases, the observability of a signal might be obscured by other signals that better fit these categories. Feeney, Haines, and Riding (1999) reveal that the poor management capacity of the entrepreneurial team is the main deal-killer for investors. Maxwell, Jeffrey, and Levesque (2011) argue that it is time-consuming for business angels to collect and evaluate all information needed to make a final decision. Therefore, they consider a smaller set of information to reject a large number of opportunities. The existence of red-flagged signals prevents investors from considering other positive signals in decision-making. Startups that are aware of such deal-killer signals can take actions not to vibrate these signals and manage their impression over possible investors (Maxwell, Jeffrey, and Levesque 2011).

The literature drives us to conclude that despite the heterogeneity among resource holders, they rely on the signals that conform to the prevailing norms of the legitimate venture when making a decision (DiMaggio and Powell 1983). These norms are collectively created, shared, and reproduced by resource holders and startups. Accelerators are part of this web of interactions in which common understandings regarding the appropriate and acceptable organizations are emerged, shared, reproduced, or reframed, and attain legitimacy. Accelerators select startups based on these prevailing norms and mitigate the information asymmetry for investors and other resource holders. Guerini and Quas (2016) suggest that startups that are previously funded by government venture capital are more likely to receive private venture capital since government VC funding decreases the information asymmetry for private VCs by selecting and screening promising startups.

Accelerators are engaged in the entrepreneurial social context and share similar norms with investors and other resource holders. Shared values, norms, and common understandings increase interaction and communication, thus decrease information asymmetry and build trust among actors (Edwards and Cable 2009; Gulati and Sytch 2008). Endorsements by accelerators increase signaling costs and decrease the possibility of cheating or false signaling (Gubitta, Tognazzo, and Destro 2016). These reputable organizations mobilize their resources to enhance new ventures’ potential (Lee, Pollock, and Jin 2011), thus reduce uncertainty (Connelly et al. 2011; Gubitta, Tognazzo, and Destro 2016). This situation increases the cost of signaling for accelerators. Since accelerators invest money, time, and effort to nurture new ventures, they risk their reputation in the case of false signaling to other stakeholders (Pollock and Gulati 2007).

This research focuses on accelerators’ selection and screening process and the criteria they apply to select startups.

3 Methodology

This paper investigates the details of the entrepreneur selection process that accelerators implement. To answer what mechanisms and criteria that accelerators use to select startups and how those mechanisms and selection criteria serve startups and investors, we rely on qualitative inductive methodology using multiple cases (Eisenhardt 1989; Eisenhardt and Graebner 2007). The number of cases increases the robustness and generalizability of findings and leads to more meaningful theoretical conclusions (Eisenhardt and Graebner 2007; Yin 2014). Even though we collected some secondary data to support our cases, this paper’s primary method is a multiple case study, a separate and all-encompassing method with its research design (Yin 2014).

3.1 Research Context

Creating interfaces such as accelerators to establish and enhance innovation is a critical component of Turkish technology and innovation policy. Such interfaces as organizations, connected firms and entrepreneurs, and the professionals working in the interfaces define an environment where technology-based entrepreneurship flourishes.

As of 2020, there are 57 accelerators in Turkey (Investment Office 2020) in various sizes and forms, most of which are located in either Ankara or Istanbul. Accelerators have been well received by the other actors of the entrepreneurship ecosystem. The number of accelerators increased approximately 10-folds from 6 in 2010 to 57 in 2020. However, when the fieldwork started in 2016, there were 24 accelerators in Turkey. Most accelerators in Turkey were formed to organize certain elements (intangible services to obtain fast traction) of the entrepreneurship support activities already present in prominent universities in Ankara and Istanbul. Due to law, some accelerators are organized under the university technology park or the university’s technology transfer office. Only a few of the accelerators are private or sponsored by corporations, municipalities, or non-government organizations.

3.2 Sample Selection

Accelerators differ from incubators in many aspects (Cohen and Hochberg 2014; Cohen et al. 2019; Galbraith, McAdam, and Cross 2019; Pauwels et al. 2016; Sansone et al. 2020); for instance, the duration of the program is shorter than incubators, and they accept startups in cohorts. Due to the high number of applications, most of the accelerators use a staged selection system. At the first stage, applications are evaluated based on information provided by applicants through a web-based system. Then, at the second stage, the successors of the first stage receive an invitation for an interview (Yin and Luo 2018).

As a first step, we made a list of accelerators that we would interview for this research by collecting secondary data from newspapers, magazines, public agencies, and the websites of accelerators. We considered three criteria for selecting cases:

  1. a history of continued operations: Some accelerators have sustainability problems, some cease to exist, and some are very small in size. The selected accelerators have a certain scale and continuing operations for more than a year (see Table 1, column 2).

  2. the duration of the acceleration: It ranges from several weeks to one year (see Table 1, column 3).

  3. cohort-based selection: The selected accelerators have well-defined application and selection processes in cohorts (see Table 1, column 4).

Table 1:

Selection procedure of accelerators.

Accelerator Year founded Duration of the support Selection procedure of applicants
A 2011 5 weeks intense + 3 months Applications are collected online. Two-stage selection process: At the first stage of selection, the manager and a mentor make the selection. In the second stage, a jury of entrepreneurs, investors, and representatives from various corporations select.
B 2008 At most 1 year Applications are collected online. Two-stage selection process: At the first stage of selection, the manager and the experts of the acceleration program make the selection. In the second stage, a jury of 40 people, including professionals from corporations, investors, entrepreneurs, and academics, select.
C 2012 At most 1 year, first 8 weeks intense Applications are collected online. Single-stage selection process: Selection is made by a small group of evaluators, including the manager, the business development coordinator, and a few accelerator mentors.
D 2015 6 months with possible extension of six months Applications are collected online. Two-stage selection process: At the first stage of selection, accelerator experts carry out the first evaluation. In the second stage, a jury of angel investors, representatives from VCs, managers of corporations select.
E 2013 9 months, first six weeks intense Applications are collected online. Two-stage selection process: After evaluation by the experts in the first stage, the successors are assessed by a jury of about 10 people, in the second stage, including angel investors, representatives from VCs, managers of various corporations, and academics.
F 2012 5 months Applications are collected online. Two-stage selection process: Applications are first evaluated by accelerator managers; the remaining projects are evaluated by a jury, in the second stage, including a minimum of 3 people from the sponsor organization.
G 2015 3 months Applications are collected online. Two-stage selection process: At the first stage, accelerator managers assess the applications. At the second stage, a jury including representatives from sponsor organizations, mentors, and investors evaluate applicants.
H 2008 Flexible Applications are collected online: A group of five selectors evaluates all applicants in several stages until they agree on a set of startups.
I 2005 6 months Applications are collected online. Three-stage selection process: In the first stage, accelerator experts select through the information provided in the online application form. In the second stage, the remaining applications are evaluated according to written criteria, and at the third stage, the applicants with high scores are invited to present. The selection committee at the third stage includes members from university, sponsoring organizations, and entrepreneurs
J 2010 4 months intense then follow-up There is no online application process. Accelerator managers first investigate the startups in technoparks, incubations etc. (first stage). From a set of identified startups, the ones which are positively evaluated by the managers and the experts, in the second stage, are selected to nurture.
  1. Source: Our interviews, websites, and newsletters.

