Skip to main content

The Official Journal of the Pan-Pacific Association of Input-Output Studies (PAPAIOS)

Financial structure, cycle, and instability

Abstract

The subprime loan mortgage crisis has revived scholarly interest in Minsky’s financial instability hypothesis. The related mathematical models present two types of Minskian financial structures. We construct macrodynamic models that consider both structures and discuss financial instability and cycles. We also demonstrate that one of the financial cycles occurs when a real factor stabilizes the economy. The burden of interest-bearing debt is an important determinant of the cycle. We posit that the escalating financial fragility in this cycle is a more appropriate interpretation of the Minskian financial structure that refers to hedging, speculative and Ponzi behaviors. We further demonstrate that another financial structure destabilizes the economy. If the instability occurs at the point of fragility, then the economy may deteriorate into financial crisis. Fragility then becomes instability.

1 Introduction

The financial instability hypothesis proposed by Hyman P. Minsky (1975, 1982a, 1986) has attracted renewed attention following the subprime loan mortgage crisis. Many authors, mainly post-Keynesian economists, employ two types of financial structures in their mathematical models.

Taylor and O’Connell (1985) formulated that lenders’ liquidity preferences intensify with a decrease in the expected profit rate (\(\rho\)). They hypothesized that an increase in the expected profit rate (\(\rho\)) reduces the interest rate (\(i\)). They also asserted that a true Minsky crisis occurs when the value of derivatives (\({i}_{\rho }\)) turns significantly negative. Kregel (1997) emphasized that the margins of safety proposed by Minsky (1982a) are significant for financial instability.Footnote 1 When an economic boom reduces lenders’ risks, banks, including commercial ones, promote lending despite erosion in the margin of safety.

Ninomiya (2007, 2018) considered these factors in a Kaldorian business cycle model and discusses financial instability as a cycle. Ninomiya and Tokuda (2017) demonstrated that Japan’s financial structure has been fragile since the mid-1990s by expanding upon the work of Taylor and O’Connell (1985) and applying VAR analysis. Ninomiya and Tokuda (2012) demonstrated that Korea’s financial structure stabilized after the Asian monetary crisis.

On the contrary, Kregel (2008) does not regard the subprime mortgage crisis as traditional Minskian financial instability. Ninomiya and Tokuda (2021) demonstrated that the US financial structure stabilized before the crisis.Footnote 2 We identify financial structures similar to the aforementioned structures (Japan and Korea) as the lenders’ risk type (LR).

Minsky emphasizes increasing financial fragility, which refers to hedging, speculation, and Ponzi finance. His financial instability hypothesis is an endogenous financial business cycle theory. Therefore, related mathematical models interpret enlargement in firms’ debt burdens as the source of increasing financial fragility and introduce a dynamic equation for debt burden into Kaldorian business cycle, Goodwin, and Kaleckian models.Footnote 3

Asada (2001) and Ninomiya (2015, 2018) developed a macrodynamic model that takes interest-bearing debt into account as a source of financial instability and cycles. However, Asada (2001) did not consider the LR financial structure. Furthermore, Asada (2001), Ninomiya (2015, 2018), and many other studies did not explicitly define the Minskian financial structure.

Nishi (2012b) and Ninomiya and Tokuda (2017) examined debt burden and financial instability by applying a VAR analysis.Footnote 4 Nishi (2021) focused on debt dynamics at the industrial level and discussed financial fragility, thereby separating the complete period (1960–2018) into two at 1998 to demonstrate fluctuations in the debt ratio over the business cycle for 1960–2018 in Japan.

Some studies explicitly consider the latter type of Minskian financial structure,Footnote 5 which we identify as the hedge, speculative and Ponzi type (HSP). Nishi (2012a) proposed a revised Minskian financial structure and introduces the burden of interest-bearing debt into a Kaleckian model. Although his definition of hedge finance differs from Foley’s (2003), it promises to be widely accepted. Nonetheless, he focused on the long run without discussing financial cycles and assumes a constant interest rate. He did not consider an LR financial structure.Footnote 6

Sasaki and Fujita (2014) consider dividends in a Kaleckian model and suggest that cyclical fluctuations can occur such that the financial structure of firms changes periodically between speculative finance and Ponzi finance. Since we do not consider dividends, we adopt Nishi’s definition. Note also that Sasaki and Fujita (2014) also assume a constant interest rate and do not consider the LR financial structure. Although Ninomiya and Tokuda (2017) considered both the LR and HSP financial structures, they did not explicitly examine the HSP financial structure.

This paper constructs simple macrodynamic models, introduces two types of Minskian financial structures (LR and HPS) and discusses financial instability and cycles. Multiple studies include the LR or HSP financial structure in their models, whereas this study explicitly considers the HSP financial structure and focuses on the business cycle because the financial instability hypothesis is an endogenous theory of the business cycle. We present a numerical simulation of financial cycles and describe an HSP financial structure. One of the cycles indicates that the financial factor has a stabilizing role in the economy, although the financial regime becomes more fragile from hedge finance to speculative and Ponzi finance. By contrast, another cycle indicates that interest-bearing debt burden has a destabilizing role in the economy. Further, examining monetary and fiscal policy interventions is worthwhile for coping with financial instability. We emphasize the importance of considering both LR and HSP structures in dynamic systems.

The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 introduces the two types of Minskian financial structures, thereby presenting a basic macrodynamic model in which the interest rate is constant, finally exploring financial instability and cycles, and considering only the HSP structure in the model. Section 3 presents extended models featuring an endogenous interest rate, which include both LR and HSP financial structures. Section 4 concludes.

2 Financial structures and basic dynamics

We first clarify LR and HSP Minskian financial structure. Real gross profit \(\Pi\) is defined as follows:

$$\Pi ={Y}^{d}-\frac{W}{p}N,$$
(1)

where \({Y}^{d}\) is the demand side of goods, \(W\) is the nominal wage, \(p\) is the price level and \(N\) represents the level of employment. Following Asada (1995), we assume that disequilibrium in the goods market is compensated by inventory fluctuation and the demand side is always realized (\({Y}^{d}=Y\)).

We also assume that the economy is oligopolistic and the price level \(p\) is decided by the mark-up principle as follows:

$$p=(1+\tau )\frac{WN}{Y},$$
(2)

where \(\tau\) is the mark-up rate. Therefore, real gross profit \(\Pi\) is:

$$\Pi =Y-\frac{W}{p}N=\frac{\tau }{1+\tau }Y=\theta Y,$$
(3)

where \(\theta\) is the rate of profit sharing.

We assume that the real gross profit \(\Pi\) is distributed to firms, and an interest payment \(iD\) is distributed to rentiers. Firms retain their remaining profit as internal reserves \(V\), obtained by

$$V=\Pi -iD=\theta Y-iD,$$
(4)

where \(i\) is the interest rate and \(D\) denotes firms’ debt burdens.Footnote 7 We assume that all interest payments are saved.

Following Nishi (2012a), who formulated the HSP-type Minskian financial structure, we formalize the financial regimes as follows:

$$\Pi \geqq \dot{D}+iD\hspace{1em}\hspace{1em}\left(\mathrm{hedge}\hspace{0.33em}\mathrm{finance}\right),$$
(5)
$$\Pi \geqq iD\hspace{1em}\hspace{1em}\left(\mathrm{speculative}\hspace{0.33em}\mathrm{finance}\right),$$
(6)
$$\Pi <iD\hspace{1em}\hspace{1em}\left(\mathrm{Ponzi}\hspace{0.33em}\mathrm{finance}\right),$$
(7)

where \(\dot{D}\) denotes the change in debt burden \(D\). For example, hedge finance means that internal reserves \(V(=\Pi -iD)\) exceed the increase in debt burden \(D\). Ponzi finance means that a firm’s gross profit (net operating revenue \(\Pi\)) cannot cover its interest payment \(iD\).

Suppose that investment demand must be financed by adding debt if it is not financed via internal reserves. The dynamic equation expressing debt burden \(D\) becomes

$$\dot{D}=I-V=I-(\theta Y-iD).$$
(8)

The investment function \(I\) is defined as

$$I={g}_{1}Y-{g}_{2}iD-{g}_{0},\hspace{1em}{g}_{i}>0,$$
(9)

where \({g}_{1}\) represents animal spirits or appropriate investment opportunities. For example, a paucity of appropriate opportunities reduces \({g}_{1}\) even though income \(Y\) rises. \(-{g}_{2}\) implies that a firm curtails investment demand because its debt burden rises.Footnote 8\(-{g}_{0}\) is a depreciation that indicates that \(I\) falls when \(Y\) is sufficiently small.

