Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-p2v8j Total loading time: 0.001 Render date: 2024-05-16T04:04:27.526Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Equilibrium and ${\rm {\cal A}}$-efficient fertility with increasing returns to population and endogenous mortality

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  07 May 2020

Robert Tamura*
Affiliation:
Clemson University
David Cuberes
Affiliation:
Clark University
*
*Corresponding author. E-mail: rtamura@clemson.edu
Get access

Abstract

A general equilibrium model that characterizes the gap between optimal and equilibrium fertility and investment in human capital is developed. The aggregate production function exhibits increasing returns to population arising from specialization, but households face a quantity–quality trade-off when choosing their fertility and how much education these children receive. We show that equilibrium fertility is too low and investment per child is too high, in contrast to a current planner who internalizes the externality of current fertility on the next generation's productivity. We next introduce mortality of young adults in the model and assume that households have a precautionary demand for children. Human capital investment lowers next generation mortality. This model endogenously generates a demographic transition but, since households do not internalize the negative effects of human capital on mortality, the equilibrium demographic transition takes place many years later than the efficient solution. We show that ${\rm {\cal A}}$-efficient fertility and human capital investment pair can switch; in high-mortality regimes, ${\rm {\cal A}}$-efficient fertility is lower than equilibrium fertility, and ${\rm {\cal A}}$-efficient human capital investment is higher than equilibrium investment. In the zero mortality regime, however, ${\rm {\cal A}}$-efficient fertility exceeds equilibrium fertility, and ${\rm {\cal A}}$-efficient human capital investment is lower than the equilibrium choice.