We identified about 15 accelerators that fit the above criteria in Turkey (out of 24 that existed when the fieldwork started in 2016). The accelerators in Ankara and Istanbul were contacted, and 10 accelerators agreed to participate in the research. All accelerators in our sample use a staged selection system where at least in the second stage, a jury or a committee decides on the applicants’ faith. Turkish Economist (Ekonomist 2018) reports about more than six thousand startups that have benefited from the acceleration services as of January 2018, 75% of which were officially registered in six accelerators in our sample (Accelerators B, C, D, E, F, and I in Table 2). Table 2 provides brief information on the selected accelerators, the role of the interviewee, and the date of the interview.

Table 2:

Summary information on the selected accelerators.

Accelerator Location Role of the Interviewee Date of the interview
A Istanbul Program Manager March 2016
B Ankara Program Director August 2016
C Istanbul Program Coordinator April 2016
D Istanbul Program Coordinator March 2016
E Istanbul Program Coordinator January 2017
F Istanbul Project Manager May 2016
G Istanbul Managing Director June 2016
H Istanbul Business Development Specialist September 2016
I Ankara Program Director November 2016
J Ankara Owner-Manager November 2016

3.3 Data Collection and Analysis

The data used in the empirical research was collected from two sources: primary data came from the transcribed semi-structured in-depth interviews and site visits, while secondary data was collected on literature review and archival data (such as accelerators’ websites, blogs, newspapers, newsletters). Archival data were mainly used to select accelerators, prepare for the semi-structured interviews, open up new questions in interviews, and supplement interview data. Thus, data triangulation has secured our interviews to be carried out with a representative group of accelerators. This approach of using supplementary data to improve a primary set of collected data has been widely used in the literature (e.g., Sklyara et al. 2019).

We interviewed accelerator managers at their offices face-to-face and observed their operations and their relationship with startups at these visits. All interviews were conducted from March 2016 to January 2017. During these interviews, a set of questions were asked to collect information about the organizational structure of accelerators, history of operations, general processes before and after the selection, detailed information about selection and selection committees, selection criteria, the definition of an ideal startup. The length of the interviews was between 45 and 90 min. All of them were recorded and transcripted.

As consistent with inductive research methodology (Bryman and Bell 2007), first, we tried to understand how startups are selected by different actors such as VCs, business angels, incubators, and accelerators. After an intense literature review on startup selection, the authors reviewed the transcripts and field notes. Two of the authors made the first contacts with accelerator managers, field visits, and face-to-face interviews. An iterative process was used to analyze the information embodied in transcribed interviews and compare and contrast the analysis with the theory. We conducted a peer evaluation process (Miles and Huberman 1994). All authors contributed to coding by carrying out independent parallel analysis of data items, but all codes are based on consensus (Bryman and Bell 2007). Thus, we did not conduct an inter-judge reliability test.

We searched for themes that we drew from previous research; however, we embraced the new ones. This iterative process involved drafting themes and sub-themes that emerged from face-to-face interviews and the data collected from secondary resources. We looked for emergent codes and statements in the transcripts, grouped these codes under sub-themes and themes, and re-read the transcripts to edge the sub-themes and interpret the findings (Bryman and Bell 2007; Denzin and Lincoln 2000; Stake 1995). The first read of the transcripts was based on the themes from the literature and produced various codes (column 2, Table 3) that derives from actual statements (column 1, Table 3). Then these codes were refined and matched to sub-themes (column 4, Table 3) (Gioia, Corley, and Hamilton 2012). Once a draft code-sub-themes and themes structure was ready, a second read was conducted for the robustness of the analysis. The final analysis produced 21 codes grouped under five sub-themes of selection (columns 2 and 4, Table 3). Previous research that scrutinizes the role of sub-themes in startup selection is also provided in Table 3 (column 3). Finally, these sub-themes are grouped under two main themes of startup selection, “business opportunity” and “team” (column 5, Table 3). We reviewed each case and checked how these five sub-themes appear in the interviews at the final stage. The common recurring sub-themes can be viewed as criteria of startup selection to accelerators.

Table 3:

Analysis of the interviews: codes and themes of the selection process.

Statements from the interviews Codes Related literature Sub-themes Themes
Can it be commercialized? (C); how quickly can it go to the market? (D); a ready prototype takes the project far front (E); if it doesn’t involve innovation and pursue in the existing market, we eliminate (F); at least we look for a prototype (G); what problem it addresses is very important for us (H); does the idea fix a problem? (J) Tangible, realistic, innovative, prototype, time to commercialization Audretsch, Bönte, and Mahagaonkar (2012);

Tyebjee and Bruno (1984)
Business idea Business opportunity
Spending money on entering a crowded market is meaningless (A); how big is the market? How many competitors? (D); once we see it is scalable, we say yes, this is it (E); is there a sufficiently large market? (I); once the idea comes, is it sustainable? can it expand globally? (J) Size of the market, scalability, competition Mason and Stork (2004);

Feeney, Haines, and Riding (1999)
Market
They talk about a technology business, but do they have such background, experience? (A); what do they want to do? Do they have experience? (B); if it is a technology startup, one founder should have a technology background (G); we want the nuclear competence within the team (J) Technological competence, business competence, previous experience, expertise Hisrich and Jankowicz (1990); Baum and Silverman (2004);

