Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-2lccl Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-25T11:46:02.344Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

QUALITY OF KNOWLEDGE TECHNOLOGY, RETURNS TO PRODUCTION TECHNOLOGY, AND ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  06 April 2004

CUONG LE VAN
Affiliation:
CNRS, CERMSEM, Université de Paris I
H. CAGRI SAGLAM
Affiliation:
IRES, Université Catholique de Louvain

Abstract

We incorporate a production technology that exhibits increasing returns to scale for small values of the capital stock and diminishing returns for the higher stocks at the firm level in a discrete-time version of Romer's endogenous growth model. We study the social planner's problem where the social production technology exhibits globally increasing returns to scale. The properties of the optimal paths are characterized. It is proved that for a given quality of knowledge technology, the countries can take off if their initial stock of capital is above a critical value. We analyze the effect of three factors on the critical value: initial knowledge, quality of knowledge technology, and level of fixed costs associated with production.

Type
ARTICLES
Copyright
© 2004 Cambridge University Press

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Askenazy P. & C. Le Van 1999 A model of optimal growth strategy. Journal of Economic Theory 85, 24 51.Google Scholar
Azariadis C. 1996 The economics of poverty-traps. Part 1: Complete markets. Journal of Economic Growth 1, 449 486.Google Scholar
Becker R.A. & J.H. Boyd III 1997 Capital Theory, Equilibrium Analysis and Recursive Utility. Malden, MA: Blackwell.
Benhabib J. & K. Nishimura 1985 Competitive equilibrium cycles. Journal of Economic Theory 35, 284 306.Google Scholar
Cass D. 1965 Optimal growth in an aggregative model of capital accumulation. Review of Economic Studies 32 233 240.Google Scholar
Clark C.W. 1971 Economically optimal policies for the utilization of biologically renewable resources. Mathematical Biosciences 17, 245 268.Google Scholar
Dechert W.D. & K. Nishimura 1983 A complete characterization of optimal growth paths in an aggregated model with nonconcave production function. Journal of Economic Theory 31, 332 354.Google Scholar
Dimaria C.-H. & C. Le Van 2002 Optimal growth, debt, corruption, and R&D. Macroeconomic Dynamics 6, 597 613.Google Scholar
Koopmans T.C. 1965 On the Concept of Optimal Economic Growth. The Econometric Approach to Development Planning. Amsterdam: North-Holland.
Le Van C., L. Morhaim, & C.-H. Dimaria 2002 The discrete time version of the Romer model. Economic Theory 28, 133 158.Google Scholar
Majumdar M. & T. Mitra 1982 Intertemporal allocation with a nonconvex technology: The aggregative framework. Journal of Economic Theory 27, 101 136.Google Scholar
Ni S. & X. Wang 1996 A model of structural breaks in economic growth. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 7, 223 241.Google Scholar
Ramsey F. 1928 A mathematical theory of saving. Economic Journal 38 543 559.Google Scholar
Romer P. 1986 Increasing returns and long-run growth. Journal of Political Economy 94, 1002 1037.Google Scholar
Skiba A.K. 1978 Optimal growth with a convex-concave production function. Econometrica 46, 527 539.Google Scholar
Topkis D. 1978 Minimizing a submodular function on a lattice. Operations Research 26, 305 321.Google Scholar