Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-gtxcr Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-23T07:09:32.176Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Morris A. Copeland: A Case Study in the History of Institutional Economics

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  11 June 2009

Malcolm Rutherford
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, University of Victoria, P.O. Box 1700 STN CSC, Victoria BC, V8W 2Y2, Canada.

Extract

Morris A. Copeland's work and career as an institutional economist has been the subject of only one significant paper (Millar 1980) and is not well known today, even among institutionalists. The standard histories of institutional economics have tended to focus on a few leading figures, notably Thorstein Veblen, Wesley C. Mitchell, John R. Commons, and Clarence Ayres, and have largely ignored the many others (some of whom had outstanding careers) associated with the movement. This narrow focus has given a misleading impression both of the institutionalist movement itself and also of the nature of the institutionalist contribution to economics. The examination of Copeland's career, treated as a case study in the history of institutional economics, can help correct this problem. Copeland is a perfect candidate for such a case study due to his central place within the interwar institutionalist movement, his teachers, the contacts he maintained, his work in both academic economics and in public service, and his professional standing within economics more generally.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © The History of Economics Society 2002

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Ayres, Clarence E. 1921. “Instinct and Capacity I.Journal of Philosophy 18 (10 13): 561–65.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ayres, Clarence E. 1944. The Theory of Economic Progress, 2nd edition. New York: Schocken Books, 1962.Google Scholar
Ayres, Clarence E. 1951. “The Co-ordinates of Institutionalism.” American Economic Review 41 (05): 4755.Google Scholar
Ayres, Clarence E. 1968. “The Price System and Public Policy.” Journal of Economic Issues 2 (09): 342–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Burns, Eveline M. 1931. “Does Institutional Economics Complement or Compete with “Orthodox” Economics?American Economic Review 21 (03): 8087.Google Scholar
Central Statistical Board. 1939. The Central Statistical Board and its Work. Prepared for the use of the Committee on Expenditures in the Executive Departments, House of Representatives, in Connection with consideration of HR 5917, 76th Congress, April 25, 1939. Morris A. Copeland Papers, Box 3, Central Statistical Board Folder, Butler Library, Columbia University.Google Scholar
Clark, J. M. 1919. “Economic Theory in an Era of Social Readjustment.” American Economic Review 9 (03): 280–90.Google Scholar
Clark, J. M. 1923. Studies in the Economics of Overhead Costs. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Clark, John M., Hamilton, Walton H., and Moulton, Harold G., eds., 1918. Readings in the Economics of War. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Cohen, Jacob. 1972. “Copeland's Moneyflows After Twenty-Five Years: A Survey.” Journal of Economic Literature 10 (03): 125.Google Scholar
Committee on Government Statistics and Information Services. 1933. “The Statistical Services of the Federal Government in Relation to the Recovery Program.” Report Addressed to Hon. John Dickenson, Assistant Secretary of Commerce and Dr. Alexander Sachs, Chief of Research and Planning, Industrial Recovery Administration, Washington DC, July 1933. Morris A Copeland Papers, Box 3, Central Statistical Board Folder.Google Scholar
Commons, John R. 1924. The Legal Foundations of Capitalism. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1920. “Seasonal Problems in Financial Administration.” Journal of Political Economy 28 (12): 793826.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1921. Some Phases of Institutional Value Theory. Ph.D. Thesis, University of Chicago. Morris A. Copeland Papers, Box 8, Manuscripts by M. A. Copeland Folder.Google Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1924. “Communities of Economic Interest and the Price System.” In Tugwell, Rexford G., ed., The Trend of Economics, Port Washington NY: Kennikat Press, pp. 105–50, reprinted 1971.Google Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1925a. “The Economics of Advertising-Discussion.” American Economic Review 15 (03): 3841.Google Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1925b. “Review of John M. Clark, Studies in the Economics of Overhead Costs.” Political Science Quarterly 40 (06): 296–99.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1925c. “Professor Knight on Psychology.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 40 (11): 134–51.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1926. “Desire Choice, and Purpose from a Natural-Evolutionary Standpoint.” Psychological Review 33 (07): 245–67CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1927. “An Instrumental View of the Part-Whole Relation.” Journal of Philosophy 24 (02 17): 96104CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1928. “An Estimate of Total Volume of Debts to Individual Accounts in the United States.” Journal of the American Statistical Association 23 (09): 301303.