Gimmon and Levie (2010);

Foo (2010);

Becker-Blease and Sohl (2015)
Capacity and competence Team
We look whether they are open to change their mindset (A); some walk alone, but we guide them; take a seller; take a designer (C); if he/she does not want to try and is stubborn, it is not good for us (D); how loyal is the team to each other? Are there disagreements? (F); we look at team harmony (H) Team level harmony, diversity in teams,

coachability of teams, team flexibility, team-accelerator harmony
Haines, Madill, and Riding (2003);

Franke et al. (2008);

Ciuchta et al. (2018)
Coordination harmony
The kid genuinely dedicates himself (A); do they want to stick their neck out? (D); Ambitious? Will they give importance to the business; an entrepreneur must sacrifice or risk something (E); entrepreneurship experience is more valuable than corporate experience. We want them to have accomplished something (F); we want them to be full-time entrepreneurs and give their full energy (H) Persistence, dedication, preparedness, entrepreneurship story Busenitz, Fiet, and Moesel (2005);

Chen, Yao, and Kotha (2009);

Elsbach and Kramer (2003);

Pollack, Rutherford, and Nagy (2012);

Cardon, Mitteness, and Sudek (2017)
Commitment and passion

4 Findings

The observations of the case studies explicate the significant role of selection committees and selection criteria in accelerators’ selection process. The details are discussed in-depth below.

4.1 The Engagement of Various Actors through Selection Committees

Accelerators aim to attract high-quality teams in each cohort. Social media and websites are the basic channels for reaching potential entrepreneurial teams. They collect applications on different occasions via web-based forms as well. In the first step, evaluations are made using the information in these forms, and most applicants are eliminated based on available or missing information. Application forms include questions which help applicants to better explain the entrepreneurial opportunity they have discovered, and their business model. One interviewee (Interviewee D) mentioned “what you make different and how you make it different? Who are the customers? What are your unique resources? Applicants have difficulties answering such questions”. This sharp trimming down makes further screening affordable. If acceleration experts are not sure about the appropriateness of a startup, they contact applicants face-to-face or on the phone to get the details about the entrepreneurial opportunity and the team. Sometimes they are given advice on how to improve their projects. By spending time with startups in this process, accelerators get closer to startups.

In the second step, selection committees make the final selection. The size of the selection jury ranges from three to 40. Most of the accelerators in Turkey invite angel investors, industry representatives, sponsor organizations, mentors, or influential serial entrepreneurs to their selection committees. By doing so, they open up the communication channels and increases the interaction between investors and accelerators and also between investors and startups. Accelerators have the chance to learn more about the concerns and expectations of investors and the type of startups they are willing to invest. In these selection committees, norms and understandings regarding the new ventures are exchanged, discussed, and opened to negotiations. Accelerators interact vividly with potential investors. As stated by one interviewee, “inviting investors to our selection committees is a signal to investors: t hese startups will be brought to you when they are seeking investment. Now, you need to tell us what you want. Then we will find those startups for you” (Interviewee D).

The interaction between investors and accelerators is not limited to the selection process. It continues in different forms; for example, some investors serve as mentors in accelerations, and can benefit from information flow from accelerators about the startups under their tenants. These interactions help them select the most appropriate startups to invest and close the information gap between investors and startups. Thus, accelerators build trust on behalf of the investors that the accelerator will bring them what they want (as emphasized by Interviewee D). These interactions are also valuable to accelerators to learn more about the appropriate signals a startup needs to vibrate to access resources. In that way, they can sense the products, markets that investors are most interested in, or the team qualifications that are concerned by investors and the appropriate ways of showing off these qualifications.

Our research indicates that program managers and experts make their decisions very quickly, especially at the first round of selection, where they need to downsize hundreds of applications into reasonable amounts. Nevertheless, the experts in accelerators have a chance to spend more time with applicants to observe them. They learn more about entrepreneurs’ backgrounds, motivations, what they did so far for their project, and their future projections and work together to understand how teams take the feedbacks and respond to them. For example, “we are giving small assignments; such as a competitor analysis. Their returns and works in this process give us a lot of clues about how they are serious. Most of the time, an application form is not enough” (Interviewee E). Accelerators trim the most appropriate entrepreneurial teams and opportunities that are likely to be invested. They eliminate red-flagged startups, which cannot vibrate the “right” signals. Thus, accelerators clean the noise and find out the most appropriate new ventures for investors by reducing information asymmetry.

Accelerators bring investors into the startup selection process. Accelerators prefer to engage investors in the selection process to assess better startups’ potential to achieve product-market fit and quick scalability. Additionally, it helps them build relations with investors that could provide private funding as quickly as possible since it is a matter of survival and the key to scaling fast for startups. As stated by Interviewee A, most of these accelerators have close connections with angel investors and most of these investors serve as mentors to startups: “we are well connected to angel investor networks… In one of the mentorship sessions, one of our angel investor mentors very much liked the presentation of a startup. He wanted to work with them voluntarily. Now they are working together 2–3 days a week. He has not invested yet but wants to mentor them for now”.

In connection with other supporting mechanisms, selection mechanisms applied by accelerators generate benefits for both parties by reducing the information asymmetries among investors and startups. They eliminate the red-flagged startups at very early stages for investors by bringing investors’ concerns and expectations forward in the selection mechanisms and training startups to vibrate positive signals to investors. In this environment, private investment actors can shape the new ventures’ context and growth (Baum and Silverman 2004).

4.2 Selection Criteria for Entrepreneurial Teams

Due to high uncertainty and ambiguity, it is difficult to decide based on future projections of an entrepreneurial project. Therefore, most of the experts/managers of the accelerators emphasize that they do not consider the financial projections of a startup for selection and screening. From the interviews, two main selection criteria emerge: the entrepreneurial opportunity and the team. Although these two criteria are common in the selection, there are still differences among accelerators. The criteria applied to startups are essential to understand how new ventures are selected by accelerators and the impact of selecting entrepreneurial activities and the ecosystem.

The first criterion is the entrepreneurial opportunity, consisting of concerns about the problem, value proposition, innovativeness, and market-related issues such as market size. The second criterion covers founder and team characteristics. It ranges from the technological and business-related competencies of founders to their passion. Figure 1 depicts salient signals which are considered by accelerators while selecting entrepreneurial teams to nurture.

