Hostname: page-component-7c8c6479df-94d59 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-03-28T16:36:40.127Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

JUSTICE WITHOUT ROMANCE: THE HISTORY OF THE ECONOMIC ANALYSES OF JUDGES’ BEHAVIOR, 1960–1993

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  02 June 2020

Abstract

Richard Posner’s “What Do Judges and Justices Maximize?” (1993b) is not, as usually believed, the first analysis of judges’ behaviors made by using the assumption that judges are rational and maximize a utility function. That analysis arrived at the end of a rather long process. This paper recounts the history of this process, from the “birth” of law and economics in the 1960s to 1993. We show that economic analyses of judges’ behavior were introduced in the early 1970s under the pen of Posner. At that time, rationality was not modeled in terms of utility maximization. Utility maximization came later. We also show that rationality and incentives were introduced to explain the efficiency of common law. Around this theme, a controversy took place that led Posner and other economists to postpone their analysis of judicial behavior until the 1990s. By then, the situation had changed. New and conclusive evidence of judges’ utility maximizing behavior demanded a general theory to be expressed. In addition, the context was favorable to Chicago economists. It was time for Posner to publish his article.

Type
Symposium: Economists in Court
Copyright
© The History of Economics Society 2020

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

Alain Marciano: MRE and University of Montpellier; Alessandro Melcarne, EconomiX – CNRS and University of Paris Nanterre; Giovanni B. Ramello, Università del Piemonte Orientale and IEL International Program on Institutions, Economics and Law. Earlier versions of this paper were presented at the London School of Economics and Political Science History of Postwar Social Science Workshop (London, December 2015), at the annual conference of the Italian Society of Law and Economics (Napoli, December 2015), at the annual conference of the European Association of Law and Economics (Bologna, September 2016), at a GREDEG seminar at the University of Nice Sophia Antipolis (January 2017), and at a workshop on “Economists in Courts” at the Walras-Pareto Center (Lausanne, September 2017). We thank the participants, in particular Jean-Baptiste Fleury, for their comments; and the editors of the journal and the referees for their help. Special thanks to Richard Posner and Paul Rubin for their help. Giovanni Ramello acknowledges the support by the Compagnia di San Paolo. Alain Marciano acknowledges the support of the French National Research Agency (ANR) – research program “Investissements d’avenir,” contract ANR-10-LABX-l l-0l. Alessandro Melcarne acknowledges the support of the French National Research Agency (ANR) – research program JCJC, contract ANR-17-CE26-0010-01.