We, first, begin to examine a basic dynamic system and assume that the interest rate is constant in the system as follows:

$$i={i}_{0}.$$
(10)

By ordering (3)–(10), we obtain the following financial regimes:

$$D\geqq \frac{\left({g}_{1}-2\theta \right)}{\left({g}_{2}-2\right){i}_{0}}Y-\frac{{g}_{0}}{\left({g}_{2}-2\right){i}_{0}}\hspace{1em}\hspace{1em}\left(\mathrm{hedge}\hspace{0.33em}\mathrm{finance}\right),$$
(11)
$$D\leqq \frac{\theta }{{i}_{0}}Y\hspace{1em}\hspace{1em}\left(\mathrm{speculative}\hspace{0.33em}\mathrm{finance}\right),$$
(12)
$$D>\frac{\theta }{{i}_{0}}Y\hspace{1em}\hspace{1em}\left(\mathrm{Ponzi}\hspace{0.33em}\mathrm{finance}\right).$$
(13)

Figure 1 presents one of the regions in (\(D\), \(Y\)) space to the different regimes. The boundary of hedge finance (11) depends on the signs of \({g}_{1}-2\theta\) and \({g}_{2}-2\). For example, the coefficient of \(Y\) is positive and the intercept on the \(Y\) axis is negative when \({g}_{2}-2>0\) and \({g}_{1}-2\theta >0\). We assume that an economy is expanding, and both investment demand \(I\) and internal reserves V increase. \({g}_{1}-2\theta >0\) indicates that growth in investment demand \(I\) exceeds that in internal reserves V; therefore, debt burden \(D\) increases. By contrast, \({g}_{2}-2>0\) indicates that the increasing burden of interest-bearing debt \(iD\) significantly induces the decline in investment demand \(I\). These two effects lead to a decline in debt burden (Fig. 1-1).

Fig. 1
figure 1

Financial regimes

Note that the region of speculative finance (2) in Fig. 1-1 satisfies the hedge finance condition. For example, the reduction in investment demand \(I\) prevents an increase in debt burden D. Meanwhile, a decrease in investment demand I induces the decrease in income Y, what we refer to as a recession. Therefore, the economy of the speculative finance (2) region may be as fragile as that of the speculative finance (1) region.

Conversely, the coefficient of \(Y\) is negative and the intercept on the \(Y\) axis is positive when \({g}_{2}-2<0\) and \({g}_{1}-2\theta >0\). We again assume that the economy is expanding. \({g}_{2}-2<0\) indicates that the increase in the burden of interest-bearing debt \(iD\) induces the decline in investment demand \(I\) but not significantly. This effect leads to an increase in debt burden (Fig. 1-2).

The boundary between speculative and Ponzi finance depends on the parameter \(\theta\) and the interest rate \({i}_{0}\). The region of Ponzi finance expands when \(\theta\) falls or \({i}_{0}\) rises. The fall in \(\theta\) reduces internal reserves, and the rise in \({i}_{0}\) enlarges the burden of interest-bearing debt. Therefore, firms’ financial conditions deteriorate.

Note that the region of Ponzi (2) in Fig. 1-2 satisfies the condition of hedge finance through the reduction in debt burden \(D\). Accordingly, the decline in investment demand \(I\) is highly significant in covering payment obligations \(iD\). The economy of the Ponzi (2) region is as serious as that of the Ponzi (1) region.

We, next, formulate the basic dynamic system assuming that interest rate is constant. This means that we cannot consider the LR structure in the basic dynamic system.

Real wage income \({H}_{w}\) is obtained from Eq. (3) as follows:

$${H}_{w}=\frac{W}{p}N=\frac{1}{1+\tau }Y=(1-\theta )Y,\hspace{1em}0<\theta <1.$$
(14)

The income-tax function T is assumed as follows:

$$T=tY,\hspace{1em}0<t<1,$$
(15)

where t represents tax rate.Footnote 9

The consumption function \(C\) is assumed to be a linear function of \({H}_{w}-T\):

$$C=c{(H}_{w}-T)+{C}_{0}=c(1-\theta -t)Y+{C}_{0},\hspace{1em}0<c<1,\hspace{1em}{C}_{0}>0,$$
(16)

where \(c\) is the marginal propensity to consume and \({C}_{0}\) is basic consumption.

The dynamic equation for income \(Y\) is formulated as

$$\dot{Y}=\alpha (C+I+G-Y),\hspace{1em}\alpha >0.$$
(17)

Equation (17) describes the quantity adjustment in the goods market, and \(\alpha\) is the speed of adjustment.

Ordering (8), (9), (10), (15), (16) and (17) obtains the following dynamic system \(({S}_{a}.1)\):

$$\dot{Y}=\alpha \left[c\left(1-\theta -t\right)Y+{C}_{0}+{g}_{1}Y-{g}_{2}{i}_{0}D-{g}_{0}+G-Y\right] \qquad \qquad \left({S}_{a}.1.1\right),$$
$$\dot{D}={g}_{1}Y-{g}_{2}{i}_{0}D-{g}_{0}-\theta Y+{i}_{0}D\qquad \qquad \qquad \qquad \left({S}_{a}.1.2\right).$$

We adopt the following assumption:

$${g}_{1}-s>0, \qquad \qquad \qquad \qquad \qquad \left(A.1\right)$$

where \(s=1-c(1-\theta -t)\). Assumption A.1 indicates that the real factor destabilizes the economy.Footnote 10 Kaldorian business cycle models employ a similar assumption.Footnote 11

The loci of \(\dot{Y}=0\) and \(\dot{D}=0\) are as follows:

$${D}_{(\dot{Y}=0)}=\frac{{g}_{1}-s}{{g}_{2}{i}_{0}}Y+\frac{{C}_{0}+G-{g}_{0}}{{g}_{2}{i}_{0}},$$
(18)
$${D}_{(\dot{D}=0)}=\frac{{g}_{1}-\theta }{{(g}_{2}-1){i}_{0}}Y-\frac{{g}_{0}}{({g}_{2}-1){i}_{0}}.$$
(19)

The locus of \(\dot{Y}=0\) is positive by assumption A.1, but the locus of \(\dot{D}=0\) depends on the sign of \({g}_{2}-1\). The slope is negative when \({g}_{2}-1<0\) (Fig. 2-1) and positive when \({g}_{2}-1>0\) (Fig. 2-2).Footnote 12

Fig. 2
figure 2

Dynamic system Sa

The Jacobian matrix of the dynamic system \(({S}_{a}.1)\) at equilibrium can be expressed as:

$${J}_{a}=\left(\begin{array}{cc}\alpha ({g}_{1}-s)& -\alpha {g}_{2}{i}_{0}\\ {g}_{1}-\theta & (1-{g}_{2}){i}_{0}\end{array}\right).$$
(20)

Therefore, we obtain:

$$\mathrm{tr}{J}_{a}=\alpha ({g}_{1}-s)+(1-{g}_{2}){i}_{0},$$
(21)
$$\mathrm{det }{J}_{a}=\alpha {i}_{0}[{g}_{1}-s+(s-\theta ){g}_{2}]>0.$$
(22)

We obtain \(\mathrm{det }{J}_{a}>0\) by adopting assumption A.1.Footnote 13 Therefore, the stability of the system \(({S}_{a}.1)\) depends on only the tr \({J}_{a}\).