Figure 1: 
Criteria applied to startups in the selection and screening process.
Source: Interviews.
Figure 1:

Criteria applied to startups in the selection and screening process.

Source: Interviews.

The market addressed by the entrepreneurial team is critical in the evaluation process. One of the interviewees suggests that “the problem gives us an idea about the market” (Interviewee A). However, how the designated problem is solved is as important as the problem. The solution needs to be innovative and offer something new to customers. Nonetheless, acceleration managers are aware of the difficulties of creating a new market. One of the interviewees explained that “it is meaningless to create a product which does not have an existing market” (Interviewee H). This point reminds us the concept of legitimate distinctiveness (Navis and Glynn 2011). Having an innovative idea is a positive signal to attract the attention of accelerator experts. However, this innovative solution must address an existing market that is easily identifiable by investors and other stakeholders. Creating an entirely new market is challenging, time-consuming, and expensive. The novelty of entrepreneurial opportunities is appreciated up to a limit. When the entrepreneurial opportunity is latent, target customers and market size are not identified. Then, innovativeness and novelty can even turn into an obstacle. In such a situation, the signal does not fit the receiver’s expectations.

Similarly, as the time needed to commercialize the entrepreneurial opportunity increases, the probability of being selected by any accelerator decreases. This criterion limits the technology fields that accelerators prefer. They mostly prefer technologies and products that can be developed quickly and have an easily identifiable market. A working prototype is the most valuable signal to measure the required time to market, which is a step toward being selected.

Interviewees frequently mention that team characteristics and composition are the most important factors they consider in screening and selection. Our research reveals that acceleration experts consider many different factors related to entrepreneurial teams. These factors consist of characteristics such as passion and commitment exhibited by entrepreneurs, fields of education, knowledge about markets, preparedness, coachability of teams, diversity in entrepreneurial teams, and chemistry among team members. The technical and business-related capabilities of entrepreneurial team members are interpreted as valuable signals of how well the team fits the opportunity. Acceleration experts generally do not have expertise in technological fields, and therefore cannot provide mentoring or training to support startups in relevant problems. Thus, the teams capable of solving technical problems are also seen as critical for the sustainability of startups. For accelerators, the educational background of founders is a signal to measure the capabilities of entrepreneurial teams. The signal of business-related capabilities is not formal education or relevant industry experience but instead team members’ attitudes and willingness to engage in business-related activities.

In most cases, technical competencies create a disadvantage for entrepreneurial teams because they focus too much on the product’s technical qualifications and ignore customers. How team members work together, how long they know each other, and how they allocate the responsibilities within the team are also valued as “right” signals. One of our interviewees reveals that “we are looking for people who are very good at technical issues but also they can easily communicate with people, be persuasive and be capable in bargaining, and develop themselves in selling and marketing” (Interviewee E).

Two signals are remarkably voiced in the interviews: passion revealed by entrepreneurial teams and whether they are coachable or not. Though it is difficult to observe and measure entrepreneurial passion, we identified several signals regarding teams’ commitment to the entrepreneurial process’s overwhelming requirements and preparedness. The willingness of entrepreneurial teams to dedicate their full time to entrepreneurial activities is taken as a positive signal. The personal investments of team members in their project is also a “right” signal. One of the interviewees emphasizes that “if an entrepreneur does not risk her savings for this project, it means that she does not believe in her project” (Interviewee E). Signals of commitment are critical for accelerators to distinguish applicants who persist in their entrepreneurial endeavors. As previous research emphasizes, entrepreneurial passion is manifested in behaviors and narratives of teams (Chen, Yao, and Kotha 2009; Pollack, Rutherford, and Nagy 2012). We find that building a prototype, doing market research, building networks, benchmarking the product with existing competitors, even having some ideas about target customer segments, markets, and telling a consistent story about the emergence of business are perceived as the signals of preparedness and entrepreneurial passion by the interviewed accelerators. The flexibility of entrepreneurs and their willingness to collaborate with managers/experts are seen as eminent signals of coachable entrepreneurial teams. In literature, coachability is defined as “the degree to which an entrepreneur seeks, carefully considers, and integrates feedback to improve his or her venture’s performance” (Ciuchta et al. 2018, p.861). Our interviewees emphasize that entrepreneurs must be open to collaboration with accelerator managers, experts, and mentors to improve their entrepreneurial projects further. They must be open to constructive criticism and pivot their projects when it is necessary. Interviewee D states that “in order to benefit from the services provided by our program, they have to be open to criticism and change… if an entrepreneur does not want to try what we advise her to improve the project, we do not want to work with her”.

Due to the high uncertainty and ambiguity, it is difficult to make realistic projections for experts about a proposed entrepreneurial project. They focus on signals vibrating the quality of the teams, the fit of the team to the opportunity, and the founders’ passion and commitment. If the experts observe positive signals in a team, they are more likely to invest in time and effort. Interviewees emphasize their unwillingness to spend their limited resources on teams that lack passion and commitment or those that would eventually disband due to disputes among the team members.

The criteria applied by accelerators resemble those applied by investors to make investment decisions (as shown in Table 3). In most cases, accelerators include a wide range of audiences (i.e., entrepreneurs, business angels, VCs) in their selection process (Clarysse, Wright, and van Hove 2016; Leatherbee and Gonzalez-Uribe 2018). Intense interaction and exchange between investors and accelerators in the selection process and inviting investors to the selection process increase the probability of uniform understandings of the appropriate or acceptable new ventures. In the selection process, accelerators reproduce common understandings about an appropriate and eligible startup (Meyer and Rowan 1977). Signals of legitimate organizations are created and reproduced in every instance by accelerators, investors, mentors, and startups. Some signals become more observable and easily recognized and interpreted by receivers, while others are ignored. In sum, our study shows that accelerators act as a substitute for investors while selecting the startups to nurture.