References

REFERENCES

Becker, Gary S. 1968. “Crime and Punishment: An Economic Approach.” Journal of Political Economy 76 (2): 169217.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, Gary S. 1971. Economic Theory. New York: Alfred Knopf.Google Scholar
Becker, Gary S. 1976. The Economic Approach to Human Behavior. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bertrand, Élodie. 2015. “‘The Fugitive’: The Figure of the Judge in Coase’s Economics.” Journal of Institutional Economics 11 (2): 413435.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bonner, John T. 1975. “Review of ‘Sociobiology: The New Synthesis.’” Scientific American 233 (October): 129137.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buchanan, James M. [1979] 1984. “Politics without Romance: A Sketch of Positive Public Choice Theory and Its Normative Implications.” Inaugural lecture, Institute for Advanced Studies, Vienna, Austria. Zeitschrift des Instituts für Höhere Studien 3: B1B11. Reprinted in , James M. Buchanan and Tollison, Robert D., eds., The Theory of Public Choice—II. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press, pp. 1122.Google Scholar
Buchanan, James M. 1986. “The Constitution of Economic Policy.” Prize Lecture to the Memory of Alfred Nobel, December 8.Google Scholar
Calabresi, Guido. 1961. “Some Thoughts on Risk Distribution and the Law of Torts.” Yale Law Journal 70 (4): 499553.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coase, Ronald H. 1960. “The Problem of Social Cost.” Journal of Law and Economics 3 (October): 144.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coase, Ronald H. 1978. “Economics and Contiguous Discipline.” Journal of Legal Studies 7 (2): 201211.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coase, Ronald H. 1988. ‘‘The Nature of the Firm: Influence.’Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 4 (1): 3347.Google Scholar
Coase, Ronald H. 1993. “Law and Economics at Chicago.” Journal of Law and Economics 36 (1): Part 2: 239254.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coase, Ronald H. 1996. “Law and Economics and A. W. Brian Simpson.” Journal of Legal Studies 25 (1): 103119.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coase, Ronald H. 1998. ‘‘The New Institutional Economics.’American Economic Review 88 (May): 7274.Google Scholar
Coase, Ronald H. 2012. Saving Economics from the Economists. http://hbr.org/2012/12/saving-economics-from-the-economists. Accessed January 21, 2020.Google Scholar
Coase, Ronald H., and Wang, Ning. 2013. “A New Journal from the Ronald Coase Institute.” https://thinkmarkets.wordpress.com/2013/07/24/a-new-journal-from-the-ronald-coase-institute. Accessed January 21, 2020.Google Scholar
Cohen, Mark A. 1991. “Explaining Judicial Behavior or What’s ‘Unconstituitional’ about the Sentencing Commission?Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 7 (1): 183199.Google Scholar
Cooter, Robert D. 1983. “The Objectives of Private and Public Judges.” Public Choice 41 (1): 107132.Google Scholar
Cooter, Robert, and Kornhauser, Lewis. 1980. “Can Litigation Improve the Law without the Help of Judges?Journal of Legal Studies 9 (1): 139163.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Demsetz, Harold. 1964. “The Exchange and Enforcement of Property Rights.” Journal of Law and Economics 7 (Oct.): 1126.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Domnarski, William. 2016. Richard Posner. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Downs, Anthony. 1957. An Economic Theory of Democracy. New York: Harper & Row.Google Scholar
Downs, Anthony, Landes, William M., Rottenberg, Simon, and Hoffman, Richard B.. 1969. “Round Table on Allocation of Resources in Law Enforcement.” American Economic Review 59 (2): 504512.Google Scholar
Ehrlich, Isaac. 1972. “The Deterrent Effect of Criminal Law Enforcement.” Journal of Legal Studies 1 (2): 259276.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ehrlich, Isaac. 1973. “Participation in Illegitimate Activities: A Theoretical and Empirical Investigation.” Journal of Political Economy 81 (3): 521565.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Epstein, Richard A. 1990. “Independence of Judges: The Uses and Limitations of Public Choice Theory.” Bringham Young University Law Review: 827850.Google Scholar
Fleury, Jean-Baptiste. 2015. “Massive Influence with Scarce Contributions: The Rationalizing Economist Gary S. Becker, 1930–2014.” European Journal of Law and Economics 39 (1): 39.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fleury, Jean-Baptiste. 2019a. “Becker, Gary S.” In Marciano, A. and Ramello, G. B., eds., Encyclopedia of Law and Economics. New York: Springer. https://link.springer.com/referenceworkentry/10.1007%2F978-1-4614-7753-2_97. Accessed February 11, 2020.Google Scholar