The dynamic system \(({S}_{a}.1)\) becomes unstable when \(1-{g}_{2}>0\) in Fig. 2-1 through the following mechanism. Suppose income \(Y\) descends below equilibrium during an economic downturn. The decrease leads to a decline in profit \(\Pi\) and an expansion in debt burden \(D\). Expansion in \(D\) restrains investment demand \(I\). However, debt burdens rise because the upsurge in interest payments \(iD\) exceeds the decline in investment demand \(I\). Therefore, \(D\) rises with the decline in \(Y\). This mechanism indicates that financial factors destabilize the economy alongside real factors. Note that the burden of interest-bearing debt \(iD\) is a crucial contributor to financial instability.

$$Y\downarrow \Rightarrow\Pi \downarrow \Rightarrow D\uparrow \Rightarrow I\downarrow <iD\uparrow \Rightarrow D\uparrow .$$

In addition, there is one parameter value \({\alpha }_{a}\) at which Hopf bifurcation occurs when \(1-{g}_{2}<0\).Footnote 14 Figure 2-2 shows at least one closed orbit around the equilibrium in the system \(({S}_{a}.1)\) in this case, when \(\alpha\) is close to \({\alpha }_{a}\) (Appendix 1).Footnote 15 This is a financial cycle with income \(Y\) and debt burden \(D\). This cycle occurs via the following mechanism. Suppose the economy occupies Point A in Fig. 2-2. Income \(Y\) and debt burden \(D\) increase at Point A. Rising \(D\) restrains investment demand \(I\), and the economy enters recession. In this instance, however, erosion in investment demand \(I\) exceeds the greater burden of interest-bearing debt \(iD\). Therefore, debt burden \(D\) shrinks. The financial factor stabilizes the economy.Footnote 16

$$D\uparrow \Rightarrow I\downarrow \left(Y\downarrow \right)>iD\uparrow \Rightarrow D\downarrow .$$

Figure 3 presents the relation between an HSP structure (Fig. 1) and the dynamic in Fig. 2. That is, Fig. 3 shows escalating financial fragility during a business cycle. Suppose the economy operates under a hedge finance regime at Point A in Fig. 3-1. Income \(Y\) increases, and the financial regime shifts from hedge to speculative (Point B). The debt burden \(D\) also expands,Footnote 17 and the financial regime shifts to Ponzi finance (Point C).Footnote 18 Consequently, the economy enters depression (Point D).

Fig. 3
figure 3

Financial regimes and cycles

Figure 3-2 shows the other process of escalating financial fragility during the business cycle. We emphasize that the financial factor has a stabilizing role in the economy, although the financial regime becomes more fragile from the hedge finance to the speculative finance and the Ponzi finance.Footnote 19

Next, we simulate the financial cycle in the basic dynamic system numerically. By enumerating parameters as \(c=0.6,\) \(\theta =0.5,\) \(t=0.2,\) \({C}_{0}=20,\) \({g}_{1}=1.5,\) \({g}_{2}=3,\) \(i=1(\%),\) \({g}_{0}=35\) and \(G=25\), we rewrite dynamic system \(({S}_{a}.2)\) as follows (see Appendix 2):

$$\dot{Y}=\alpha \left[0.68Y-3D+10\right] \qquad \qquad \qquad \qquad \left({S}_{a}.2.1\right),$$
$$\dot{D}=Y-2D-35 \qquad \qquad \qquad \qquad \qquad \qquad \left({S}_{a}.2.2\right).$$

By considering (11), (12) and (13), the financial regimes are

$$D\geqq 0.5Y-35\hspace{1em}\hspace{1em}\left(\mathrm{hedge}\hspace{0.33em}\mathrm{finance}\right),$$
(23)
$$D\leqq 0.5Y\hspace{1em}\hspace{1em}\left(\mathrm{speculative}\hspace{0.33em}\mathrm{finance}\right),$$
(24)
$$D>0.5Y\hspace{1em}\hspace{1em}\left(\mathrm{Ponzi}\hspace{0.33em}\mathrm{finance}\right).$$
(25)

Figure 4 illustrates there is a closed orbit in the dynamic system \(({S}_{a}.2)\) when \(\alpha =2.941.\)Footnote 20 The equilibrium value of \(Y\) is \({Y}^{*}\fallingdotseq 82.31\). Figure 4 also illustrates the relation between the financial cycle and the financial structure. The hedge finance regime of (23) satisfies \({g}_{1}-2\theta >0\) and \({g}_{2}-2>0\). Figure 4 also illustrates the escalating fragility of an HSP financial structure in the business cycle.Footnote 21

Fig. 4
figure 4

Numerical simulation system Sa

3 Lenders’ risks and instability

Section 2 assumed a constant interest rate, which prevented us from investigating the LR financial structure in the dynamic system \(({S}_{a}.1)\). We now consider a dynamic system in which the interest rate is an endogenous variable. That is, in addition to the HSP structure, the LR financial structure is considered.

The money demand function \({M}^{d}\) is

(26)

where \({L}_{Y}<0\) implies that lenders’ liquidity preference intensifies with the decrease in income \(Y\). This effect expresses an aspect of LR. We call this LR the “Taylor and O’Connell type (T-O type) LR”.Footnote 22

Following Rose (1969) and Ninomiya (2007, 2015, 2016, 2018), we define the money supply function \({M}^{s}\) as:

$${M}^{s}=\mu (Y,i)H,\hspace{1em}{\mu }_{Y}\equiv \frac{\partial \mu }{\partial Y}>0,\hspace{1em}{\mu }_{i}\equiv \frac{\partial \mu }{\partial i}>0,$$
(27)

where \(\mu\) is a monetary multiplier. \({\mu }_{Y}>0\) implies that the money supply increases when a bank lends to an expanding economy. This effect is also an expression of the T-O type LR.Footnote 23 The monetary multiplier \(\mu\) includes commercial bank behavior.Footnote 24 We assume that high-powered money \(H\) is constant (\(H=\bar{H}\)).

Ordering (26) and (27), the interest rate \(i\) is determined by equilibrium in the money market as follows:Footnote 25

$$L(Y,i)=\mu (Y,i)\bar{H}.$$
(28)

Totally differentiating Eq. (28) with respect to interest rate \(i\) and income Y, we obtain

(29)

Equation (29) also shows that interest rate \(i\) is reflected by LRs. This is a financial structure of the LR type.

As mentioned, LRs are expressed by \({L}_{Y}\) and \({\mu }_{Y}\). The sign of \({i}_{Y}\) depends on the sign of \({L}_{Y}-{\mu }_{Y}\bar{H}\). We obtain \({i}_{Y}<0\) when \({L}_{Y}-{\mu }_{Y}\bar{H}<0\). For example, we obtain \({i}_{Y}<0\) when \({\mu }_{Y}\) is significant. The monetary multiplier \(\mu\) includes the behavior of commercial banks. Kregel (1997) emphasized that the margins of safety proposed by Minsky are significant for financial instability. When an economic boom reduces LRs, lenders, including commercial banks, promote lending despite erosion in margins of safety.

We also obtain \({i}_{Y}<0\) when \({L}_{Y}<0\). This is similar to Taylor and O’Connell’s (1985) study. They presented that an economy would fall into a financial crisis when a decline in expected profit rates aggravated the financial condition of firms and increased household preference for liquidity.

Ninomiya (2007, 2016) introduced the factors \({L}_{Y}<0\) and \({\mu }_{Y}>0\), and discusses financial instability when \({i}_{Y}<0\). He indicated that the economy becomes unstable even when the real factor (\({g}_{1}-s\)) stabilizes the economy when \({i}_{Y}<0\). We call this instability the “Taylor–O’Connell type (T-O type) financial instability”. The mechanism of this instability is as follows. We suppose that an economy is in recession. A decline in income \(Y\) raises the interest rate \(i\). An increase in interest rate \(i\) restrains investment demand \(I\), and a financial crisis ensues.

$$Y\downarrow \Rightarrow i\uparrow \Rightarrow I\downarrow \Rightarrow Y\downarrow .$$

By ordering (8), (9), (15), (16), (17), and (29), we obtain the following dynamic system \(({S}_{b}.1)\):

$$\dot{Y}=\alpha \left[c\left(1-\theta -t\right)Y+{C}_{0}+{g}_{1}Y-{g}_{2}i\left(Y\right)D-{g}_{0}+G-Y\right] \qquad \qquad \qquad \left({S}_{b}.1.1\right),$$
$$\dot{D}={g}_{1}Y-{g}_{2}i\left(Y\right)D-{g}_{0}-\theta Y+i\left(Y\right)D\qquad \qquad \qquad \qquad \qquad \left({S}_{b}.1.2\right).$$

The Jacobian matrix of the dynamic system \(({S}_{b}.1)\) at equilibrium can be expressed as:

$${J}_{b}=\left(\begin{array}{cc}\alpha [({g}_{1}-s)-{g}_{2}{i}_{Y}D]& -\alpha {g}_{2}i\\ {g}_{1}-\theta +(1-{g}_{2}){i}_{Y}D& (1-{g}_{2})i\end{array}\right).$$
(30)

Therefore, we obtain

$$\mathrm{tr}{J}_{b}=\alpha \{({g}_{1}-s)-{g}_{2}{i}_{Y}D\}+(1-{g}_{2})i,$$
(31)
$$\mathrm{det }{J}_{b}=\alpha i[({g}_{1}-s)+(s-\theta ){g}_{2}]>0.$$
(32)