Inexperienced entrepreneurial teams are not aware of the right signals to vibrate to access funding. During the acceleration process, as one of our interviewees briefly explains, “the proposed entrepreneurial project is shaken, deconstructed and reconstructed by entrepreneurs in collaboration with program experts, mentors, and trainers” (Interviewee G). The entrepreneurial narrative is rewritten in this process in collaboration. Accelerators help entrepreneurs to reconstruct their entrepreneurial opportunities and narratives. Startups learn how to vibrate the right signals and vibrate them in the right form (Busenitz, Fiet, and Moesel 2005; Higgins and Gulati 2006; Kirsch, Goldfarb, and Gera 2009). Accelerators coach startups to vibrate positive signals in an appropriate form. Therefore, accelerators tend to select the most coachable, open to collaboration, passionate, and willing to be committed startups. As the number of successful startups increases, the reputation of accelerators and their capabilities to mobilize external resources increase too. This reputation works as a positive signal to possible investors.

5 Conclusions and Implications

Accelerators are one of the actors of entrepreneurship ecosystems and influence the institutional context and the definition of ideal startups. Their role in making startups access private funds is apparent in many studies (e.g., Drori and Wright 2018; GALI 2018). Our research focuses on screening and selection procedures and criteria in accelerators. The startup selection process is one of the most important value creation mechanisms in accelerators. However, how this mechanism works is not well-scrutinized in the literature until recently (Yin and Luo 2018; Zarei, Rasti-Barzoki and Moon, 2022). Relying on the qualitative analysis of the face-to-face interviews with the managers of accelerators in Turkey, this research sheds light on selection and screening mechanisms in accelerators and their possible implications.

5.1 Implications for Theory

This paper offers two contributions to the literature on accelerators. First, the findings help us understand the selection in accelerators as a complex process involving multiple actors. Accelerators overcome the uncertainty in their context by involving various actors in the selection process. The collaborations within the selection committees facilitate a futile ground for communication among accelerators, startups, and investors. This research also exhibits the criteria applied by accelerators in Turkey to select startups to nurture. Our findings show that accelerators focus on opportunity and team, with specific emphasis on team members’ characteristics, including coachable, open to collaboration, passionate, and willing to be committed entrepreneurs. These findings resemble how VCs and angel investors select their own invested entrepreneurs (Huang and Pearce 2015; MacMillan, Siegel, and Narasimha 1985). Second, our findings support previous research that suggests that accelerators are more connected to investors in the selection process (Clarysse, Wright, and van Hove 2016; Leatherbee and Gonzalez-Uribe 2018). But they also exhibit how these connections help the quick scalability of startups in accelerators. By including investors in selection committees and applying selection criteria resembling those of investors, accelerators substitute investors and trim down the startups which cannot attract investment and hence cannot quickly scale. Furthermore, by preferring coachable, passionate, and willing to be committed entrepreneurs, accelerators spend their resources on those that they can train to reach milestones faster and therefore vibrate positive signals to prospective investors.

5.2 Implications for Practice

There are some practical implications of accelerators behaving as receivers and signalers in the selection and screening process. On the investors/resource holders’ side, investors’ engagement in the selection process in accelerators may lead to a well-functioning and more effective selection. Moreover, new venture teams who are less suffered from information asymmetry can manage their impressions over resource holders, increase their chance to access private funds (Maxwell, Jeffrey, and Levesque 2011), and help their accelerator gain a reputation in the ecosystem. In a developing country context, this would increase the number of business angels and the total amount of seed funding provided to startups, attracting more foreign VCs and increasing the number of seed-funded startups as observed in the Turkish case (Investment Office 2020). The interaction among different actors of the entrepreneurship ecosystem would increase and become more institutionalized.

However, some unintended practical implications may also be observed. Bringing investor selection and selection criteria backward to earlier stages of the startup life cycle may confront the entrepreneurial teams’ market selection biases very early. For example, they might eliminate some disadvantaged groups, e.g., female lead entrepreneurial teams (Lall, Chen, and Roberts 2020; Yang, Kher, and Newbert 2020). Also, the early involvement of investors might be biased to entrepreneurial teams with radical product/service innovations or deep-tech innovations in which the problem/need is latent, and the market is not foreseen. Since the entrepreneurs with radical ideas may not be easily coachable (Ciuchta et al. 2018), they can be dropped out of the system where the resources are scarce. The risk for accelerators might be selecting startups with low impact and identical or resembling products/services in motivation to increase the number of startups funded by private investors. In the long run, this problem may lead to a decrease in the efficiency of the acceleration system and may create a reverse impact on their reputation. It would be beneficial for accelerators to be self-reflective about their selection procedure and revise it to ensure variety in each cohort.

In sum, accelerators bring many advantages to stakeholders of the entrepreneurial ecosystem. Startups get early access to finance, while investors identify worthy startups. Accelerators become critical mediating agents in the ecosystem thanks to their efforts to reduce uncertainty and increase seed funding efficiency.

5.3 Limitations and Future Research

This explorative study has four main limitations that might become opportunities for further studies. First, this study exploits a limited number of in-depth interviews with accelerator managers in Turkey. Hence, our findings’ generalizability may increase if similar studies covering accelerators in other countries are conducted to compare findings across different contexts. Second, the study focuses on the selection process in accelerators, while other activities such as networking and mechanisms to improve startups’ market presence and survival might also influence the performance of startups. Third, our research does not consider the negative impact of the selection processes in accelerators. Bringing investor selection to the early stages may lead to the institutionalization of “a certain type of startup.” As observed in our interviews, the selection mechanism emphasizes picking the winners. Such a selection mechanism might create biases against some startups that develop radical or disruptive technologies with high market uncertainties and longer time-to-market, eventually reducing heterogeneity in the entrepreneurship ecosystem. Finally, this study interviews accelerator managers, while future studies should interview other stakeholders involved in the selection process and entrepreneurs who are selected into accelerators. An additional research avenue might be conducting quantitative studies to understand the impact of different selection processes on the final performances of the accelerators.


Corresponding author: Berna Beyhan, Sabanci Business School, Sabanci University, Istanbul, Turkey, E-mail:

Funding source: Türkiye Bilimsel ve Teknolojik Araştırma Kurumu (TÜBİTAK)

Award Identifier / Grant number: 115K204

  1. Research funding: We would like to thank Türkiye Bilimsel ve Teknolojik Araştırma Kurumu (TÜBİTAK) for their support (grant number SOBAG 115K204), and our anonymous reviewers for their valuable insights and constructive comments to improve the paper.

References

Audretsch, D., W. Bönte, and P. Mahagaonkar. 2012. “Financial Signaling by Innovative Nascent Ventures: The Relevance of Patents and Prototypes.” Research Policy 41 (8): 1407–21, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2012.02.003.Search in Google Scholar

Barley, S. R., and P. S. Tolbert. 1997. “Institutionalization and Structuration: Studying the Links between Action and Institution.” Organization Studies 18 (1): 93–117, https://doi.org/10.1177/017084069701800106.Search in Google Scholar

Baum, J. A. C., and B. S. Silverman. 2004. “Picking Winners or Building Them? Alliance, Intellectual, and Human Capital as Selection Criteria in Venture Financing and Performance of Biotechnology Startups.” Journal of Business Venturing 19: 411–36, https://doi.org/10.1016/s0883-9026(03)00038-7.Search in Google Scholar

Becker-Blease, J. R., and J. E. Sohl. 2015. “New Venture Legitimacy: The Conditions for Angel Investors.” Small Business Economics 45: 735–49, https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-015-9668-7.Search in Google Scholar

Bryman, A., and E. Bell. 2007. Business Research Methods. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Search in Google Scholar

Busenitz, L. W., J. O. Fiet, and D. D. Moesel. 2005. “Signaling in Venture Capitalist-New Venture Team Funding Decisions: Does it Indicate Long-Term Venture Outcomes?” Entrepreneurship: Theory and Practice 29 (1): 1–12, https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6520.2005.00066.x.Search in Google Scholar

Cardon, M. S., C. Mitteness, and R. Sudek. 2017. “Motivational Cues and Angel Investing: Interactions Among Enthusiasm, Preparedness, and Commitment.” Entrepreneurship: Theory and Practice 41 (6): 1057–85, https://doi.org/10.1111/etap.12255.Search in Google Scholar

Chen, X. P., X. Yao, and S. Kotha. 2009. “Entrepreneur Passion and Preparedness in Business Plan Presentations: A Persuasion Analysis of Venture Capitalists’ Funding Decisions.” Academy of Management Journal 52 (1): 199–214, https://doi.org/10.5465/amj.2009.36462018.Search in Google Scholar

Ciuchta, M. P., C. Letwin, R. Stevenson, S. McMahon, and M. N. Huvaj. 2018. “Betting on the Coachable Entrepreneur: Signaling and Social Exchange in Entrepreneurial Pitches.” Entrepreneurship: Theory and Practice 42 (6): 860–85, https://doi.org/10.1177/1042258717725520.Search in Google Scholar

Clarysse, B., M. Wright, and van Hove. 2016. “A Look Inside Accelerators in the United Kingdom: Building Technology Businesses.” In Technology Entrepreneurship and Business Incubation: Theory, Practice, Lesson Learned, edited by P. H. Phan, S. A. Mian, and W. Lamine, 57–86. London: Imperial College Press, https://doi.org/10.1142/9781783269778_0003.Search in Google Scholar

Crişan, E. L., I. Salanta, I. N. Beleiu, O. N. Bordean, and R. Bunduchi. 2021. “A Systematic Literature Review on Accelerators.” Journal of Technology Transfer 46: 62–89.10.1007/s10961-019-09754-9Search in Google Scholar

Cohen, S., D. C. Fehder, Y. Hochberg, and F. Murray. 2019. “The Design of Startup Accelerators.” Research Policy 48: 1781–97, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2019.04.003.Search in Google Scholar

Cohen, S. G., and Y. V. Hochberg. 2014. “Accelerating Startups: The Seed Accelerator Phenomenon.” Also available at https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2418000.Search in Google Scholar

Connelly, B., S. T. Certo, R. D. Ireland, and C. R. Reutzel. 2011. “Signaling Theory: A Review and Assessment.” Journal of Management 37 (1): 39–67, https://doi.org/10.1177/0149206310388419.Search in Google Scholar

Denzin, N. K., and Y. S. Lincoln. 2000. “Introduction: The Discipline and Practice of Qualitative Research.” In Handbook of Qualitative Research, edited by N. K. Denzin, and Y. S. Lincoln, 1–32. London: Sage.Search in Google Scholar

DiMaggio, P. J., and W. W. Powell. 1983. “The Iron Cage Revisited: Institutional Isomorphism and Collective Rationality in Organizational Fields.” American Sociological Review 48 (2): 147–60, https://doi.org/10.2307/2095101.Search in Google Scholar

Drori, I., and M. Wright. 2018. “Accelerators: Characteristics, Trends and the New Entrepreneurial Ecosystem.” In Accelerators: Successful Venture Creation and Growth, edited by Wright, and I. Drori, 1–20. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.10.4337/9781786434098.00005Search in Google Scholar

Edwards, J. R., and D. M. Cable. 2009. “The Value of Value Congruence.” Journal of Applied Psychology 94 (3): 654–77, https://doi.org/10.1037/a0014891.Search in Google Scholar

Eisenhardt, K. M. 1989. “Building Theories from the Case Study Research.” Academy of Management Review 14 (4): 532–50, https://doi.org/10.5465/amr.1989.4308385.Search in Google Scholar

Eisenhardt, K. M., and M. E. Graebner. 2007. “Building Theory from Cases: Opportunities and Challenges.” Academy of Management Journal 50 (1): 25–37, https://doi.org/10.5465/amj.2007.24160888.Search in Google Scholar

Elsbach, K. D., and R. M. Kramer. 2003. “Assessing Creativity in Hollywood Pitch Meetings: Evidence for a Dual Process Model of Creativity Judgments.” Academy of Management Journal 46: 283–301, https://doi.org/10.5465/30040623.Search in Google Scholar

Ekonomist. 2018. “Bu yıl ‘kuluçka’dan 1.105 start up çıkacak.” https://www.ekonomist.com.tr/girisim-kobi/bu-yil-kuluckadan-1-105-start-up-cikacak.html (accessed September 15, 2020).Search in Google Scholar

Feeney, L., G. H. HainesJr., and A. L. Riding. 1999. “Private Investors’ Investment Criteria: Insights from Qualitative Data.” Venture Capital 1 (2): 121–45, https://doi.org/10.1080/136910699295938.Search in Google Scholar