Fleury, Jean-Baptiste. 2019b. “Crime and Punishment (Becker 1968).” In Marciano, A. and Ramello, G. B., eds., Encyclopedia of Law and Economics. New York: Springer. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4614-7753-2_17. Accessed February 11, 2020.Google Scholar
Ghiselin, Michael T. 1974. The Economy of Nature and the Evolution of Sex. Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Goodman, John C. 1978. “An Economic Theory of the Evolution of Common Law.” Journal of Legal Studies 7 (2): 393406.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gordon, Wendy, Marciano, Alain, and Rambello, Giovanni B.. 2019. “The Future of Law and Economics and the Legacy of Guido Calabresi.” European Journal of Law and Economics 48: 18.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harnay, Sophie, and Marciano, Alain. 2009. “Posner, Economics and the Law: From Law and Economics to an Economic Analysis of Law.” Journal of the History of Economic Thought 31 (2): 215232.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Higgins, Richard S., and Rubin, Paul H.. 1980. “Judicial Discretion.” Journal of Legal Studies 9 (1): 129138.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hovenkamp, Herbert. 1990. “The First Great Law and Economics Movement.” Stanford Law Review 42 (4): 9931058.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kau, James B., and Rubin, Paul H.. 1979. “Self-Interest, Ideology, and Logrolling in Congressional Voting.” Journal of Law and Economics 22 (2): 365374.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Landes, William M. 1967. “The Effect of State Fair Employment Laws on the Economic Position of Nonwhites.” American Economic Review 57 (2): 578590.Google Scholar
Landes, William M. 1968. “The Economics of Fair Employment Law.” Journal of Political Economy 76 (4): 507552.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Landes, William M. 1971. “An Economic Analysis of the Courts.” Journal of Law and Economics 14 (1): 61107.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Landes, William M., and Posner, Richard A.. 1975. “The Independent Judiciary in an Interest-Group Perspective.” NBER Working Paper No. 110 (October).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Landes, William M., and Posner, Richard A.. 1979. “Adjudication as a Private Good.” Journal of Legal Studies 8 (2): 235284.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Landes, William M., and Posner, Richard A.. 1980. “Legal Change, Judicial Behavior and the Diversity Jurisdiction.” Journal of Legal Studies 9 (2): 367386.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marciano, Alain. 2012. “Guido Calabresi’s Economic Analysis of Law, Coase and the Coase Theorem.” International Review of Law and Economics 32 (1): 110118.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marciano, Alain. 2016. “Economic Analysis of Law.” In Marciano, A. and Ramello, G. B., eds., Encyclopedia of Law and Economics. New York: Springer. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4614-7883-6_598-1. Accessed January 21, 2020.Google Scholar
Marciano, Alain, and Medema, Steven G.. 2020. “Disciplinary Collisions: Blum, Kalven, and the Economic Analysis of Accident Law at Chicago in the 1960s.” In Malecka, Magdałena and Cserne, Peter, eds., Law and Economics as Interdisciplinary Practice. New York: Routledge, pp. 5375.Google Scholar
Marciano, Alain, and Ramello, Giovanni. 2014. “Consent, Choice and Guido Calabresi’s Heterodox Economic Analysis of Law.” Law and Contemporary Problems 77 (2): 97112.Google Scholar
Marciano, Alain, and Ramello, Giovanni. 2018. “Cesare Beccaria: Back to the Future of Law and Economics.” Special issue, European Journal of Law and Economics 46 (3).Google Scholar
Marciano, Alain, and Romaniuc, Rustam. 2015. “Accident Costs, Resource Allocation and Individual Rationality: Blum, Kalven and Calabresi.” The European Journal of the History of Economic Thought 22 (6): 10841114.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Medema, Steven G. 1998. “Wandering the Road from Pluralism to Posner: The Transformation of Law and Economics, 1920s–1970s.” In “The Transformation of American Economics: From Interwar Pluralism to Postwar Neoclassicism,” annual supplement, History of Political Economy 30: 202224.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Niskanen, William N. 1968. “The Peculiar Economics of Bureaucracy.” In “Papers and Proceedings of the Eightieth Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association,” American Economic Review 58 (2): 293305.Google Scholar
