Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-xtgtn Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-18T08:17:28.190Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Relative Gains in the Shadow of a Trade War

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  04 March 2022

Abstract

When do people care about relative gains in trade? Much of the international relations scholarship—and much of the political rhetoric on trade—would lead us to expect support for a trade policy that benefits ourselves more than it benefits others. Yet, a large interdisciplinary literature also points to the prevalence and importance of other-regarding preferences, rendering the conventional wisdom contestable. We investigate whether and how relative gains influence trade preferences through an original survey experiment in the midst of the China–US trade war. We find that in a win-win scenario, relative gains shape trade opinion: if both sides are gaining, people want to gain more than their foreign trade partner. However, these considerations are offset in a win-lose scenario where the other side is losing out. Relative-gains considerations causally affect opinion on trade, but not in a “beggar-thy-neighbor” or even a “beggar-thy-rival” situation. These findings contribute to our understanding of the role of relative gains in international relations and provide the first experimental evidence that relative-gains considerations can be offset by other-regarding preferences in international trade.

Type
Research Note
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2022. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of The IO Foundation

I will use tariffs when they are needed, but the difference between me and Trump is that I will have a strategy—a plan—to use those tariffs to win.

—Joe Biden, May 2020Footnote 1

Relative-gains considerations often feature in the political rhetoric on trade.Footnote 2 The raison d’être of international trade lies in generating mutual benefits for all trading countries, but both politicians and the public seem to have become increasingly concerned about winning against their trade partner, instead of focusing on their own absolute gains from trade.Footnote 3 Relative-gains considerations also underlie the recent trade war between China and the US, as seen in how politicians such as Donald Trump framed the issue, using the rhetoric of “win” or “lose” to emphasize how the US is performing relative to China.Footnote 4 While mutual gains lie at the heart of international trade, relative gains have become prominent in the politics of trade.

Despite the prevalence of relative-gains considerations in the political rhetoric, few studies have explored whether and how such considerations influence trade preferences. On the one hand, while the conventional wisdom in international political economy suggests that trade preferences are predominantly guided by economic self-interest, a growing body of research now shows that sociotropic preferences can also affect opinion on trade.Footnote 5 On the other hand, while the issue of relative gains has long been discussed by international relations (IR) scholars, few have connected it directly with the study of domestic trade preferences.

We investigate how relative gains influence trade preferences through an original survey experiment in the midst of the China–US trade war. We find that in a win-win scenario, relative gains shape trade opinion: if both sides are gaining, people want to gain more than their foreign trade partner. However, these considerations are offset in a win-lose scenario where the other side is losing out—whether the other side is China in particular, or an unnamed trade partner in general. Relative-gains considerations can shape trade preferences, but they can also be countervailed by other-regarding concerns if the trade policy involves a win-lose scenario. Additional analyses of the open-ended responses reinforce our conclusions.

Our study is the first to experimentally investigate how relative gains and other- regarding preferences interact in trade. We argue that it is necessary to study them jointly, rather than in isolation from one another, to better understand the role of relative gains in trade opinion. Our study thus extends previous research that found other-regarding concerns operating toward domestic others,Footnote 6 as well as the latest experimental work that found concerns over fairness shaping trade preferences.Footnote 7 By studying not only win-win but also win-lose settings, we show that while relative gains influence attitudes toward trade, other-regarding considerations—specifically concerns over losses in a trade partner—also shape trade preferences and can offset relative-gains considerations. Finally, by showing that beliefs about relative gains at the societal level can influence personal sentiments on trade, our findings provide additional support for the idea that trade preferences are also guided by sociotropic motivations.Footnote 8

Trade Preferences and Relative Gains

Conventional wisdom in international political economy suggests that individual trade preferences are predominantly guided by economic self-interest. The Heckscher–Ohlin model shows that free trade would increase (or decrease) the real earnings of owners of factors of production that are abundant (or scarce) relative to foreign countries.Footnote 9 The model predicts that trade preferences are shaped by individual factor endowments, and several studies have provided evidence for it.Footnote 10 The Ricardo–Viner model, on the other hand, predicts that people in export-oriented (or import-oriented) sectors will support (or oppose) free trade.Footnote 11 Studies providing empirical support include Beaulieu, Irwin, and Kaempfer and Marks,Footnote 12 and the model has also received joint support along with the Heckscher–Ohlin model.Footnote 13 At the same time, however, a sizable body of research also suggests trade preferences are not merely guided by the individual's direct material self-interest.Footnote 14

In particular, mainstream neorealist scholarship would predict that trade preferences are affected by relative-gains considerations. This is because “the general insecurity of international anarchy leads states to worry not simply about how well they fare themselves (absolute gains) but about how well they fare compared to other states (relative gains).”Footnote 15 As the relative power and influence of a country depend on relative gains rather than absolute gains, “relative gain is more important than absolute gain.”Footnote 16 Given states’ pursuit of relative gains, international cooperation can become a zero-sum, or near-zero-sum, game.Footnote 17