Foo, M. -D. 2010. “Member Experience, Use of External Assistance and Evaluation of Business Ideas.” Journal of Small Business Management 48 (1): 32–43, https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-627x.2009.00285.x.Search in Google Scholar

Franke, N., M. Gruber, D. Harhoff, and J. Henkel. 2008. “Venture Capitalists’ Evaluations of Startup Teams: Trade-Offs, Knock-Out Criteria, and the Impact of VC Experience.” Entrepreneurship: Theory and Practice 32 (3): 459–83, https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6520.2008.00236.x.Search in Google Scholar

Galbraith, B., R. McAdam, and S. E. Cross. 2019. “The Evolution of the Incubator: Past, Present, and Future.” IEEE Transactions on Engineering Management 68 (1): 265–71.10.1109/TEM.2019.2905297Search in Google Scholar

GALI. 2018. Accelerating the Flow of Funds into Early-Stage Ventures. https://www.galidata.org/assets/report/pdf/Accelerating%20the%20Flow%20of%20Funds%20into%20Early-Stage%20Ventures.pdf (accessed April 15, 2020).Search in Google Scholar

Gimmon, E., and J. Levie. 2010. “Founder’s Human Capital, External Investment, and the Survival of New High-Technology Ventures.” Research Policy 39 (9): 1214–26, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2010.05.017.Search in Google Scholar

Gioia, D. A., C. G. Corley, and A. M. Hamilton. 2012. “Seeking Qualitative Rigor in Inductive Research: Notes on the Gioia Methodology.” Organizational Research Methods 16 (1): 15–31, https://doi.org/10.1177/1094428112452151.Search in Google Scholar

Goswami, K., J. R. Mitchell, and S. Bhagavatula. 2018. “Accelerator Expertise: Understanding the Intermediary Role of Accelerators in the Development of the Bangalore Entrepreneurial Ecosystem.” Strategic Entrepreneurship Journal 12: 117–50, https://doi.org/10.1002/sej.1281.Search in Google Scholar

Gubitta, P., A. Tognazzo, and F. Destro. 2016. “Signaling in Academic Ventures: The Role of Technology Transfer Offices and University Funds.” Journal of Technology Transfer 41: 368–93, https://doi.org/10.1007/s10961-015-9398-7.Search in Google Scholar

Guerini, M., and A. Quas. 2016. “Government Venture Capital in Europe: Screening and Certification.” Journal of Business Venturing 31: 175–95.10.1016/j.jbusvent.2015.10.001Search in Google Scholar

Gulati, R., and M. Sytch. 2008. “Does Familiarity Breed Trust? Revisiting the Antecedents of Trust.” Management and Decision Economics 29 (2–3): 165–90, https://doi.org/10.1002/mde.1396.Search in Google Scholar

Gust. 2016. The Global Accelerator Report. http://gust.com/accelerator_reports/2016/global/ (accessed April 15, 2020).Search in Google Scholar

Haines, G. H., J. Madill, and A. R. Riding. 2003. “Informal Investment in Canada: Financing Small Business Growth.” Journal of Small Business and Entrepreneurship 16 (3–4): 13–40, https://doi.org/10.1080/08276331.2003.10593306.Search in Google Scholar

Hallen, B. L., S. Cohen, and C. B. Bingham. 2020. “Do Accelerators Work? If So, How?” Organization Science 31 (2): 378–414, https://doi.org/10.1287/orsc.2019.1304.Search in Google Scholar

Hausberg, J. P., and S. Korreck. 2020. “Business Incubators and Accelerators: A Co-citation Analysis-Based, Systematic Literature Review.” Journal of Technology Transfer 45: 151–76, https://doi.org/10.1007/s10961-018-9651-y.Search in Google Scholar

Higgins, M. C., and R. Gulati. 2006. “Stacking the Deck: The Effects of Top Management Backgrounds on Investor Decisions.” Strategic Management Journal 27 (1): 1–25, https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.495.Search in Google Scholar

Hisrich, K. D., and A. U. Jankowicz. 1990. “Intuition in Venture Capital Decisions: An Exploratory Study Using a New Technique.” Journal of Business Venturing 5: 49–62, https://doi.org/10.1016/0883-9026(90)90026-p.Search in Google Scholar

Huang, L., and J. L. Pearce. 2015. “Managing the Unknowable: The Effectiveness of Early-Stage Investor Gut Feel in Entrepreneurial Investment Decisions.” Administrative Science Quarterly 60 (4): 634–70, https://doi.org/10.1177/0001839215597270.Search in Google Scholar

Hughes, M., R. D. Ireland, and R. E. Morgan. 2007. “Stimulating Dynamic Value: Social Capital and Business Incubation as a Pathway to Competitive Success.” Long Range Planning 40 (2): 154–77, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.lrp.2007.03.008.Search in Google Scholar

Investment Office. 2020. The State of Turkish Startup Ecosystem. https://www.invest.gov.tr/tr/library/publications/lists/investpublications/turk-startup-ekosisteminin-gorunumu.pdf (accessed August 15, 2020).Search in Google Scholar

Kirsch, D., B. Goldfarb, and A. Gera. 2009. “Form or Substance: The Role of Business Plans in Venture Capital Decision Making.” Strategic Management Journal 30: 487–515, https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.751.Search in Google Scholar

Lall, S. A., L. -W. Chen, and P. W. Roberts. 2020. “Are We Accelerating Equity Investment into Impact-Oriented Ventures?” World Development 131: 104952. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2020.104952.Search in Google Scholar

Leatherbee, M., and J. Gonzalez-Uribe. 2018. “Selection Issues.” In Accelerators: Successful Venture Creation and Growth, edited by M. Wright, and I. Drori, 81–99. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing.10.4337/9781786434098.00009Search in Google Scholar

Lee, P. M., T. G. Pollock, and K. Jin. 2011. “The Contingent Value of Venture Capitalist Reputation.” Strategic Organization 9 (1): 33–69, https://doi.org/10.1177/1476127011400505.Search in Google Scholar

MacMillan, I. C., R. Siegel, and P. N. Subba Narasimha. 1985. “Criteria Used by Venture Capitalists to Evaluate New Venture Proposals.” Journal of Business Venturing 1 (1): 119–28, https://doi.org/10.1016/0883-9026(85)90011-4.Search in Google Scholar