Posner, Richard A. 1971a. “Taxation by Regulation.” Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 2 (1): 2250.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Posner, Richard A. 1971b. “Killing or Wounding to Protect a Property Interest.” Journal of Law and Economics 14 (1): 201232.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Posner, Richard A. 1972a. “A Theory of Negligence.” Journal of Legal Studies 1 (1): 2996.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Posner, Richard A. 1972b. “The Behavior of Administrative Agencies.” Journal of Legal Studies 1 (2): 305347.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Posner, Richard A. 1972c. “Volume One of ‘The Journal of Legal Studies’: An Afterword.” Journal of Legal Studies 1 (2): 437440.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Posner, Richard A. 1973a. Economic Analysis of Law. Boston and Toronto: Little, Brown and Company.Google Scholar
Posner, Richard A. 1973b. “An Economic Approach to Legal Procedure and Judicial Administration.” Journal of Legal Studies 2 (2): 399458.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Posner, Richard A. 1975. “The Economic Approach to Law.” Texas Law Review 53 (XX): 757782.Google Scholar
Posner, Richard A. 1987. “The Law and Economics Movement.” In “Papers and Proceedings of the Ninety-Ninth Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association,” American Economic Review 77 (2): 113.Google Scholar
Posner, Richard A. 1988. “Comment on Donohue.” Law & Society Review 22 (5): 927930.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Posner, Richard A. 1993a. “Gary Becker’s Contributions to Law and Economics.” Journal of Legal Studies 22 (2): 211215.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Posner, Richard A. 1993b. “What Do Judges and Justices Maximize? (The Same Thing Everyone Else Does).” Supreme Court Economic Review 3: 141.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Posner, Richard A. 1993c. “Nobel Laureate: Ronald Coase and Methodology.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 7 (4): 195210.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Priest, George L. 1977. “The Common Law Process and the Selection of Efficient Rules.” Journal of Legal Studies 6 (1): 6582.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Priest, George L. 1980. “Selective Characteristics of Litigation.” In “Change in the Common Law: Legal and Economic Perspectives,” Journal of Legal Studies 9 (2): 399421.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ramello, Giovanni B. 2016. “The Past, Present, and Future of Comparative Law and Economics.” In Eisenberg, Theodore and Ramello, Giovanni B., eds., Comparative Law and Economics. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing.Google Scholar
Rottenberg, Simon. 1965. “Liability in Law and Economics.” American Economic Review 55 (1/2): 107114.Google Scholar
Rubin, Paul H. 1973. “The Economic Theory of the Criminal Firm.” In Rottenberg, Simon, ed., The Economics of Crime and Punishment. Washington, DC: American Enterprise Institute, pp. 155166.Google Scholar
Rubin, Paul H. 1977. “Why Is the Common Law Efficient?Journal of Legal Studies 6 (1): 5163.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rubin, Paul H. 1980. “Predictability and the Economic Approach to Law: A Comment on Rizzo.” In “Change in the Common Law: Legal and Economic Perspectives,” Journal of Legal Studies 9 (2): 319334.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rubin, Paul H. 1982. “Common Law and Statute Law.” Journal of Legal Studies 11 (2): 205223.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rubin, Paul HPaul, Rubin, H. 1983. “The Objectives of Private and Public Judges: A Comment.” Public Choice 41 (1): 133137.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rubin, Paul H. 1999. “Judge Made Law.” In Bouckaert, B. and de Geest, G., eds., Encyclopedia in Law and Economics. Cheltenham: Elgar, pp. 543558.Google Scholar
Schauer, Frederick. 2000. “Incentives, Reputation, and the Inglorious Determinants of Judicial Behavior.” University of Cincinnati Law Review 68 (3): 615636.Google Scholar
Stigler, George J. 1992. “Law or Economics?Journal of Law & Economics 35 (2): 455468.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Terrebonne, R. Peter. 1981. “A Strictly Evolutionary Model of Common Law.” Journal of Legal Studies 10 (2): 397407.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tullock, Gordon. 1965. The Politics of Bureaucracy. Washington, DC: Public Affairs Press.Google Scholar
Wilson, Edmund O. 1975. Sociobiology: The New Synthesis. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar