Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-pftt2 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-05-21T01:46:05.227Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

An economic guide to ticket pricing in the entertainment industry

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  17 August 2016

Pascal Courty*
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, London Business School
Get access

Summary

This paper reviews the literature on ticket pricing in the entertainment industry. All along, I try to evaluate whether ticket markets outcomes are consistent with theoretical predictions. Overall, the literature provides a good understanding for observed variations in ticket prices. The literature, however, fails to explain situations where prices do not vary. We have but a poor understanding for why prices often do not vary over the run of a show, why more popular shows do not charge more and why most venues are scaled in just a few sections. I also review the empirical literature of price discrimination in ticket markets. By contrasting the theoretical and the empirical literatures, the paper identifies a set of promising directions for future research.

Résumé

Résumé

Mon article étudie la littérature portant sur le prix des billets dans le secteur des spectacles. Son objectif est de voir si les prédictions théoriques sont confirmées empiriquement. Dans l’ensemble, la littérature théorique fournit une bonne explication des différences de prix. Par contre, elle échoue à expliquer certaines situations d’absence de variations des prix. En particulier, les faits suivants restent peu compris : que les prix ne changent pas durant le cycle de vie des spectacles, qu’ils n’augmentent pas en cas de succès et qu’il y ait si peu de types de prix différents pour un même spectacle. J’examine également la littérature en matière de discrimination des prix dans le secteur des spectacles. Finalement, quelques pistes de recherches prometteuses sont suggérées.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Université catholique de Louvain, Institut de recherches économiques et sociales 2000 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

*

I would like to thank Gurdeep Stephens, Victor Ginsburgh and two anonymous referees. All errors are my responsibility.

References

Andrews, Paul (1993). “Paul Allen’s Ticket to Future”. The Seattle Times Company (November 23).Google Scholar
Adams, James, and Yellen, Janet (1976). “Commodity Bundling and the Burden of Monopoly.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 90 : 475–98.Google Scholar
Becker, Gary (1991). “A Note on Restaurant Pricing and Other Examples of Social Influences on Price.” Journal of Political Economy 99 (5) : 11091116.Google Scholar
Boiteux, M (1996). “La Tarification des Demandes en Point : Application de la Theorie de la Vente au Cout Marginal.” Revue Generale d’Electricite (August 1949) : 321–40. Translated as “Peak Load Pricing.” Journal of Business 33 (2) : 157–70.Google Scholar
Borenstein, Severin and Rose, Nancy (1994). “Competition and Price Dispersion in the U.S. Airline Industry.” Journal of Political Economy 102 (4) : 653683.Google Scholar
Cheung, Steven (1977). “Why are Better Seats “Underpriced”? Economic Inquiry 15, : 513522.Google Scholar
Cheung, Steven (1980). “Rose Bowl vs. Hong Kong : The Economics of Seat Pricing.” In Economics of Nonproprietary Organizations. Research in Law and Economics, Supplement 1: 2749. JAI Press.Google Scholar
Coase, Ronald (1972). “Durability and Monopoly.” Journal of Law and Economics 15 : 143–49.Google Scholar
Courty, Pascal (1996). “The Economics of TicketsUniversity of Chicago Dissertation.Google Scholar
Courty, Pascal (1999). “Some Economics of Tickets.” Mimeo, London Business School. http://www.lbs.ac.uk/faculty/pcourty/mypubfiles/wkpp.htm Google Scholar
Courty, Pascal and Hao, Li (2000). “Sequential Screening.” Forthcoming Review of Economic Studies.Google Scholar
Crew, Michael, Chitru Frenando and Paul Kleindorfer (1995). “The Theory of Peal-Load Pricing : A Survey.” Journal of Regulatory Economics 8 : 215248.Google Scholar
Dana, James (1998). “Advanced Purchase Discounts and Price Discrimination in Competitive Markets.” Journal of Political Economy 19 (6) : 495–422.Google Scholar
DeGraba, Patrick (1995). “Buying Frenzies and Seller-Induced Excess Demand.” RAND Journal of Economics. Vol. 26, No 2 : 331–42.Google Scholar
DeSerpa, Allan (1994). “To Err Is Rational : A Theory of Excess Demand for Tickets.” Managerial and Decision Economics 15(5), (September-October) : 511–18.Google Scholar
Diamond, Thomas A (1982). “Ticket Scalping : A New Look at an Old Problem.” University of Miami Law Review 37 : 7192.Google Scholar
Dupuit, Jules (1952). “On the Measurement of the Utility of Public Works.” Translated into English by Barbak, R.H. in International Economic Papers No.2 London and New York : Macmillan. (Originally published in 1844.)Google Scholar
Giblin, Paul and Chadwell, Teena (1994). “Rock Concert Costs Boom for Boomers : Eagles Take it to the Limit on Ticket Price.” Business Journal-Phoenix 14 (32), (June 10).Google Scholar
Happel, S. and Jennings, M. (1989). “Assessing the Economic Rational and Legal Remedies for Ticket Scalping.” Journal of Legislation 16(1) : 114.Google Scholar
Happel, S. and Jennings, M. (1995). “The Folly of Anti-Scalping Laws.” Cato Journal 15(1) :6580.Google Scholar
Happel, S. and Jennings, M. (1995). “Herd them together and Scalp them.” The Wall Street Journal (February 23) : Section A p. 14 column 4.Google Scholar
Hobbs, Bill (1994). “Battle Between Scalpers, Concert Industry Never Over.” Amusement Business 106 (36), (September 5).Google Scholar
Honan, William (1991). “Anti-Scalping Law : Mixed Impact LikelyThe New York Times. (August 8) : Section C, p. 13.Google Scholar
Huntington, Paul (1993). “Ticket Pricing Policy and Box Office Revenue.” Journal of Cultural Economics 17(1) : 7187.Google Scholar
Landsburgh, Steve (1993). “Why Popcorn Costs More at the Movies and why the Obvious Answer is Wrong.” In The Armchair Economist : Economics and Everyday Life Maxwell Macmillan : 157167.Google Scholar
Lèvy-Garboua, Louis and Montmarquette, Claude (1996). “A Microeconometric Study of Theater Demand.” Journal of Cultural Economics 20 (1) : 2550.Google Scholar
Leslie, Phillip (1998). “A Structural Econometric Analysis of Price Discrimination in Broadway Theater.” Mimeo, Yale University.Google Scholar
Locay, Luis and Rodriguez, Alvaro (1993). “Price Discrimination in Competitive Markets.” Journal of Political Economy 10 : 954–66.Google Scholar
Lott, John and Roberts, Russell (1991). “A Guide to the Pitfalls of Identifying Price Discrimination.” Economic Inquiry 29(1) : 1423.Google Scholar
McAfee, Preston, McMillan, John and Whinston, Michael (1989). “Multi-product Monopoly, Commodity Bundling, and Correlation of Values.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 103 : 371383.Google Scholar
Marburger, Daniel (1997). “Optimal Ticket Pricing for Performance Goods.” Managerial and Decision Economics 18(5), (August) : 375–81.Google Scholar
McCain, Roger (1987). “Optimal Contingent Pricing of Performance in the Arts and Sports.” Journal of Cultural Economics 11(1), (June) : 121.Google Scholar
Mussa, Michael and Rosen, Sherwin (1978). “Monopoly and Product Quality.” Journal of Economic Theory 18 : 301317.Google Scholar
Mohl, Bruce (1992). “Rising Ticket Fees Pad Concert Profits.” The Boston Globe. (September 10.)Google Scholar
Oi, Walter (1971). “A Disneyland Dilemma : Two-Part Tariffs for a Mickey Mouse Monopoly.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 85 : 7796.Google Scholar
Philips, Chuck (1990). “Why Does a $30 Ticket Becomes a $600 Ticket?Los Angeles Times Calendar, (May 27) : 8.Google Scholar
Powel, Ton (1990). “Negotiating Deals : How Far Should Promoters, Venues. Tix cos. Bend?Amusement Business 102 (38), (September 24).Google Scholar
Putsis, William and Sen, Subrata (1999, Forhtcoming). “Should NFL Blackouts be Banned ?Applied Economics.Google Scholar
Rochet, Jean-Charles and Chone, Philippe (1998). “Ironing, Sweeping and Multidimeintional Screening.” Econometrica 66 (8).Google Scholar
Rosen, Sherwin (1974). “Hedonic Prices and Implicit Markets : Product Differentiation in Pure Competition.” Journal of Political Economy 82 (1) :3555.Google Scholar
Rosen, Sherwin and Rosenfield, Andrew (1997). “Ticket Pricing.” Journal of Law and Economics 40(2) : 351–76.Google Scholar
Spence, Michael (1975). “Monopoly, Quality and Regulation.” Bell Journal of Economics (6) : 417–4xx.Google Scholar
Steiner, Faye (1997). “Optimal Pricing of Museum Admission.’ Journal of Cultural Economics 21(4) : 307333.Google Scholar
Tirole, Jean (1988). The Theory of Industrial Organization. Cambridge. Mass. : The MIT Press.Google Scholar
Thiel, Stuart (1993). “Two Cheers for ToutsScottish Journal of Political Economy. 40(4), (November) : 447–55.Google Scholar
Throsby, David (1994). “The Production and Consumption of the Arts: A View of Cultural EconomicsJournal of Economic Literature. 32. (March) : 129.Google Scholar
Walras, L (1980). “The State of the Railways.” (1875) Translated into English by Holmes, P. in Journal of Public Economics. 13 : S1–100.Google Scholar
Weatherford, Lawrence and Bodily, Samuel (1992). “A Taxonomy and Research Overview of Perishable-Asset Revenue Management : Yield Management, Overbooking, and Pricing.” Operational Research 831–44.Google Scholar
Weber, Bruce (1994). “The Broadway Ticket Game : Bargain-Hunters Can Play.” The New York Time. (March 18) Section C.Google Scholar
Welki, Andrew and Zlatoper, Thomas (1994). “U.S. Professional Football: The Demand for Game-Day Attendance in 1991.” Managerial and Decision Economics. 15(5), (September-October) :489–95.Google Scholar
Williams, Andrew (1994). “Do Anti-Ticket Scalping Laws Make a Difference?Managerial and Decision Economics 15(5) (September-October) : 503–09.Google Scholar