Type
Research Papers
Copyright
Copyright © Université catholique de Louvain 2020

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S. and Robinson, J. (2001) The colonial origins of comparative development: an empirical investigation. American Economic Review 91, 13691401.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, D., Ticchi, D. and Vindigni, A. (2011) Emergence and persistence of inefficient states. Journal of the European Economic Association 9, 177208.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barro, R. J. and Becker, G. S. (1989) Fertility choice in a model of economic growth. Econometrica 57, 481501.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Basso, A. and Cuberes, D. (2017) Deep-rooted determinants of the fertility transition across countries. Macroeconomic Dynamics 21, 17121751.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, G. S. (1960) An economic analysis of fertility. In Demographic and Economic Change in Developed Countries, Conference of the Universities, NBER, pp. 209240. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Becker, G. S. and Barro, R. J. (1988) A reformulation of the economic theory of fertility. Quarterly Journal of Economics 103, 125.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, G. S. and Lewis, H. G. (1973) On the interaction between the quantity and quality of children. Journal of Political Economy 81, S279S288.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boldrin, M. and Jones, L. E. (2002) Mortality, fertility and saving decisions. Review of Economic Dynamics 5, 775814.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boucekkine, R., de la Croix, D. and Licandro, O. (2003) Early mortality declines at the dawn of modern growth. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 105, 401418.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boucekkine, R., de la Croix, D. and Peeters, D. (2007) Early literacy achievements, population density and the transition to modern growth. Journal of the European Economic Association 5, 183226.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boucekkine, R., de la Croix, D. and Peeters, D. (2008) Disentangling the demographic determinants of the English take-off: 1530–1860. In Prskawetz, Alexia, Bloom, David E. & Lutz, Wolfgang (eds.), Population and Development Review Supplement, Population Aging, Human Capital Accumulation, and Productivity Growth, pp. 126148.Google Scholar
Conde-Ruiz, J. I., Giménez, E. L. and Pérez-Nievas, M. (2010) Millian efficiency with endogenous fertility. Review of Economic Studies 77, 154187.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Daalgard, C.-J. and Strulik, H. (2013) The history augmented solow model. European Economic Review 63, 134149.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dasgupta, P. (1969) On the concept of optimal population. Review of Economic Studies 36, 295318.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
de la Croix, D. and Licandro, O. (2013) The child is father of the man—implications for the demographic transition. The Economic Journal 123, 236261.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
de la Croix, D., Lindh, T. and Malmberg, B. (2008) Swedish economic growth and education since 1800. Canadian Journal of Economics 41, 166185.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
de la Croix, D., Lindh, T. and Malmberg, B. (2009) Demographic change and economic growth in Sweden: 1750–2050. Journal of Macroeconomics 31, 132148.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
de la Croix, D. and Ponthière, G. (2012) How powerful is demography? The serendipity theorem revisited. Journal of Population Economics 25, 899922.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Doepke, M. (2005) Child mortality and fertility decline: does the Barro–Becker model fit the facts? Journal of Population Economics 18, 337366.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eckstein, Z. and Wolpin, K. I. (1985) Endogenous fertility and optimal population size. Journal of Public Economics 27, 93106.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fernández-Villaverde, J. (2001) Was Malthus Right? Economic Growth and Population Dynamics. University of Pennsylvania working paper.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Galor, O. (2012) The demographic transition: causes and consequences. Cliometrica 6, 128.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Galor, O. and Moav, O. (2002) Natural selection and the origin of economic growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics 117, 11331191.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Galor, O and Weil, D. N. (1999) From Malthusian stagnation to modern growth. American Economic Review 89, 150154.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Galor, O. and Weil, D. N. (2000) Population, technology, and growth: from Malthusian stagnation to the demographic transition and beyond. American Economic Review 90, 806828.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gigliotti, A. G (1983) Total utility, overlapping generations and optimal population. Review of Economic Studies 50, 7186.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Golosov, M., Jones, L. E. and Tertilt, M. (2007) Efficiency with endogenous population growth. Econometrica 75, 10391071.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jones, C. I. (2001) Was an industrial revolution inevitable? Economic growth over the very long run. The B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics Advances in Macroeconomics 1(2), Article 1, 143.Google Scholar
Kalemli-Ozcan, S. (2002) Does the mortality decline promote economic growth? Journal of Economic Growth 7, 411439.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kalemli-Ozcan, S. (2003) A stochastic model of mortality, fertility and human capital investment. Journal of Development Economics 70(1), 103118.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lagerlöf, N.-P. (2003) From Malthus to modern growth: can epidemics explain the three regimes? International Economic Review 44, 755777.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nerlove, M., Razin, A. and Sadka, E. (1982) Population size and the social welfare functions of Bentham and Mills. Economic Letters 10, 6164.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nerlove, M., Razin, A. and Sadka, E. (1987) Household and economy: welfare economics of endogenous fertility. In Economic Theory, Econometrics and Mathematical Economics Series. Boston: Harcourt, Brace Jovanovich.Google Scholar
Pérez-Nievas, M., Conde-Ruiz, J. I. and Giménez, E. L. (2019) Efficiency and endogenous fertility. Theoretical Economics 14, 475512.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Razin, A. and Ben-Zion, U. (1975) An intergenerational model of population growth. American Economic Review 65, 923933.Google Scholar
Reher, D. S. (2004) The demographic transition revisited as a global process. Population Space and Place 10, 1942.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Romer, P. M. (1986) Increasing returns and long-run growth. Journal of Political Economy 94(5), 10021037.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rosen, S. (1982) The Division of Labor and the Extent of the Market. unpublished University of Chicago manuscript.Google Scholar
Sah, R. K. (1991) The effects of child mortality changes on fertility choice and parental welfare. Journal of Political Economy 99, 582606.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Samuelson, P. A. (1975) The optimum growth rate for population. International Economic Review 16, 531538.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schoonbroodt, A. and Tertilt, M. (2014) Property rights and efficiency in OLG models with endogenous fertility. Journal of Economic Theory 150, 551582.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Spolaore, E. and Wacziarg, R. (2014) Fertility and Modernity. Unpublished manuscript.Google Scholar
Tamura, R. (1991) Income convergence in an endogenous growth model. Journal of Political Economy 99, 522540.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tamura, R. (1992) Efficient equilibrium convergence: heterogeneity and growth. Journal of Economic Theory 58, 355376.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tamura, R. (1996) From decay to growth: a demographic transition to economic growth. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 20, 12371262.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tamura, R. (2002) Human capital and the switch from agriculture to industry. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 27, 207242.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tamura, R. (2006) Human capital and economic development. Journal of Development Economics 79, 2672.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tamura, R., Dwyer, G. P., Devereux, J. and Baier, S. L. (2019) Economic growth in the long Run. Journal of Development Economics 137, 135.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tamura, R. and Simon, C. J. (2017) Secular fertility declines, baby booms and economic growth: international evidence. Macroeconomic Dynamics 21, 16011672.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tamura, R., Simon, C. J. and Murphy, K. M. (2016) Black and white fertility, differential baby booms: the value of equal education opportunity. Journal of Demographic Economics 82, 27109.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Voigtländer, N. and Voth, J. (2012) Persecution perpetuated: the medieval origins of anti-semitic violence in Nazi Germany. Quarterly Journal of Economics 127, 13391392.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Willis, R. J. (1987) Externalities and population. In Johnson, G. & Lee, R. D. (eds.), Population Growth and Economic Development: Issues and Evidence, pp. 661702. Madison: University of Wisconsin Press.Google Scholar
Zimmermann, K. F. (1989) Economic Theory of Optimal Population. Berlin, Heidelberg, New York: Springer-Verlag.CrossRefGoogle Scholar