Relative-gains considerations mean that “states compare their absolute outcome to the absolute outcomes of other states.”Footnote 18 It follows that a win-win trade policy where domestic gains outweigh the trade partner's gains would be preferred to a win-win policy where foreign gains outweigh domestic gains. It also follows that a win-lose trade policy, where domestic gains are derived at the expense of the trade partner, would be even better from the relative-gains perspective, even if the domestic absolute gains remain the same.Footnote 19 Such relative-gains calculations can impede international cooperation, as several models have shown.Footnote 20

Yet, relative gains do not always impede international trade.Footnote 21 For example, relative-gains concerns in the economic realm can be less salient than those in the security realm.Footnote 22 A state may also favor a policy where foreign gains outweigh domestic gains if the absolute gains it derives from the policy would create relative gains vis-à-vis other foreign states.Footnote 23 Even if states have a natural tendency to compete, international economic cooperation may still be in their strategic interests.Footnote 24 However, if a trade policy is likely to affect the future interactions between home and foreign states, relative-gains concerns will kick in.Footnote 25 In particular, if people believe that relative economic advantages can be translated into relative military advantages, or that the trade partner is a potential security threat, then relative gains in trade are likely to be important.Footnote 26 Theorizing relative gains as security externalities, Gowa and Mansfield found that free trade took place more frequently within, but not across, military alliances, suggesting that states take relative gains into consideration on the issue of trade.Footnote 27 Mastanduno argued that America's shift to a more protectionist trade policy in the late 1980s showed “clear signs of relative gains-seeking behavior … in the US policy process.”Footnote 28

Relative-gains concerns can affect trade preferences at the individual level through sociotropic considerations. A large body of research has established the importance of sociotropic motivations in policy preferences. Early work by Kinder and Kiewiet found a sociotropic voting pattern in American politics, where voters tend to focus on collective-level instead of individual-level information.Footnote 29 Sociotropic influence is highly relevant to how political perceptions form and may even outweigh egotropic considerations.Footnote 30 Mansfield and Mutz found that trade preferences depended on how people perceived the economic impact of international trade on the US as a whole, and that in-group favoritism could affect opinion on trade.Footnote 31 Relative-gains considerations operate here insofar as people would prefer a trade policy that brings greater gains to the domestic in-group relative to the foreign out-group.

Previous work has focused on the role of relative gains under a win-win trade policy. But what happens when a trade policy involves a win-lose scenario? The underlying expectation in the literature is that the same logic of relative gains would apply: individuals would support a win-lose trade policy as long as their country is on the winning side. We argue, however, that a win-lose trade policy would be characterized not only by its relative-gains implications but also by its other-regarding ramifications. The two are not mutually exclusive. When a win-lose trade policy is implemented, both relative-gains and other-regarding concerns can be triggered. Relative-gains considerations may be mitigated by the other-regarding concerns that characterize human behavior in general.

That human beings have other-regarding social preferences is one of the most widely documented facts in social science.Footnote 32 In economics, many laboratory experiments have found individuals deviating from the “rationality” predicted by standard game-theoretic models in response to social preferences. Examples include how human players respond to the ultimatum game,Footnote 33 the dictator game,Footnote 34 and the trust game.Footnote 35 Economists have formalized the ideas of altruism and inequity aversion,Footnote 36 and found experimental evidence for such behavior.Footnote 37 Recent research has also found neural evidence for altruistic and inequity-averse preferences in human beings.Footnote 38

Such other-regarding motivations can influence economic decisions and policy preferences.Footnote 39 Examining anthropological, experimental, and survey evidence, Fong, Bowles, and Gintis suggested that reciprocity motives often play an important role in shaping public opinion on redistribution.Footnote 40 Relatedly, in Johnson and colleagues’ experiments, people displayed a high willingness to punish free riders in public goods games.Footnote 41 On trade issues in particular, Funk found from the American National Election Studies data that societal motivations could be important in determining policy attitudes.Footnote 42 Lü, Scheve, and Slaughter found that people were more supportive of protecting a domestic industry when their monthly income was higher than the monthly income the average worker in that industry earns.Footnote 43 While this study does not consider relative gains in the IR sense or touch on the welfare consequences for foreign states, it demonstrates the role of inequity aversion in public support for protectionism.

We believe that such social preferences can also extend to foreign citizens: people want themselves and their national in-group to do well, but they also do not want to see themselves doing well at the direct expense of others. Research has shown that people have a strong psychological need for a positive self-image, and that other-regarding motivations in human beings can also extend toward out-group members.Footnote 44 Recent work has also suggested the prevalence and importance of social preferences in IR.Footnote 45 Building on prior work, we argue that other-regarding considerations can interact with relative-gains concerns in individual trade preferences. Consider a trade policy that benefits the domestic economy at the expense of a foreign economy. If relative-gains considerations are strong while social preferences are weak, then domestic citizens are likely to support this policy. Yet if social preferences are strong while the relative-gains considerations are weak, domestic citizens may oppose it. In this way, the relevance of relative gains in shaping public opinion toward trade is conditional on the existence and salience of other-regarding preferences.

Past Experimental Approaches

Three previous experiments have touched on the relationship between trade preferences and relative gains. Rousseau conducted an experiment with undergraduates at four US universities, and separately with the general public of Virginia, that asked: “Would you support or oppose an international trade agreement that results in small economic gains by the United States but major economic gains by [Russia / China / Japan / Canada]?”Footnote 46 The trade partner was the experimental treatment, with one country randomly assigned to each respondent. Respondents were more likely to support the agreement when the trade partner was Russia or Canada than when it was China or Japan.

Manipulating not only the trade partner but also the distribution of gains in a factorial experiment, Herrmann, Tetlock, and Diascro tested whether American citizens behaved like “intuitive neorealists” in trade.Footnote 47 They produced twelve sets of hypothetical scenarios that varied the relative gains to the US; the identity of the trade partner (ally or enemy); and the affluence of the trade partner (rich or poor). The results indicated that a sizable proportion of the respondents thought along intuitive neorealist lines: they were most supportive of trade restrictions when the US suffered a relative loss vis-à-vis a wealthy trade partner that was also an enemy.

More recently, Mutz and Kim ran a survey experiment on a US national sample to study the impact of in-group favoritism on trade preferences.Footnote 48 By manipulating the job gains or losses for the trade partner while holding constant the job gains for the US, they evaluated whether benefiting the trade partner would affect people's support for the proposed trade policy. For the full sample, support for the trade policy was not influenced by the manipulation: respondents supported the policy as long as it benefited US jobs. However, respondents with a stronger “social dominance orientation” or with zero-sum perceptions of trade's impact on employment, who tend to be Republicans, were more opposed to the win-win trade policy that also benefited the trade partner.

Our study differs from previous studies in three ways. First, we focus on directly and experimentally manipulating the relative gains for the US vis-à-vis its trade partner. Rousseau's experiment studied the effect of the identity of the trade partner, rather than the effect of relative gains. Herrmann, Tetlock, and Diascro's experiment studied the prevalence of neorealist thinking in trade by jointly studying the distribution of gains and the political-economic status of the trade partner. Mutz and Kim's experiment, which manipulated the job gains or losses for the trade partner, did not directly test the effect of relative gains since the job-losses treatment not only introduced gains to the US but also involved inflicting harm on the trade partner, which generated other-regarding concerns in the same experiment. It is possible that no significant effect was found from the manipulation because the relative-gains and other-regarding considerations countervailed one another (see earlier discussion). We avoid this complication by designing a relative-gains treatment in which both the US and its trade partner gain, except that one gains more relative to the other. Thus our study provides a direct test of the effect of relative gains and differs fundamentally from Mutz and Kim's study, which focuses on in-group favoritism.

Second, we also investigate how other-regarding preferences in trade may offset relative-gains considerations. We do so by experimentally manipulating the magnitude of the losses caused to the trade partner across two different win-lose policy scenarios. This differs from Mutz and Kim's study, which did not compare two win-lose scenarios or examine the role of other-regarding preferences in trade. It also differs from Herrmann, Tetlock, and Diascro's study, which did not incorporate a win-lose setting or study how other-regarding preferences interact with relative-gains concerns in trade.

Finally, we differ from Mutz and Kim in how we manipulate respondents’ per- ceptions of the gains or losses from trade. Instead of using job gains or losses as our experimental manipulation, we directly inform our respondents of the winners and losers from trade. We avoid using job gains or losses because the international political economy literature has shown that individuals are particularly sensitive to job losses in economic issues,Footnote 49 and that the mere introduction of issue framing with job losses can shift public opinion on trade by a large margin.Footnote 50 Our design allows respondents to focus squarely on the relative gains or losses from trade without the additional salience of job losses.

Experimental Design

We conducted a national survey in the US in August 2018 using Amazon Mechanical Turk (n = 1,733).Footnote 51 Respondents were randomly assigned to one of eight experimental groups, which were shown different vignettes. Appendices A and B (in the online supplement) show the experimental instrument and the covariate balance across the groups.

We conducted a series of robustness checks that controlled for different sets of demographic and attitudinal variables in ordered probit regressions (see Tables A1–A4). Like Rho and Tomz,Footnote 52 we also replicated our findings after reweighting the survey data to match the population benchmarks in age, gender, education, and party identification (see Appendix G). Our main conclusions remained unchanged across these robustness checks.

Our experiment begins with a scenario where the US proposes to [remove / impose] import limits on [China / Country X]. Figure 1 summarizes our experimental design.