Mason, C., and M. Stork. 2004. “What Do Investors Look for in a Business Plan? A Comparison of the Investment Criteria of Bankers, Venture Capitalists and Business Angels.” International Small Business Journal 22 (3): 227–48, https://doi.org/10.1177/0266242604042377.Search in Google Scholar

Maxwell, A. L., S. A. Jeffrey, and M. Levesque. 2011. “Business Angel Early Stage Decision Making.” Journal of Business Venturing 26 (2): 212–25, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusvent.2009.09.002.Search in Google Scholar

Meyer, J. W., and B. Rowan. 1977. “Institutionalized Organizations: Formal Structure as Myth and Ceremony.” American Journal of Sociology 83: 340–63, https://doi.org/10.1086/226550.Search in Google Scholar

Miles, M. B., and M. A. Huberman. 1994. Qualitative Data Analysis: An Expanded Sourcebook, 2nd ed. London: Sage Publications.Search in Google Scholar

Navis, C., and M. A. Glynn. 2011. “Legitimate Distinctiveness and the Entrepreneurial Identity: Influence on Investor Judgments of New Venture Plausibility.” Academy of Management Review 36 (3): 479–99, https://doi.org/10.5465/amr.2011.61031809.Search in Google Scholar

Pandey, S., S. Lall, S. K. Pandey, and S. Ahlawat. 2017. “The Appeal of Social Accelerators: What Do Social Entrepreneurs Value?” Journal of Social Entrepreneurship 8 (1): 88–109, https://doi.org/10.1080/19420676.2017.1299035.Search in Google Scholar

Pauwels, C., B. Clarysse, M. Wright, and J. van Hove. 2016. “Understanding a New Generation Incubation Model: The Accelerator.” Technovation 50-51: 13–24, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2015.09.003.Search in Google Scholar

Pollack, J. M., M. W. Rutherford, and B. G. Nagy. 2012. “Preparedness and Cognitive Legitimacy as Antecedents of New Venture Funding in Televised Business Pitches.” Entrepreneurship: Theory and Practice 36 (5): 915–39, https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6520.2012.00531.x.Search in Google Scholar

Pollock, T. G., and R. Gulati. 2007. “Standing Out from the Crowd: The Visibility-Enhancing Effects of IPO_related Signals on Alliance Formation by Entrepreneurial Firms.” Strategic Organization 5 (4): 339–72, https://doi.org/10.1177/1476127007083346.Search in Google Scholar

Prexl, K. M., M. Hubert, S. Beck, C. Heiden, and R. Prugl. 2019. “Identifying and Analyzing the Drivers of Heterogeneity among Ecosystem Builder Accelerators.” R&D Management 49 (4): 624–38, https://doi.org/10.1111/radm.12352.Search in Google Scholar

Qin, F., M. Wright, and J. Gao. 2019. “Accelerators and Intra-Ecosystem Variety: How Entrepreneurial Agency Influences Venture Development in a Time-Compressed Support Program.” Industrial and Corporate Change 28 (4): 961–75, https://doi.org/10.1093/icc/dtz036.Search in Google Scholar

Sansone, G., P. Andreotti, A. Colombelli, and P. Landoni. 2020. “Are Social Incubators Different from Other Incubators? Evidence from Italy.” Technological Forecasting and Social Change 158: 120132, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.techfore.2020.120132.Search in Google Scholar

Shankar, R. K., and T. H. Clausen. 2020. “Scale Quickly or Fail Fast: An Inductive Study of Acceleration.” Technovation 98: 102174, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2020.102174.Search in Google Scholar

Sklyara, A., C. Kowalkowskia, B. Tronvoll, and D. Sörhammare. 2019. “Organizing for Digital Servitization: A Service Ecosystem Perspective.” Journal of Business Research 104: 450–60, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusres.2019.02.012.Search in Google Scholar

Stake, R. E. 1995. “Case Studies.” In Handbook of Qualitative Research, edited by N. K. Denzin, and Y. S. Lincoln. Thousand Oaks: Sage.Search in Google Scholar

Stayton, J., and V. Mangematin. 2019. “Seed Accelerators and the Speed of New Venture Creation.” Journal of Technology Transfer 44: 1163–87, https://doi.org/10.1007/s10961-017-9646-0.Search in Google Scholar

Suchman, M. C. 1995. “Managing Legitimacy: Strategic and Institutional Approaches.” Academy of Management Review 20 (3): 571–610, https://doi.org/10.5465/amr.1995.9508080331.Search in Google Scholar

Tyebjee, T. T., and A. V. Bruno. 1984. “A Model of Venture Capital Investment Activity.” Management Science 30 (9): 1051–66, https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.30.9.1051.Search in Google Scholar

Yang, S., R. Kher, and S. L. Newbert. 2020. “What Signals Matter for Social Startups? It Depends: The Influence of Gender Role Congruity on Social Impact Accelerator Selection Decisions.” Journal of Business Venturing 35 (2): 105932, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusvent.2019.03.001.Search in Google Scholar

Yin, R. K. 2014. Case Study Research Design and Methods, 5th ed. Thousand Oaks: Sage.Search in Google Scholar

Yin, B., and J. Luo. 2018. “How Do Accelerators Select Startups? Shifting Decision Criteria across Stages.” IEEE Transactions on Engineering Management 65 (4): 574–89, https://doi.org/10.1109/tem.2018.2791501.Search in Google Scholar

Zacharakis, A. L., and D. A. Shepherd. 2001. “The Nature of Information and Overconfidence on Venture Capitalists’ Decision Making.” Journal of Business Venturing 16 (4): 311–32, https://doi.org/10.1016/s0883-9026(99)00052-x.Search in Google Scholar

Zarei, H., M. Rasti-Barzoki, and I. Moon. 2022. “A Game Theoretic Approach to the Selection, Mentorship, and Investment Decisions of Startup Accelerators.” IEEE Transactions on Engineering Management 69 (4): 1753–1768. https://doi.org/10.1109/TEM.2020.2974532.Search in Google Scholar

Received: 2021-03-18
Accepted: 2021-09-14
Published Online: 2021-10-01

© 2021 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston

Downloaded on 23.4.2024 from https://www.degruyter.com/document/doi/10.1515/erj-2021-0122/html
Scroll to top button