We obtain \(\mathrm{det }{J}_{b}\) \(>0\). Therefore, the stability depends on the sign of tr \({J}_{b}\) as indicated:

  1. (1)

    \({g}_{1}-s-{g}_{2}{i}_{Y}D>0,\hspace{1em}1-{g}_{2}>0\Rightarrow \mathrm{tr}{J}_{b}>0: \mathrm{Unstable},\)

  2. (2)

    \({g}_{1}-s-{g}_{2}{i}_{Y}D<0,\hspace{1em}1-{g}_{2}<0\Rightarrow \mathrm{tr}{J}_{b}<0: \mathrm{Stable},\)

Stability depends on the signs of \(1-{g}_{2}\) and \({g}_{1}-s-{g}_{2}{i}_{Y}D\). The inequity \({g}_{1}-s-{g}_{2}{i}_{Y}D>0\) indicates that the goods market destabilizes the economy. This is usually assumed in closed Kaldorian models. We should note that the condition is satisfied even when \({i}_{Y}<0\) and the absolute value is significant. This means that the LR financial structure is unstable and the financial factor may stabilize the economy when \({g}_{1}-s-{g}_{2}{i}_{Y}D>0\).

There is one parameter value \({\alpha }_{b}\) at which Hopf bifurcation occurs when \(1-{g}_{2}<0\). There is at least one closed orbit around equilibrium in the system \(({S}_{b}.1)\), when \(\alpha\) is close to \({\alpha }_{b}\) (Appendix 3). Cycle 1 is similar to the cycles in the basic dynamic system \(({S}_{a})\).Footnote 26 We should note that the HSP financial structure stabilizes the system \(({S}_{b}.1)\). The system \(({S}_{b}.1)\) is unstable when \({g}_{1}-s-{g}_{2}{i}_{Y}D>0\) and \(1-{g}_{2}>0\). We emphasize that the fragile HSP financial structure also destabilizes the economy when \(1-{g}_{2}>0\).

In contrast, \({g}_{1}-s-{g}_{2}{i}_{Y}D<0\) indicates that marginal propensity to invest (\({g}_{1}-{g}_{2}{i}_{Y}D\)) is smaller than marginal propensity to save (\(s\)). In other words, the indirect effect (\({g}_{2}{i}_{Y}D\)) is significant. Therefore, the goods market stabilizes the economy despite the destabilizing real factor (\({g}_{1}-s>0\)). This means that the LR financial structure makes the economy stable. Therefore, the dynamic system \(({S}_{b})\) is stable when \({g}_{1}-s-{g}_{2}{i}_{Y}D<0\) and \(1-{g}_{2}<0\). The HSP financial structure also stabilizes the economy when \(1-{g}_{2}<0\).

There is one parameter value \({\alpha }_{b}\) at which Hopf bifurcation occurs when \({g}_{1}-s-{g}_{2}{i}_{Y}D<0\) and \(1-{g}_{2}>0\), which means that the HSP financial structure is fragile. There is at least one closed orbit around equilibrium in System \(({S}_{b}.1)\), when \(\alpha\) is close to \({\alpha }_{b}\) (Appendix 3). In other words, Cycle 2 is quite different from Cycle 1 and Asada (2001).

Although economic boom reduces safety margins, lenders continue to lend due to the decrease in the T-O type LRs. The economy might fall into “euphoria”. However, recession exacerbates the T-O type LRs, and they may curtail lending rapidly and drastically. A financial crisis could occur if T-O type financial instability occurs as fragility progresses from hedge finance to speculative finance and Ponzi finance. Fragility then becomes instability.Footnote 27 As mentioned, the system \(({S}_{b}.1)\) is unstable when \({g}_{1}-s-{g}_{2}{i}_{Y}D>0\) and \(1-{g}_{2}>0\). Again, we emphasize it is essential to consider both types of financial structures in dynamic systems.

It is worthwhile to describe monetary policy interventions for coping with financial instability. The dynamic system \(({S}_{a})\) shows stability conditions under a constant interest rate. That is, the economy mirrors the system \(({S}_{a})\) if central bank policy targets the interest rate. We regard interest rate targeting useful in avoiding T-O type financial instability.

Next, we present a numerical simulation in the case of \({i}_{Y}>0\) by giving an example and specify Eq. (29) as:

$$i={i}_{1}Y,\hspace{1em}{i}_{1}>0.$$
(33)

By considering Eq. (33), we obtain the following dynamic system \(({S}_{b}.2)\)Footnote 28:

$$\dot{Y}=\alpha \left[c\left(1-\theta -t\right)Y+{C}_{0}+{g}_{1}Y-{g}_{2}{i}_{1}YD-{g}_{0}+G-Y\right]\qquad \qquad \qquad \qquad \left({S}_{b}.2.1\right),$$
$$\dot{D}={g}_{1}Y-{g}_{2}{i}_{1}YD-{g}_{0}-\theta Y+{i}_{1}YD \qquad \qquad \qquad \qquad \qquad \qquad \left({S}_{b}.2.2\right).$$

By ordering (3)–(9), and (33), we obtain these financial regimes in the dynamic system \(({S}_{b}.2)\):

$$Y\geqq -\frac{{g}_{0}}{\left(2\theta -{g}_{1}\right)+\left({g}_{2}-2\right){i}_{1}D}\hspace{1em}\hspace{1em}\left(\mathrm{hedge}\hspace{0.33em}\mathrm{finance}\right),$$
(34)
$$D\leqq \frac{\theta }{{i}_{1}}\hspace{1em}\hspace{1em}\left(\mathrm{speculative}\hspace{0.33em}\mathrm{finance}\right),$$
(35)
$$D>\frac{\theta }{{i}_{1}}\hspace{1em}\hspace{1em}\left(\mathrm{Ponzi}\hspace{0.33em}\mathrm{finance}\right).$$
(36)

The boundary of hedge finance (34) depends on the signs of \(2\theta -{g}_{1}\), \(2-{g}_{2}\) and \({i}_{1}\). We offer the following numerical simulation as an example because there are many patterns. The boundary between speculative and Ponzi finance depends on the parameter \(\theta\) and the parameter of interest rate \({i}_{1}\). The region of Ponzi finance expands when \(\theta\) decreases or \({i}_{1}\) rises. The decrease in \(\theta\) reduces internal reserves. The rise in \({i}_{1}\) enhances the burden of interest-bearing debt via the increase in the T-O type LRs.

We present a numerical simulation of the financial cycle. We enumerate parameters as \(c=0.8,\) \(\theta =0.6,\) \(t=0.2,\) \({C}_{0}=15,\) \({g}_{1}=2,\) \({g}_{2}=1.1,\) \({i}_{1}=0.1,\) \({g}_{0}=35,\) and \(G=10\). Therefore, we rewrite the dynamic system \(({S}_{b}.2)\) as follows (see Appendix 4):

$$\dot{Y}=\alpha \left[1.16Y-0.11YD-10\right] \qquad \qquad \qquad \qquad \left({S}_{b}.3.1\right),$$
$$\dot{D}=1.4Y-0.01YD-35\qquad \qquad \qquad \qquad \qquad \left({S}_{b}.3.2\right).$$

By considering (34), (35) and (36), the financial regimes are:

$$Y\geqq -\frac{35}{-0.8-0.09D}\hspace{1em}\hspace{1em}\left(\mathrm{hedge}\hspace{0.33em}\mathrm{finance}\right),$$
(37)
$$D\leqq 6\hspace{1em}\hspace{1em}\left(\mathrm{speculative}\hspace{0.33em}\mathrm{finance}\right),$$
(38)
$$D>6\hspace{1em}\hspace{1em}\left(\mathrm{Ponzi}\hspace{0.33em}\mathrm{finance}\right).$$
(39)

Figure 5 shows that there is a closed orbit in dynamic system \(({S}_{b}.3)\) when \(\alpha =0.672\) and the financial structure is HSP.Footnote 29 The equilibrium value of \(Y\) is \({Y}^{*}\fallingdotseq 26.33\). This simulation is an example of Cycle 2. Figure 5 also shows the escalation of financial fragility in the business cycle. In addition, the financial factor destabilizes the economy in Cycle 2. Therefore, escalating financial fragility depicted in Cycle 2 is a more appropriate interpretation of an HSP Minskian structure. As previously mentioned, the financial factor may stabilize the economy in Cycle 1.