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1929a. “Two Hypotheses Concerning the Equation of Exchange.” Journal of the American Statistical Association 24, Supplement (03): 146–48.Google Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1929b. “Special Purpose Indexes for the Equation of Exchange for the United States, 1919 1927.” Journal of the American Statistical Association 24 (06): 109–22.Google Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1929c. “Money, Trade, and Prices—A Test of Causal Primacy.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 43 (08): 648–66.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1929d. “The National Income and its Distribution.” In Recent Economic Changes in the United States, vol. 2. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1930. “Psychology and the Natural Science Point of View.” In Morris A. Copeland, Fact and Theory in Economics. Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1973, pp. 1136.Google Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1931a. “Economic Theory and the Natural Science Point of View.” American Economic Review 21 (03): 6779.Google Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1931b. “Some Suggestions for Improving Our Information on Wholesale Commodity Prices.” Journal of the American Statistical Association 26, Supplement (03): 110–15.Google Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1932a. “Some Problems in the Theory of National Income.” Journal of Political Economy 40 (02): 151.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1932b. “How Large is our National Income?Journal of Political Economy 40 (12): 771–95.Google Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1934. “The Theory of Monopolistic Competition.” Reprinted in Morris A. Copeland, Fact and Theory in Economics. Westport Conn: Greenwood Press, 1973, pp. 247–51.Google Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1935. “National Wealth and Income—An Interpretation.” Journal of the American Statistical Association 30 (06): 377–86.Google Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1936. “Commons's Institutionalismin Relation to Problems of Social Evolution and Economic Planning.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 50 (02): 333–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1937. “Concepts of National Income.” In Studies in Income and Wealth, vol I. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1939a. “Public Investment in the United States.” American Economic Review 29 (03): 3341.Google Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1939b. “Aims and Purposes of the United States Central Statistical Board.” The Controller 7 (07): 236–37, 255.Google Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1940a. “Examining for Professional Positions.” Personnel Administration 2 (01): 14.Google Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1940b. “Competing Products and Monopolistic Competition.” Reprinted in Morris A. Copeland, Fact and Theory in Economics. Westport Conn: Greenwood Press, 1973, pp. 251–300.Google Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1941. “Economic Research in the Federal Government.” American Economic Review 31 (09): 526–36.Google Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1942a. “Production Planning for a War Economy.” Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science 220 (03): 94105.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1942b. “The Defense Effort and the National Income Response Pattern.” Journal of Political Economy 50 (06): 415–26.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1944. “Business Stabilization by Agreement.” Reprinted in Morris A. Copeland, Fact and Theory in Economics. Westport Conn: Greenwood Press, 1973, pp. 310–25.Google Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1948. “Authority and Reason as Instruments of Coordination in the United States.” In Morris A. Copeland, Fact and Theory in Economics. Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1973, pp. 119–29.Google Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1951. “Institutional Economics and Model Analysis.” American Economic Review 41 (05): 5665.Google Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1952a. A Study of Moneyflows in the United States. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1952b. The Keynesian Reformation: Three Lectures. Delhi: Delhi School of Economics.Google Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1955. “Statistics and Objective Economics.” Reprinted in Morris A. Copeland, Fact and Theory in Economics. Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1973, pp. 67–91.Google Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1958a. “Institutionalism and Welfare Economics.” American Economic Review 48 (03): 117.Google Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1958b. “On the Scope and Method of Economics.” In Dowd, Douglas F., ed., Thorstein Veblen: A Critical Reappraisal. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1965. Our Free Enterprise System. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1966. Toward Full Employment in our Free Enterprise Economy. New York: Fordham University Press.Google Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1967. “Laissez Faire, Pecuniary Incentives, and Public Policy.” Journal of Economic Issues 1 (12): 335–48.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1970. “On Unemployment and Overemployment, Assuming Wage and Price Stability (Flexibility).” Journal of Economic Issues 4 (0609): 4059. Corrigenda, Journal of Economic Issues 5 (June 1971): 134–36.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1974. “Concerning the Origin of a Money Economy.” American Journal of Economics and Sociology 33 (01): 117.