Fig. 5
figure 5

Numerical simulation system Sb

In the dynamic system \(({S}_{b})\), we suppose that the interest rate \(i\) depends on the income \(Y\). However, some studies supposed that the interest rate \(i\) depends on the debt burden \(D.\)Footnote 30 We also construct the following dynamic system \(({S}_{c})\) in which the interest rate \(i\) depends on the debt burden \(D\).

We define the money supply function \({M}^{s}\) as:

$${M}^{s}=\mu (i,D)H,\hspace{1em}{\mu }_{i}\equiv \frac{\partial \mu }{\partial i}>0,\hspace{1em}{\mu }_{D}\equiv \frac{\partial \mu }{\partial D}<0.$$
(40)

\({\mu }_{D}<0\) implies that the money supply shrinks as banks, concerned about firms’ increased debt burden \(D\), curtail lending. This effect also expresses LRs.

The money demand function \({M}^{d}\) is:

$${M}^{d}=L(i,D),\hspace{1em}{L}_{i}\equiv \frac{\partial L}{\partial i}<0,\hspace{1em}{L}_{D}\equiv \frac{\partial L}{\partial D}>0,$$
(41)

where \({L}_{D}>0\) also implies that lenders’ liquidity preferences intensify with the decrease in income \(Y\) and the increase in firms’ debt burden \(D\). This effect also expresses LRs.

Ordering (40) and (41), we determined the interest rate \(i\) by equilibrium in the money market as follows:

$$L(i,D)=\mu (i,D)\bar{H}.$$
(42)

Totally differentiating Eq. (42) with respect to the interest rate \(i\) and debt burden D, we obtain

$$i=i\left(D\right),\hspace{1em}{i}_{D}\left(\equiv \frac{\partial i}{\partial D}\right)=-\frac{{L}_{D}-{\mu }_{D}\bar{H}}{{L}_{i}-{\mu }_{i}\bar{H}}>0.$$
(43)

Since \({i}_{D}>0,\) we specify Eq. (43) as followsFootnote 31:

$$i={i}_{2}D,\hspace{1em}{i}_{2}>0.$$
(44)

By ordering (8), (9), (15), (16), (17) and (44), we obtain dynamic system \(({S}_{c})\):

$$\dot{Y}=\alpha \left[c\left(1-\theta -t\right)Y+{C}_{0}+{g}_{1}Y-{g}_{2}\left({i}_{2}D\right)D-{g}_{0}+G-Y\right]\left({S}_{c}.1\right),$$
$$\dot{D}={g}_{1}Y-{g}_{2}\left({i}_{1}D\right)D-{g}_{0}-\theta Y+\left({i}_{2}D\right)D\left({S}_{c}.2\right).$$

The Jacobian matrix of the system \(({S}_{c})\) at equilibrium can be expressed as:

$${J}_{c}=\left(\begin{array}{cc}\alpha ({g}_{1}-s)& -2\alpha {g}_{2}{i}_{2}D\\ {g}_{1}-\theta & 2(1-{g}_{2}){i}_{2}D\end{array}\right).$$
(45)

Therefore, we obtain

$$\mathrm{tr}{J}_{c}=\alpha ({g}_{1}-s)+(1-{g}_{2})2{i}_{2}D,$$
(46)
$$\mathrm{det }{J}_{c}=\alpha 2{i}_{2}D[{g}_{1}-s+(s-\theta ){g}_{2}]>0.$$
(47)

We also obtain \(\mathrm{det }{J}_{c}>0\) by adopting assumption A.1 in this case. Therefore, stability of the system depends solely on the sign of tr \({J}_{c}\). The dynamic system \(({S}_{c})\) is unstable when \(1-{g}_{2}>0\) (Fig. 6-1). However, there is one parameter value \({\alpha }_{c}\) at which Hopf bifurcation occurs when \(1-{g}_{2}<0\). In this case, at least one closed orbit around equilibrium in the system \(({S}_{c})\) occurs when \(\alpha\) is close to \({\alpha }_{c}\) (Fig. 6-2) (Appendix 5). These properties are identical to those in the dynamic system \(({S}_{a})\) because \({i}_{D}(={i}_{2})>0\) also stabilizes the dynamic system \(({S}_{c})\).Footnote 32

Fig. 6
figure 6

Dynamic system Sc

By ordering (3)–(9), (44), we obtain the following financial regimes in the dynamic system \(({S}_{c})\):

$$Y\geqq \frac{\left(2-{g}_{2}\right){i}_{2}}{\left(2\theta -{g}_{1}\right)}{D}^{2}-\frac{{g}_{0}}{\left(2\theta -{g}_{1}\right)}\hspace{1em}\hspace{1em}\left(\mathrm{hedge}\hspace{0.33em}\mathrm{finance}\right),$$
(48)
$$Y\geqq \frac{{i}_{2}}{\theta }{D}^{2}\hspace{1em}\hspace{1em}\left(\mathrm{speculative}\hspace{0.33em}\mathrm{finance}\right),$$
(49)
$$Y<\frac{{i}_{2}}{\theta }{D}^{2}\hspace{1em}\hspace{1em}\left(\mathrm{Ponzi}\hspace{0.33em}\mathrm{finance}\right).$$
(50)

The boundary of hedge finance also depends on the sign of \(2\theta -{g}_{1}\) and \(2-{g}_{2}\). For example, the coefficient of \({D}^{2}\) and the intercept are positive when \(2-{g}_{2}<0\) and \(2\theta -{g}_{1}<0\). The former indicates that the decline in investment demand \(I\) via the increase in debt burden \(D\) exceeds the rising burden of interest-bearing debt \(iD\). This effect leads to the decrease in debt burden. In this case, therefore, the region of hedge finance also expands with the economy.

The boundary between speculative and Ponzi finance depends on the parameter \(\theta\) and the parameter of interest rate \({i}_{2}\). The region of Ponzi finance expands when \(\theta\) falls or \({i}_{2}\) rises. A decrease in \(\theta\) reduces internal reserves. Parameter \({i}_{2}\) captures LRs. For example, an increase in \({i}_{2}\) enhances the burden of interest-bearing debt via the increase in LRs. Therefore, the increase in \({i}_{2}\) reduces the region of hedge finance and enlarges the region of Ponzi finance.

Figure 7 presents one relationship between an HSP structure and the cycle in Fig. 6-2. Figure 7 also shows escalating financial fragility in the business cycle. The progression of fragility in the dynamic system \(({S}_{c})\) resembles that in the dynamic system \(({S}_{a})\), although parameter \({i}_{2}\) contains LRs. We should note that \({i}_{D}(={i}_{2})>0\) stabilizes the dynamic system \(({S}_{c})\).Footnote 33

Fig. 7
figure 7

Financial regimes and cycle: system Sc

4 Conclusion

This study considered two types of Minskian financial structures—LR finance and HSP finance—and discussed financial instability and cycles. Kregel (1997) emphasized the significance of margins of safety for financial instability. LRs affect margins of safety and interest rates. We also simulated financial cycles numerically.

We examined three instances of dynamic systems: (1) when the interest rate is constant (system \(({S}_{a})\)); (2) when it depends on income (system \(({S}_{b})\)); and (3) when it depends on debt burdens (system \(({S}_{c})\)). The system \(({S}_{a})\) can display only the process of escalating financial fragility, which refers to HSP finance during a business cycle. The systems \(({S}_{b})\) and \(({S}_{c})\) can examine LR type financial structures. However, the progression of financial fragility in the system \(({S}_{c})\) resembles that in the system \(({S}_{a})\), although the system \(({S}_{c})\) considers the effects of lenders’ risks. We noted that the financial factor has a sabilizing effect in the business cycles of the system \(({S}_{a})\) and \(({S}_{c})\).

In contrast, one cycle in the system \(({S}_{b})\) occurs when the financial factor causes economic instability. Therefore, we posit that one of the process of increasing financial fragility in the system \(({S}_{b})\) is a more appropriate interpretation of an HSP Minskian financial structure. Furthermore, we presented Taylor–O’Connell type (T-O type) financial instability occurring in the system \(({S}_{b})\). If instability occurs during the progression of increasing financial fragility of the HSP type, then the economy may deteriorate into financial crisis. Fragility becomes instability. Targeting the interest rate helps to avoid the T-O type financial instability. We emphasized the significance of considering both financial structures in dynamic systems.

However, the models in this paper are only two-dimensional systems in debt burden \(D\) and income \(Y\). We need to consider the dynamics of price and income share, and examine monetary policy to avoid this instability.

We assume that the rate of profit sharing \(\theta\) is constant. Sasaki and Fujita (2014) show that the range of fluctuations in business cycles depends on the retention ratio. We also should develop our model with a formulation that considers the borrower’s risk and differs from the money market equilibrium condition.Footnote 34 Furthermore, our study is a theoretical analysis following Ninomiya and Tokuda (2012, 2021), who examined T-O type financial instability using VAR analysis. In a future study, we will examine HSP-type instability empirically based on this research.

Availability of data and materials

Not applicable.

Notes

  1. Minsky (1982a), pp.65–66. See Nabeshima (2017) for more details.

  2. Kregel (2008) asserted that safety cushions had been insufficient from the beginning of the subprime loan crisis, and the crisis did not represent a conventional Minsky process. Ninomiya and Tokuda (2017) contended that their investigation may support this argument.

  3. See, for example, Keen (1995), Asada (2001, 2006), Ninomiya (2006), Hein (2007), Charles (2008a), Sasaki and Fujita (2014), Ninomiya (2018), and Asada et al. (2019).

  4. Nishi (2012a) investigated the dynamic relationships among income distribution, debt ratio, and capital accumulation in the Japanese economy. Ninomiya and Tokuda (2017) considered the instability of confidence and structural change.

  5. See Foley (2003), Lima and Meirelles (2007), Charles (2008b), and Sasaki and Fujita (2014).

  6. Some models depend on the endogenous money theory (horizontalist) of the post-Keynesian school, thereby assuming that the interest rate is constant. Controversy within the post-Keynesian school remains regarding the endogenous money supply theory. The horizontalists believe that the central bank supplies high-powered money completely passively, whereas the structuralists believe that there is a limited supply. Naito (2011) asserted that Minsky was primarily a structuralist.

    Minsky (1982b) contended that an increase in the interest rate triggers recession from a euphoric boom. See Nabeshima (2017) for more details. Accordingly, we emphasize the LR financial structure formulated by Taylor and O’Connell (1985).

  7. Minksy (1986) explained the difference between financial instability hypothesis and Kalecki (1971) with respect to profits as follow: “The financial instability hypothesis identifies profits, determined as Kelecki shows, as a cash flow that does or does not validate past financial commitments; it integrates Kalecki’s vision of the dynamic determination of profits with the capitalist institutional fact of a liability structure inherited from the past that commits current and future profits” (p.118).

  8. Investment function (9) is based on Kaldorian business cycle models. Using the S-sharped investment function for income, Kaldor (1940) presented an endogenous business cycle. Meanwhile, Chang and Smyth (1971) used the Poincaré–Bendixson theorem to investigate the work of Kaldor (1940). Asada (1995) did not assume the S-shaped investment function and developed a Kaldorian business cycle model in an open economy.

    However, investment function (9) depends on debt burden. This formulation is based on Adachi (1994) and Asada (1997, 2001). Adachi (1994) formulated the discounted present value of expected returns PV from investment as follows:

    \(PV=\frac{Q}{i+\sigma },\)

    where Q is the average expected returns, i is the interest rate, and σ is the risk premium. Adachi (1994) assumed that the risk premium increases with an increase in debt burden and presented a simple optimization model that posits the dependence of investment on debt burden. Asada (1997, 2001) used an optimization model to extend the ‘Penrose effect’ (Uzawa 1969) to debt burden and show how investment depends on debt burden. Adachi (1994) and Asada (1997, 2001) based their study on the principle of increasing risk (Kalecki, 1937). Furthermore, Asada and Semmler (1995) and Nakamura (2002) discussed the investment based on Kalecki (1937).

    The Cabinet Office (2006) empirically discussed the relationship between the investment and the interest-bearing debt burden during 1990–2004 in Japan. After the collapse of the bubble economy in 1991, the problem of non-performing loans had become more severe in Japan.

  9. For simplicity, we ignore corporate income tax in this paper; however, considering corporate income tax is crucial for future studies expanding on this paper. A reduction in corporate income tax improves firms’ financial condition, which may have the effect of deterring financial instability.

  10. If \({g}_{1}-s>0\), we obtain \(\frac{d\dot{Y}}{dY}>0\). By contrast, If \({g}_{1}-s<0\), we obtain \(\frac{d\dot{Y}}{dY}<0\).

  11. See, for example, Asada (1995) and, Ninomiya (2007, 2018).

  12. Equilibrium income \({Y}_{a}^{*}\) is \({Y}_{a}^{*}=\frac{{g}_{2}({C}_{0}+G)-({C}_{0}-{g}_{0}+G)}{{(s-\theta )g}_{2}+{g}_{1}-s}.\)

    Equilibrium debt burden \({D}_{a}^{*}\) is \({D}_{a}^{*}=\frac{{g}_{0}\left({g}_{1}-s\right)+({C}_{0}+G-{g}_{0})({g}_{1}-\theta )}{{i}_{0}\{{g}_{2}\left({g}_{1}-\theta \right)-({g}_{1}-s)({g}_{2}-1)\}}.\)

  13. \(s-\theta =\left\{1-c\left(1-\theta -t\right)\right\}-\theta =\left(1-\theta \right)\left(1-c\right)+ct>0.\)

  14. See Gandolfo (1997) for more information on the Hopf bifurcation theorem.

  15. Two types in Hopf bifurcations exist. If the closed orbit exists in the region of \(\alpha\) < \({\alpha }_{a}\), it is an unstable periodic orbit. By contrast, if the closed orbit exists in the region of \(\alpha\) > \({\alpha }_{a}\), it is a stable periodic orbit. The unstable periodic orbit is called a subcritical Hopf bifurcation, whereas the stable periodic orbit is called a supercritical Hopf bifurcation. We are unable to confirm the type of cycles in this paper.

  16. Only this cycle occurs when the interest rate is constant.

  17. As previously stated, the reduction in investment demand I refrains from increasing in debt burden D. Therefore, the financial regime shifts to the speculative finance (2) region, which satisfies the hedge finance condition. However, a decrease in investment demand I induces the recession.

  18. If \({g}_{2}\) becomes small at Point C, the economy might fall into a financial crisis and the debt burdens \(D\) would continue to increase.

  19. The cycle in the dynamic system \(({S}_{a}.1)\) is similar to Asada (2001), although the interest rate is constant in the cycle.

  20. We cannot determine whether a closed orbit exists in the regions of \(\alpha\) < \({\alpha }_{a}\) or \(\alpha\) > \({\alpha }_{a}\).

  21. The cycle in Fig. 4 contains the period \(D<0\). This indicates that firms lend or firms’ bank balances exceed their outstanding loans because investment demand is extremely low.

  22. \({L}_{Y}<0\) is based on Taylor and O’Connell (1985). As we mentioned, Taylor and O’Connell (1985) formulated that lenders’ liquidity preferences (the money demand function) intensify with a decrease in the expected profit rate (\(\rho\)). They hypothesized that raising the expected profit rate (\(\rho\)) would lower the interest rate (\(i\)). They claimed that a true Minsky crisis occurs when the value of derivatives (\({i}_{\rho }\)) falls dramatically. Ninomiya (2007, 2018) and Ninomiya and Tokuda (2017) investigated T-O type LRs using a simple microeconomic framework.

  23. See Ninomiya (2007, 2018) and Ninomiya and Tokuda (2017) for more details.

  24. Lima and Meirelles (2007) and Ryoo (2013) introduce the effect of bank profitability on credit supply.

  25. Although this paper only focuses on lenders’ risks, the borrowers’ risks proposed by Minsky are also crucial. Okishio (1986), Ninomiya (2006), and Ninomiya and Tokuda (2017) demonstrated that the interest rate is determined by the bond market as follows:

    \(-\left[\left(I-S\right)+\left({M}^{d}-{M}^{s}\right)\right]=0,\)    (F.22)

    where S is savings, investment I represents the borrowers’ behavior, and investment depends on the income and interest-bearing debt burden. Ninomiya (2006) considered the borrowers’ risks. We adopt Eqs. (28) and (42) to simplify the analysis in this paper and would like to consider borrowers’ risks in more detail in future research.

  26. Cycle 1 is also similar to Asada (2001). However, he did not consider the T-O type financial instability.

  27. According to Minsky (1975), “lender’s risk does appear on signed contracts.” For any set of market conditions, as applied to a particular firm, lender’s risk takes the form of increased cash flow requirements in debt contracts as the debt-to-total-asset ratio increases. Lender’s risk manifests itself in financial contracts in various forms: higher interest rates, shorter terms to maturity, the requirement to pledge specific assets as collateral, and restrictions on dividend payments and further borrowing. The lender’s risk rises with an increase in the ratio of debt to equity financing or the ratio of commitment cash flows to total prospective cash flow” (p. 110).

    A recession increases the ratio of commitment cash flows to total prospective cash flow. Therefore, T-O type LRs will also rise.

  28. Equilibrium income \({Y}_{b}^{*}\) is \({Y}_{b}^{*}=\frac{{{g}_{0}-(1-g_{2})}({C}_{0}+G)}{{(g}_{1}-\theta )+(1-{g}_{2})(1-s)}.\)

    Equilibrium debt burden \({D}_{b}^{*}\) is \({D}_{b}^{*}=\frac{\left({C}_{0}+G\right)\left({g}_{1}-\theta \right)+(1-s){g}_{0}}{{\{g}_{0}-({C}_{0}+G)(1-{g}_{2})\}{i}_{1}}.\)

  29. The closed orbit exists in the region of \(\alpha\) < \({\alpha }_{b}\); therefore, this seems to be a subcritical Hopf bifurcation.

  30. See, for example, Asada (2006) and Adada et al. (2019). Asada (2006) said “the private debt and public bond are imperfect substitutes, and the difference of the rates of interest of these assets reflects the difference of the ‘degrees of the risk’ of these assets (p. 469).

  31. For example, Asada (2001) assumed that.

    \({i}^{*}=i+\varphi \left(d\right), \varphi \left(d\right)\ge 0, \varphi \mathrm{^{\prime}}\left(d\right)\ge 0,\)    (F.33)

    where i* is the interest rate that applied initial debt. i is the market rate of interest. d is the debt–capital ratio. As previously stated, Asada (1997, 2001) discussed investment based on the increasing risk principles (Kalecki, 1937). It seems that the principle of increasing risk captured mainly borrower’s risk. Equation 43 indicates only the lenders’ risks. That is, the interest rate affects the investment decision. Asada (1997) captured (F.33) as a lender’s risk based on Kalecki (1937) and Minsky (1986).

    Ninomiya (2015, 2016) and Ninomiya and Tokuda (2017) investigated the case of \({i}_{D}<0\) by using (F.22) in footnote 22 and an investment function that is dependent on debt burden, such as Eq. (9). It seems that \({i}_{D}<0\) is an extremely rare case. However, Ninomiya and Tokuda (2017) implied \({i}_{D}<0\) during a serious recession after the collapse of the bubble economy in Japan.

  32. The cycle in the dynamic system \(\left({S}_{c}\right)\) is very similar to Asada (2001).

  33. If we follow the definition of lender’s risk by Minsky (1975), it might be more appropriate to use \({\mu }_{D}<0\) in Eq. (40) and \({L}_{D}>0\) in Eq. (41) as the formulation of lenders’ risks. Although \({i}_{D}(={i}_{2})>0\) stabilizes the dynamic system \(({S}_{c})\), the decrease in the absolute value of \({\mu }_{D}\), for example, makes the stabilizing effect small.

  34. See Fazzari et al. (2008). Godley and Lavoie (2007) and Dos Santos and Zezza (2008) develop a stock-flow-consistent model. Okishio (1986) examines stock-flow relations among the central bank, commercial banks, firms and households, and, presents it as an \(IS\)-\(BB\) analysis.

References

  • Adachi H (1994) Theory of macrodynamics. Yuhikaku Publishing (in Japanese)

  • Asada T (1995) Kaldorian dynamics in an open economy. J Econ 62(3):239–269

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Asada T (2001) Nonlinear dynamics of debt and capital: a post-Keynesian analysis. In: Aruka Y, Japanese Association for Evolutionary Economics (eds) Evolutionary controversies in economics: a new transdisciplinary approach. Springer, Berlin, pp 73–87

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Asada T (2006) Stabilization policy in a Keynes-Goodwin model with debt accumulation. Struct Chang Econ Dyn 17:466–485

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Asada T, Denetrian M, Zimka R (2019) On dynamic in a Keynesian model of monetary and fiscal stabilization policy mix with twin debt accumulation. Metroeconomica 70:365–383

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Asada T (1997) Macrodynamics of growth and cycles, Nihon Keizai Hyoronsha (in Japanese)

  • Cabinet Office (2006) Anneal Report on the Japanese Economy and Public Finance 2006. https://www5.cao.go.jp/zenbun/wp-e/wp-je06/06-00201.html#sb2_1_2. Accessed 27 Jun 2022.

  • Chang WW, Smyth DJ (1971) The existence and persistence of cycles in a non-linear model: Kaldor’s 1940 model re-examined. Rev Econ Stud 38(1):37–44

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Charles S (2008a) Corporate debt, variable retention rate and the appearance of financial fragility. Camb J Econ 32(5):781–795

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Charles S (2008b) A post-Keynesian model of accumulation with Minskian financial structure. Rev Polit Econ 20(3):319–331

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dos Santos HC, Zezza G (2008) A simplified’, benchmark’, stock-flow consistent post-Keynesian growth model. Metroeconomica 59(3):441–478

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fazzari S, Ferri P, Greenberg E (2008) Cash flow, investment, and Keynes-Minsky cycle. J Econ Behav Organ 65:555–572

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Foley DK (2003) Financial fragility in developing economics. In: Dutt AK, Ros J (eds) Development economics and structuralist macroeconomics. Edward Elgar, pp 157–168

    Google Scholar 

  • Gandolfo G (1997) Economic dynamics. Springer

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Godley W, Lavoie M (2007) Monetary economics: an integrated approach to credit and wealth. Macmillan, Palgrave

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Hein E (2007) Interest rate, debt, distribution and capital accumulation in post-Kaleckian model. Metroeconomica 58:310–339

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaldor N (1940) A model of trade cycle. Econ J 50:78–92

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kalecki M (1937) The principle of increasing risk. Economica 14:440–447

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kalecki M (1971) Selected essays dynamic of capitalist economy 1933–1970. Cambridge University Press

    Google Scholar 

  • Keen S (1995) Finance and economic breakdown modelling Minsky’s ’financial instability hypothesis. J Post Keynesian Econ 17:607–635

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kregel JA (1997) Margin of safety and weight of argument in generating financial fragility. J Econ Issues 31(2):543–548

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kregel JA (2008) Using Minsky’s cushions of safety to analyze the crisis in the U.S. Subprime Mortgage Market. Int J Polit Econ 37(1):3–23

    Google Scholar 

  • Lima GT, Meirelles JA (2007) Macroeconomics of debt regimes, financial instability and growth. Camb J Econ 31(4):563–580

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Minsky HP (1975) John Maynard Keynes. Columbia University Press

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Minsky HP (1982a) Can “It” happen again? Essays on instability and finance. M. E. Sharpe

  • Minsky HP (1982b) The financial-instability hypothesis: capitalist processes and the behavior of the economy. In: Kindleberger CP, Laffergue J (eds) Financial crisis: theory, history and policy. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Minsky HP (1986) Stabilizing an unstable economy. Yale University Press

    Google Scholar 

  • Nabeshima N (2017) Post Keynesian economics: In quest for an alternative macroeconomic theory. Nagoya University Press. (in Japanese)

    Google Scholar 

  • Naito A (2011) Rebuilding the theory of endogenous money: a post-Keynesian money-credit approach. Nihon Keizai Hyoronsha (in Japanese)

  • Nakamura T (2002) ‘The principle of increasing risk’: Kalecki’s investment theory revisited. Rev Polit Econ 14(1):115–123

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ninomiya K (2006) Macroeconomics of financial crises. Chuokeizai-sha (in Japanese)

  • Ninomiya K (2007) Open economy financial instability. J Korean Econ 8(2):329–355

    Google Scholar 

  • Ninomiya K (2015) Debt burden, confidence, and financial instability and cycles. Polit Econ Quart 51(4):85–93 (in Japanese)

    Google Scholar 

  • Ninomiya K (2016) Financial structure, financial instability, and inflation targeting. Evol Inst Econ Rev 13(1):23–36

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ninomiya K (2018) The macrodynamics of financial instability. Otuki Shoten Publishers (in Japanese)

  • Ninomiya K, Tokuda M (2012) Structural change and financial instability in an open economy. Korea World Econ 13(1):1–37