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1977. “Foreign Exchange in the Eastern Mediterranean in the 4th Century, B.C.American Journal of Economics and Sociology 36 (04): 205–15.Google Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1981a. Essays in Socioeconomic Evolution. New York: Vantage Press.Google Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1981b. “Bank Deposit Currency Before A. D. 1700.” Research in Economic History 6: 245–54.Google Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. and Martin, Edwin M.. 1938. “The Correction of Wealth and Income Estimates for Price Changes.” In Studies in Income and Wealth, vol II. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. and Martin, Edwin M.. 1939. “National Income and Capital Formation.” Journal of Political Economy 47 (06): 398407.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dawson, John C. 1991. “Copeland as Social Accountant.” In Dawson, John C., ed., Flow of Funds Analysis: A Handbook for Practitioners. Armonk, NY: M. E. Sharpe, 1996.Google Scholar
Dawson, John C., ed. 1996. Flow of Funds Analysis: A Handbook for Practitioners. Armonk, New York: M. E. Sharpe.Google Scholar
Dorfman, Joseph. 1958. “Walter Winne Stewart (1815–1958).” Year Book of the American Philosophical Society. Philadelphia: American Philosophical Society, pp. 155–59.Google Scholar
Dowd, Douglas F. ed. 1958. Thorstein Veblen: A Critical Reappraisal. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Duncan, Joseph W. and Shelton, William C.. 1978. Revolution in United States Government Statistics, 1926–1976. Washington D. C.: U. S. Department of Commerce.Google Scholar
Givens, Meredith. 1934. “An Experiment in Advisory Service: The Committee on Government Statistics and Information Services.” Journal of the American Statistical Association 29 (12): 394404.Google Scholar
Hamilton, Walton. 1917. “Problems of Economic Instruction.” Journal of Political Economy 25 (01): 113.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamilton, Walton. 1919. “The Institutional Approach to Economic Theory.” American Economic Review 9 (03): 309–18.Google Scholar
Hammond, J. Daniel. 1996. Theory and Measurement: Causality Issues in Milton Friedman's Monetary Economics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kantor, J. R. 1922. “An Essay Toward an Institutional Conception of Social Psychology.” American Journal of Sociology 27 (03): 611–27; (May): 758–79.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kantor, J. R. 1924. “The Institutional Foundation of a Scientific Social Psychology.” American Journal of Sociology 29 (05): 674–87.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kuznets, Simon. 1937. National Income and Capital Formation, 1919–1935: A Preliminary Report. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
McDougall, William. 1924. “Can Sociology and Social Psychology Dispense with Instincts?American Journal of Sociology 29 (05): 657–73.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mehrling, Perry G. 1997. The Money Interest and the Public Interest: American Monetary Thought 1920–1979. Cambridge MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Millar, James R. 1980. “Institutionalism from a Natural Science Point of View: An Intellectual Profile of Morris A. Copeland.” In Adams, John, ed., Institutional Economics: Essays in Honor of Allan G. Gruchy. Boston, MA: Martinus Nijhoff, pp. 105–24.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mitchell, Wesley C. 1910. “Money Economy and Modern Civilization” (Paper Read Before the Cross-Roads Club of Stanford, May 6, 1910), edited by Malcolm Rutherford. History of Political Economy 28 (Fall 1996): 329–57.Google Scholar
Mitchell, Wesley C. 1925. “Quantitative Analysis in Economic Theory.” American Economic Review 15 (03): 112.Google Scholar
Mitchell, Wesley C. 1927. Business Cycles: The Problem and its Setting. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
Rice, Stuart. 1933. “Committee on Governmental Statistics and Information Services.” Journal of the American Statistical Association 28 (09): 333–34.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rutherford, Malcolm. 1999. “Institutionalism as ‘Scientific Economics.” In Backhouse, Roger and Creedy, John, eds., From Classical Economics to the Theory of the Firm: Essays in Honour of D. P. O'Brien. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, pp. 223–42.Google Scholar
Rutherford, Malcolm. 2000a. “Institutionalism Between the Wars.” Journal of Economic Issues 34 (06): 291303.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rutherford, Malcolm. 2000b. “Understanding Institutional Economics: 1918–1929.” Journal of the History of Economic Thought 22 (09): 277308.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rutherford, Malcolm. forthcoming. “On the Economic Frontier: Walton Hamilton, Institutional Economics, and Education.” History of Political Economy.Google Scholar
Stewart, Walter W. 1919. “Economic Theory—Discussion.” American Economic Review 9 (03): 319–20.Google Scholar
Stone, Richard. 1947. “Definition and Measurement of the National Income and Related Topics.” Appendix to Measurement of Nsational Income and the Construction of Social Accounts, Report of the Sub-Committee on National Income Statistics of the League of Nations Committee of Statistical Experts. Geneva: United Nations.Google Scholar
Yohe, William P. 1982. “The Mysterious Career of Walter W. Stewart, especially 1922–1930.” History of Political Economy 14 (Winter): 583607.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Yohe, William P. 1990. “The Intellectual Milieu at the Federal Reserve Board in the 1920s.” History of Political Economy 22 (Fall): 465–88.CrossRefGoogle Scholar