    Google Scholar 

  • Ninomiya K, Tokuda M (2017) Financial instability in Japan: debt, confidence, and financial structure. Res Polit Econ 32:39–61

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ninomiya K, Tokuda M (2021) Structural change and financial instability in the US economy. Evol Inst Econ Rev 18(1):205–226

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nishi H (2012a) A dynamic analysis of debt-led and debt burdened growth regimes with Minskian financial structure. Metroeconomica 63(4):634–660

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nishi H (2012b) Structural VAR analysis of debt, capital accumulation, and income distribution in the Japanese economy: a post Keynesian perspective. J Post Keynesian Econ 34(4):685–712

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nishi H (2021) Financial instability hypothesis and determinants of firms’ debt-ratio in the Japanese economy. Polit Econ Quart 57(4):7–33 (in Japanese)

    Google Scholar 

  • Okishio N (1986) The movement of interest rate and exchange rate. Kokumin Keizai Zasshi 154(6):46–69 (in Japanese)

    Google Scholar 

  • Rose H (1969) Real monetary factors in the business cycle. J Money Credit Bank 1(2):138–152

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ryoo S (2013) Bank profitability, leverage and financial instability: a Minsky-Harrod model. Camb J Econ 37:1127–1160

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sasaki H, Fujita S (2014) Pro-shareholder income distribution, debt accumulation, and cyclical fluctuations in a post-Keynesian model with labor supply constraints. Eur J Econ Econ Pol Intervent 11(1):10–30

    Google Scholar 

  • Taylor L, O’Connell SA (1985) A Minsky crisis. Quart J Econ 100:871–885

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Uzawa H (1969) Time preference and the Penrose effect in a two-class model of economic growth. J Polit Econ 77:171–204

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The author is grateful to anonymous referees, Professor Hiroyuki Uni (Kyoto University, Emeritus), Hiroyuki Takami (Oita University), Naoki Yoshihara (UMass Amherst), Hiroaki Sasaki (Kyoto University), Takashi Ohno (Doshisha University), Shinya Fujita (Nagoya University), and So Kneko (Oita University) for their many valuable comments. Needless to say, however, only the author is responsible for any remaining errors. The author would like to extend his gratitude to the Grant-in-Aid for Scientific Research from the Japan Society for the Promotion of Science (22K01414)(16K03633); the Ryosui Foundation, the Supporter’s Association of the Faculty of Economics, Shiga University; the Risk Research Center of the Faculty of Economics, Shiga University; and Shiga University for their financial supports.

Funding

(1) The Grant-in-Aid for Scientific Research from the Japan Society for the Promotion of Science (22K01414)(16K03633), (2) The Ryosui Foundation, (3) The Supporterís Association of the Faculty of Economics, Shiga University, (4) the Risk Research Center of the Faculty of Economics, Shiga University, (5) Shiga University.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Kenshiro Ninomiya.

Ethics declarations

Competing interests

The author declares that I have no competing interests.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

The method of the proof in Appendices 1, 2 and 3 is based on Gandolfo (1997).

Appendix 1

The method of the proof in Appendices 1, 2 and 3 is based on Gandolfo (1997).

Suppose \(1-{g}_{2}<0\). The characteristic equation of system \(({S}_{a})\) is

$${\lambda }^{2}+(-\mathrm{tr}J)\lambda +(\mathrm{det}J)=0.$$

A necessary condition of the Hopf bifurcation for complex roots is det \({J}_{a}>0\), which is satisfied from (22). Regarding tr \({J}_{a}\), we find that

Roots of the characteristic equation are

$${\lambda }_{\mathrm{1,2}}=-\frac{1}{2}(-\mathrm{tr}J)\pm \sqrt{(-\mathrm{tr}J{)}^{2}-4(\mathrm{det}J)}.$$

Because tr \({J}_{a}=0\) for critical value \({\alpha }_{a}\) of the parameter, the characteristic equation has a pair of pure imaginary roots, \({\lambda }_{\mathrm{1,2}}=\pm i\sqrt{(\mathrm{det}{J}_{a})}\) (where \(i=\sqrt{-1}\)). Roots of the above equation remain a complex conjugate for (\(-\) tr \({J}_{a}\)) sufficiently small, namely for \(\alpha\) sufficiently near \({\alpha }_{a}\).

We obtain

$${\frac{d(tr{J}_{a}/2)}{d\alpha }}_{\alpha ={\alpha }_{a}}=\frac{{g}_{1}-s}{2}\ne 0.$$

From the preceding discussion, all conditions for Hopf bifurcation are satisfied at Point \(\alpha ={\alpha }_{a}\).

Appendix 2

We specify the consumption function (16) and investment function (9) as follows:

$$C=c\left(1-\theta -t\right)Y+{C}_{0}=0.6\left(1-0.5-0.2\right)Y+15,$$
(51)
$$I={g}_{1}Y-{g}_{2}iD-{g}_{0}=2Y-3D-35,$$
(52)

where \(c=0.6,\) \(\theta =0.5,\) t = 0.2, \({C}_{0}=15,\) \({g}_{1}=2,\) \({g}_{2}=3,\) \(i=1(\mathrm{\%}),\) and \({g}_{0}=35\).

Ordering (8), (17), (51), (52) and \(G=30\), we obtain

$$\dot{Y}=\alpha [0.6(1-0.5-0.2)Y+15+2Y-3D-35+30-Y],$$
$$\dot{D}=2Y-3D-35-0.5Y+1D.$$

Therefore, we obtain the dynamic system \(({S}_{a}.2)\).

Appendix 3

det \({J}_{b}>0\) is satisfied from (32) when \({i}_{1}>0\). Regarding tr \({J}_{b}\), we find that

$${\alpha }_{b}=\frac{-(1-{g}_{2}){i}_{2}Y}{({g}_{1}-s)-{g}_{2}{i}_{2}D}>0.$$

Because tr \({J}_{b}=0\) for the critical value \({\alpha }_{b}\) of the parameter. We obtain

$${\frac{d(tr{J}_{b}/2)}{d\alpha }}_{\alpha ={\alpha }_{b}}=\frac{({g}_{1}-s)-{g}_{2}{i}_{1}D}{2}\ne 0.$$

From the proceeding discussion, all conditions in which Hopf bifurcation occurs are satisfied at the point \(\alpha ={\alpha }_{b}\).

Appendix 4

We specify the consumption function (16) and investment function (9) as follows:

$$C=c\left(1-\theta -t\right)Y+{C}_{0}=0.8\left(1-0.6-0.2\right)Y+15,$$
(53)
$$I={g}_{1}Y-{g}_{2}iD-{g}_{0}=2Y-1.1iD-35,$$
(54)

where \(c=0.8,\) \(\theta =0.6,\) \(t=0.2,\) \({C}_{0}=15,\) \({g}_{1}=1.5,\) \({g}_{2}=1.1,\) and \({g}_{0}=35\). We also specify Eq. (33) as follows:

$$i={i}_{1}Y=0.1Y.$$
(55)

Ordering (8), (17), (53), (54), (55) and \(G=10\), we obtain

$$\dot{Y}=\alpha [0.8(1-0.6-0.2)Y+15+2Y-1.1*0.1YD-35+10-Y],$$
$$\dot{D}=2Y-1.1*0.1YD-35-0.6Y+0.1YD.$$

Therefore, we obtain the dynamic system \(({S}_{b}.3)\).

Appendix 5

Suppose \(1-{g}_{2}<0\). det \({J}_{c}>0\) is satisfied from (47). Regarding tr \({J}_{c}\), we find that

Because tr \({J}_{c}=0\) for the critical value \({\alpha }_{c}\) of the parameter. We obtain

$${\frac{d(tr{J}_{c}/2)}{d\alpha }}_{\alpha ={\alpha }_{c}}=\frac{{g}_{1}-s}{2}\ne 0.$$

From the preceding discussion, all conditions in which Hopf bifurcation occurs are satisfied at Point \(\alpha ={\alpha }_{c}\).

Rights and permissions

Open Access This article is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License, which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons licence, and indicate if changes were made. The images or other third party material in this article are included in the article's Creative Commons licence, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the article's Creative Commons licence and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder. To view a copy of this licence, visit http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Ninomiya, K. Financial structure, cycle, and instability. Economic Structures 11, 19 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1186/s40008-022-00275-7

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1186/s40008-022-00275-7

Keywords

JEL classification