Figure 1. Design of study

Respondents in the “remove” scenario were told that the removal of the import limits would increase both American citizens’ welfare and [Chinese / Country X's] citizens’ welfare—a win-win trade policy. Half of these respondents were subsequently given an additional vignette saying that the gains enjoyed by [Chinese / Country X's] citizens would be significantly greater than the gains enjoyed by American citizens; the others were not given the additional vignette. This additional vignette imputes relative gains to the foreign country. If relative gains affect trade preferences, we should expect respondents to be less supportive of removing import limits on [China / Country X] when given the additional vignette. This provides a direct test of the effect of relative gains on trade opinion.

Respondents in the “impose” scenario were told that the imposition of the import limits would increase American citizens’ welfare and decrease [Chinese / Country X's] citizens’ welfare—a win-lose trade policy. A randomized subset of respondents were subsequently given an additional vignette saying that the losses suffered by [Chinese / Country X's] citizens would be significantly greater than the gains enjoyed by American citizens; the others were not given the additional vignette. This additional vignette implies even greater relative gains for the US under a win-lose scenario, but can also evoke greater other-regarding concerns, as foreigners are hurt more. If relative-gains considerations dominate other-regarding considerations in determining trade preferences, we should expect respondents to be more supportive of imposing the import limits on [China / Country X] when given the additional vignette. However, if other-regarding considerations dominate relative-gains considerations, they should be less supportive. Here, other-regarding considerations are inferred from the data. We also check our conclusions by analyzing the motivations expressed by respondents in their open-ended responses (see next section).

The literature in social psychology would lead us to expect relative-gains considerations to prevail in the “remove” (win-win) scenario and other-regarding considerations to dominate in the “impose” (win-lose) scenario. Part of the reason is that humans have an innate need for a positive self-image.Footnote 53 Indeed, some psychologists believe that this is the “master motive” of human beings.Footnote 54 Relatedly, self-regulation theory maintains that individuals are intrinsically motivated to uphold moral standards,Footnote 55 and self-determination theory proposes that people have an innate psychological need for “relatedness,” which makes them intrinsically motivated to care for others.Footnote 56

To uphold their positive self-image, human beings are motivated to avoid inflicting negatives on others, including foreigners.Footnote 57 Recall that in the win-win scenario foreigners continue to gain from trade, whereas in the win-lose scenario they are hurt by the proposed trade policy. We should therefore expect other-regarding concerns, in the form of not wanting to hurt or take advantage of other people, to be salient in the win-lose scenario but not in the win-win scenario.Footnote 58

Five nuances of the experimental design are useful to note:

  • Survey instruments based on import limits are frequently used in trade opinion research. Examples include Lü, Scheve, and Slaughter; Rho and Tomz;Footnote 59 and the trade sections of the American National Election Studies surveys adopted by Blonigen; Hainmueller and Hiscox; Hays, Ehrlich, and Peinhardt; and Scheve and Slaughter.Footnote 60 Survey instruments manipulating welfare gains or losses for citizens (rather than countries or governments) are also common in research on trade opinion.Footnote 61

  • China is a useful case for exploring the relevance of relative gains because it is a country not favored by most Americans, especially in the midst of a heated trade war between the US and China.Footnote 62 Thus, China provides a hard case for testing the interaction between relative-gains and other-regarding preferences in trade, compared to “Country X.”

  • We also use Country X as the hypothesized trade partner because we want to study how relative-gains and other-regarding considerations interact in trade opinion independent of the influence of the trade partner's identity. Including Country X in our design allows us to additionally test whether and to what extent our findings are sensitive to China and the trade war.Footnote 63

  • In the control group of the “remove” scenario, we did not stipulate that the welfare gains were equal for the two groups of citizens. Because equal gains in trade are inherently associated with the concepts of fairness and equality, which also affect trade preferences,Footnote 64 priming the respondents to think about equal gains could introduce an unintended treatment to the control group.

  • We did not include the win-win welfare implication for the “impose” scenario because it goes against economic theory that imposing import limits will generate gains for both countries. Similarly, we did not include the win-lose welfare implication for the “remove” scenario because it goes against economic theory that removing import limits will cause losses for the trade partner.Footnote 65

After reading the vignettes, respondents were asked how much they supported the given trade policy on a seven-point scale from 0 (“strongly oppose”) to 6 (“strongly favor”). They also provided open-ended responses to explain their preferences.

Experimental Results

To test whether relative-gains considerations affect trade preferences, we compare the groups randomly assigned to the “remove” scenario—a win-win trade policy (Table 1). If relative gains are important, support for the policy should decrease when the additional vignette (relative gains for the trade partner) is introduced. As Table 1 shows, this is indeed the case when the trade partner is China: respondents’ support for the policy decreased by 0.71 on the seven-point scale when they learned that Chinese gains would outweigh American gains (p = 0.0004, n = 435). Support also decreases, but not as much, when the trade partner is Country X: respondents’ support decreased by 0.29 when they learned that Country X's gains would outweigh American gains (p = 0.0828, n = 415). These results suggest that relative gains can affect trade opinion in a win-win scenario: if both sides are gaining, people want to gain more than their foreign trade partner. The relative-gains concerns are particularly salient when the trade partner is China.

Table 1. Average treatment effect among groups presented with the removal of import limits

Notes: The dependent variable is support for the removal of import limits, on a seven-point scale from 0 to 6. The additional vignette says that the gains enjoyed by Chinese or Country X's citizens would be greater than the gains enjoyed by American citizens. All t-tests are two-tailed.

Next, we compare the groups randomly assigned to the “impose” scenario—a win-lose trade policy (Table 2). If relative-gains concerns dominate, then support for the policy should increase when the additional vignette (greater relative gains for the US) is introduced. But it does not. When the trade partner was Country X, respondents’ support for the policy decreased by 0.80 on the seven-point scale (p = 0.0001, n = 445). Surprisingly, this decrease remained substantial (0.57) even when the trade partner was China (p = 0.0057, n = 438).

Table 2. Average treatment effect among groups presented with the imposition of import limits

Notes: The dependent variable is support for the imposition of import limits, on a seven-point scale from 0 to 6. The additional vignette says that the losses suffered by Chinese or Country X's citizens would be greater than the gains enjoyed by American citizens. All t-tests are two-tailed.

These results suggest that other-regarding preferences in trade are important not only domesticallyFootnote 66 but also internationally. Social considerations remain relevant even in the context of foreign rivalry amplified by a heated trade war. Relative-gains considerations can influence trade opinion, but they can also be countervailed if the trade policy presents a win-lose scenario that harms the trade partner.

The results also seem to indicate stronger relative-gains considerations and weaker social considerations when the trade partner is China.Footnote 67 If this is the case, we should observe a clearer pattern from respondents who are more nationalistic. We therefore subset our analyses to study the nationalists in our sample, those likely to hold stronger anti-Chinese sentiments.Footnote 68 The evidence suggests that among nationalists, relative-gains concerns are particularly salient, and social preferences more subtle, when the trade partner is China instead of Country X (Figures 2 and 3). In Appendices D and E, we further show that subset analyses of (1) hawks versus doves and (2) Republicans versus non-Republicans follow a similar empirical pattern: hawks and Republicans behave like nationalists, while doves and non-Republicans behave like non-nationalists.

Figure 2. Approval rate for removal of import limits by nationalism

Figure 3. Approval rate for imposition of import limits by nationalism

Which Forms of Other-Regarding Preferences Were at Play?

The results suggest that social preferences can affect opinion toward trade. But which specific forms of other-regarding preferences were at play? We believe that altruism and advantageous inequality aversion would be most relevant given our experimental design.

An individual is altruistic if “her utility increases with the well being of other people.”Footnote 69 A large body of research has shown that people suffer a moral cost (disutility) from causing harm to others.Footnote 70 In the win-lose scenario, respondents in the treatment group would be actively inflicting negatives on foreign citizens if they supported the proposed trade policy. This could activate their altruism and empathy. Such concerns, however, would not be activated in the win-win scenario because refusing to support the proposed policy would not actively cause harm to foreign citizens compared to the status quo.

Also consistent with our theoretical framework is advantageous inequality aversion, “the loss individuals incur because others have worse material outcomes than they do.”Footnote 71 If this form of inequity aversion operates at the international level, then domestic citizens will incur utility loss when foreign citizens have worse outcomes than they do. In the win-lose scenario where foreigners would have worse outcomes than Americans, the proposed trade policy in the treatment group would generate an even greater welfare gap between domestic and foreign citizens. Respondents driven by advantageous inequality aversion would then be less supportive of the proposed trade policy when they read the treatment vignette. This does not apply in the win-win scenario, however, because there is no advantageous inequality in that scenario.

To track the relevance of altruism and advantageous inequality aversion, we examine the open-ended responses in the win-lose scenario. We focus on whether and how frequently the respondents expressed other-regarding concerns, and what exactly these other-regarding concerns were, across different experimental conditions. This allows us to evaluate the argument that relative-gains considerations, which our experiment directly manipulated, can be offset by the respondent's other-regarding preferences, which are inferred from the data.Footnote 72

We use a two-stage approach to analyze the open-ended responses. First, we categorized responses into four groups: those displaying other-regarding preferences (e.g., “I oppose because it will strongly hurt the other country”); those displaying self-serving preferences (e.g., “Because [I] am selfish and want what is better for my country”); those raising retaliation concerns (e.g., “China owns a significant amount of the United States’ debt. It is best not to provoke a trading partner, that has significant leverage over you”); and those that were interpretable but did not fit into any other categories (e.g., “Business does not need government interference. Free trade!”).Footnote 73 Second, we broke down the responses that displayed other-regarding preferences, and classified them according to the type of other-regarding preferences implied: altruism/empathy (e.g., “I don't want anyone to suffer”); equality/fairness (e.g., “We should have equality”); cosmopolitanism (e.g., “I oppose this deal because I am a globalist, not a nationalist”); and others (e.g., “It's not moral”).

Our first-stage analysis provides further evidence that in the win-lose scenario individual trade attitudes were influenced by other-regarding preferences (Figure 4). When told that foreign losses outweigh domestic gains, respondents were more likely to justify their views based on their other-regarding preferences on the one hand, and less likely to explain their opinion based on their self-serving preferences on the other hand. Where the trade partner was China, the proportion of other-regarding responses rose by sixteen percentage points (p = 0.0011, n = 388) when the additional vignette was introduced, while the proportion of self-serving responses dropped by the same percentage points (p = 0.0017, n = 388). The empirical pattern is nearly identical where the trade partner was Country X.Footnote 74

Figure 4. Coding of open-ended responses by treatment condition in the win-lose scenario

Probing further, our second-stage analysis suggests that altruism and inequality aversion were the most relevant forms of other-regarding preferences expressed in the win-lose scenario. Among respondents who expressed other-regarding preferences in the open-ended responses, most made it clear that they did not want to harm foreign citizens, or that they did not want to make foreign citizens suffer (Figure 5).Footnote 75 Equality and fairness were also important to some respondents.Footnote 76 A small minority also viewed themselves as global citizens, and consequently believed that trade deals should be made in a way that also takes foreign welfare into consideration.Footnote 77

Figure 5. Disaggregation of other-regarding responses by treatment condition in the win-lose scenario

The results suggest that altruism and advantageous inequality aversion contributed to the generally low support for the win-lose trade policy. But alternative explanations should also be considered. First, fears of a trade war could affect our results: respondents might worry that China or Country X would respond to significant welfare losses by retaliating with a similarly hostile trade policy.Footnote 78 This explanation, while logically possible, seems unlikely as we find no increase in the percentage of open-ended responses that raised such retaliation concerns in the treatment group (Figure 4). To investigate further, we also subset our analysis by individual risk preference (see Appendix D). We find no evidence that risk-averse respondents—who should be more likely to fear retaliation—were systematically more opposed to the trade policy in the win-lose scenario when given the additional vignette. This further mitigates the concern that the treated respondents in the win-lose scenario reacted the way they did purely due to fears of retaliation from China or Country X.

Another interpretation pertains to respondents’ expectation of future cooperative- ness from China or Country X. It is possible that respondents strategically avoided causing harm to the trade partner in exchange for more favorable trade policy from China or Country X in the future. However, while some open-ended responses suggested the importance of free trade, which could be interpreted as evidence in favor of this mechanism, these responses were rare (see the category “Cosmopolitanism” in Figure 5). Nonetheless, that the results were driven by a global form of utilitarianism may be harder to rule out. Our additional vignette in the win-lose scenario may have driven utilitarian concerns in that it implied the global welfare level would decrease due to the proposed trade policy. Although very few open-ended responses displayed such concerns, we find that these responses appeared in the treatment group only, and might hint at a different but potentially very interesting form of other-regarding preferences that is not covered here.

While hand-coded content analysis can help us better understand the motivations and mechanisms behind the respondent's choice, one major shortcoming of manual coding lies in its replicability. To address this concern, we additionally conduct two separate sets of dictionary-based content analyses—one based on the Moral Foundations DictionaryFootnote 79 and the other based on our own dictionary. Their findings converge with each other, as well as with the hand-coded analysis. We document the dictionary-based analyses in detail in Appendix F.

Conclusion

We show that relative-gains considerations causally affect trade opinion, but not in a “beggar-thy-neighbor” or even a “beggar-thy-rival” situation. Relative gains are important in a win-win scenario: people want to gain more than their foreign trade partner if both sides are gaining. In a win-lose scenario, however, relative-gains considerations can be offset by other-regarding preferences. This applies not only when the trade partner is some unnamed country in general, but also when the trade partner is China in particular. This result is especially interesting because our experiment was conducted in the midst of the China–US trade war, in which mutual antagonism and competition were pronounced. Our findings challenge the conventional wisdom that underlies much of the IR scholarship—as well as much of the political rhetoric on trade—that would lead us to expect support for a trade policy in which the home state always wins.

Our work advances the literature in four ways. This study is the first to experi- mentally investigate how relative-gains and other-regarding preferences interact in trade. While previous studies have separately focused on the role of relative-gains and other-regarding factors,Footnote 80 a key question remains: what if these two forces collide? Knowing the answer to this question is important practically because both factors can come into play in real-world cases. We show that while relative gains are important under a win-win trade policy, other-regarding considerations can offset relative-gains preferences in a win-lose situation.

Second, our findings offer direct evidence on the causal relationship between relative gains and trade opinion. Contrary to previous work, we show that relative gains-seeking behavior can be observed in the full sample that includes a lot of non-Republicans—and not in Republicans onlyFootnote 81—insofar as other-regarding concerns are not triggered by the proposed trade policy.Footnote 82 The different findings are likely due to our different research focus, leading to different experimental manipulations: instead of in-group favoritism,Footnote 83 we focus directly on relative gains; instead of manipulating job gains or losses, we informed our respondents directly of the winners and losers to manipulate their perceptions of a country's gains or losses from trade. This ensures that they focus squarely on the relative gains from trade, and that the salience of job losses does not dominate their perceptions.

Third, the findings expand our understanding of the relationship between social preferences and trade opinion. Lü, Scheve, and Slaughter have found that other-regarding preferences at the domestic level influence individual trade opinion.Footnote 84 Brutger and Rathbun have recently shown that social preferences, in the form of inequity aversion, can also influence trade preferences in a win-win scenario.Footnote 85 We extend from these studies by demonstrating not only that altruism, in addition to inequity aversion, can operate at the international level and affect trade opinion, but also that such social preferences can offset relative-gains considerations in a win-lose scenario. Finally, by showing that beliefs about relative gains at the national level can influence trade opinion at the personal level, our findings support the idea that trade preferences are also guided by sociotropic motivations.Footnote 86

Several avenues open for future research. As our experiment targeted only American citizens, it would be useful to investigate whether relative-gains and other-regarding preferences vary across different countries. In addition, since our experiment emphasized the trade impact on citizens rather than on the countries per se,Footnote 87 it would be interesting for future work to explore whether a frame focusing on countries would lead to different outcomes. Moreover, our study did not cover all possible welfare implications of bilateral trade because we did not study the cases where the domestic gains outweigh the trade partner's gains or where the domestic losses outweigh the trade partner's gains. Future research may find it useful to study these two cases of asymmetric trade benefits. Finally, because trade is only one of the many forms of international interactions that create relative-gains concerns, future research should also study how perceptions of relative gains shape public preferences on issues beyond international trade.

Data Availability Statement

Replication files for this research note may be found at <https://doi.org/10.7910/DVN/DEPUUO>.

Supplementary Material

Supplementary material for this research note is available at <https://doi.org/10.1017/S0020818322000030>.

Acknowledgments

We thank Wilfred Chow, Jennifer Gandhi, Su-Hyun Lee, Renard Sexton, and participants at the 2019 MPSA Annual Conference in Chicago for their feedback and John Koo and Jiaqian Ni for their research assistance. We also thank the editors and anonymous reviewers at IO for their valuable suggestions and advice. The standard disclaimers apply.

Funding

We thank Hong Kong University and the education fund of the Research Grants Council of Hong Kong for financial support.

Footnotes

1. Quoted in David Lawder and Trevor Hunnicutt, “Pulled in Many Directions, Biden May Keep Trump's China Tariffs in Place,” Reuters, 8 September 2020.

2. Relative-gains considerations are concerns over how the home state “fare[s] compared to other states.” Snidal Reference Snidal1991b, 703.

3. For example, both Democratic and Republican senators in the United States have stressed the importance of winning—or not losing—against China in international trade. Bernie Sanders said during his presidential campaign: “Since the China trade deal I voted against, America has lost over 3 million manufacturing jobs. It's wrong to pretend that China isn't one of our major economic competitors. When we are in the White House we will win that competition by fixing our trade policies” (quoted in David Frum, “China Is a Paper Dragon,” The Atlantic, 3 May 2021). Regarding the US–China Phase 1 trade agreement, Marco Rubio commented: “This is not a win. Investing American capital in China may earn better returns in the short term. But it will come at a tremendous cost in the long term.” (Marco Rubio, “Marco Rubio: Investing in China Is Not a Good Deal,” New York Times, 17 January 2020). Lindsey Graham, another Republican senator, welcomed the trade agreement but added that “Chinese trade behavior has been very predatory against American interests,” and hoped that the agreement would “lead to further trade deals that are truly a win-win” (Lindsey Graham, “Graham Applauds New China Trade Deal,” 15 January 2020), available at <https://www.lgraham.senate.gov/public/index.cfm/2020/1/graham-applauds-new-china-trade-deal>.

4. For example, Trump tweeted: “When a country (USA) is losing many billions of dollars on trade with virtually every country it does business with, trade wars are good, and easy to win. Example, when we are down $100 billion with a certain country and they get cute, don't trade anymore—we win big. It's easy!” (quoted in Linda Qiu, “President Trump's Exaggerated and Misleading Claims on Trade,” New York Times, 6 March 2018).

5. For example, Guisinger Reference Guisinger2017; Hearn Reference Hearn2020; Lü, Scheve, and Slaughter Reference Lü, Scheve and Slaughter2012; Mansfield and Mutz Reference Mansfield and Mutz2009.

6. Lü, Scheve, and Slaughter Reference Lü, Scheve and Slaughter2012.

7. Brutger and Rathbun Reference Brutger and Rathbun2021.

9. Stolper and Samuelson Reference Stolper and Samuelson1941.

13. Baldwin and Magee Reference Baldwin and Magee2000; Mayda and Rodrik Reference Mayda and Rodrik2005.

14. Education, for example, can influence one's support for trade through channels that are unrelated to individual skills and economic self-interest. Hainmueller and Hiscox Reference Hainmueller and Hiscox2006 argued that because individuals with college education tend to have a greater exposure to economic ideas and information, they are more supportive of free trade. Rho and Tomz Reference Rho and Tomz2017 experimentally showed that economic ignorance prevented many people from understanding the distributional consequences of trade policy, which reduced their ability to identify and support a more self-serving trade policy.

15. Snidal Reference Snidal1991b, 703.

16. Waltz Reference Waltz1959, 198.

18. Snidal Reference Snidal1991a, 389.

19. This follows from the standard conceptualization of relative gains, that is, the domestic absolute outcome relative to the foreign absolute outcome. The key is the distance between domestic and foreign payoffs. See Grieco Reference Grieco1998b; Snidal Reference Snidal1991a; Waltz Reference Waltz1959.

27. Gowa and Mansfield Reference Gowa and Mansfield1993. See also Gowa Reference Gowa1989.

28. Mastanduno Reference Mastanduno1991, 109.

29. Kinder and Kiewiet Reference Kinder and Kiewiet1981.

31. Mansfield and Mutz Reference Mansfield and Mutz2009. See also Mutz and Kim Reference Mutz and Kim2017; Sabet Reference Sabet2013.

32. In line with the behavioral economics literature, we view other-regarding preferences as a form of behavioral motivation that is distinct from egoism. That is, other-regarding preferences are exhibited when an individual cares about others’ outcomes in a non-egoistic manner (Fehr and Fischbacher Reference Fehr and Fischbacher2002; Fehr and Schmidt Reference Fehr, Schmidt, Kolm and Ythier2006). Thus, relative-gains concerns do not constitute other-regarding preferences but instead demonstrate egoism, because “the gains of others give them the possibility to do harm to one's future egoistic ends through the use of coercion” (Brutger and Rathbun Reference Brutger and Rathbun2021, 884; see also Powell Reference Powell1991).

33. Güth, Schmittberger, and Schwarze Reference Güth, Schmittberger and Schwarze1982.

35. Berg, Dickhaut, and McCabe Reference Berg, Dickhaut and McCabe1995.

36. For example, Andreoni Reference Andreoni1990; Fehr and Schmidt Reference Fehr and Schmidt1999.

37. For example, Andreoni and Miller Reference Andreoni and Miller2002; Bellemare, Kröger, and van Soest Reference Bellemare, Kröger and van Soest2008; Engelmann and Strobel Reference Engelmann and Strobel2004; Fehr and Fischbacher Reference Fehr and Fischbacher2002.

39. Reviewed in Fehr and Fischbacher Reference Fehr and Fischbacher2002. See also Charness and Rabin Reference Charness and Rabin2002; Levitt and List Reference Levitt and List2007.

43. Lü, Scheve, and Slaughter Reference Lü, Scheve and Slaughter2012.

44. For instance, by manipulating the payoffs that the subjects and their partners receive in three different experimental games, Fehr, Glätzle-Rützler, and Sutter Reference Fehr, Glätzle-Rützler and Sutter2013 found that other-regarding behavior was prevalent in subjects regardless of whether their partners were deemed in-group or out-group members. But see Bernhard, Fischbacher, and Fehr Reference Bernhard, Fischbacher and Fehr2006 and Goette, Huffman, and Meier Reference Goette, Huffman and Meier2006, who suggested that other-regarding preferences among adults, in the form of altruism, can be affected by parochialism.

45. See, for example, Brutger and Rathbun Reference Brutger and Rathbun2021 and Hearn Reference Hearn2014 on trade. Hearn found that perceptions of unfair trade practices can reduce support for free trade. See Naoi Reference Naoi2020, 342–43 for an excellent review of how fairness and reciprocity shape protectionist sentiments. On the role of fairness in international bargaining, see Kertzer and Rathbun Reference Kertzer and Rathbun2015.

47. Herrmann, Tetlock, and Diascro Reference Herrmann, Tetlock and Diascro2001.

48. Mutz and Kim Reference Mutz and Kim2017.

51. Amazon Mechanical Turk (AMT) is a crowdsourcing platform that has been widely used in social science. AMT samples are significantly more diverse than traditional convenience samples, and comparable to nationally representative samples on many (but not all) demographic dimensions. Several studies testing the validity of AMT data found them to be as reliable as data from standard survey and laboratory experiments (Berinsky, Huber, and Lenz Reference Berinsky, Huber and Lenz2012; Coppock Reference Coppock2019; Coppock, Leeper, and Mullinix Reference Coppock, Leeper and Mullinix2018; Krupnikov and Levine Reference Krupnikov and Levine2014). Other studies have shown that AMT participants are at least as attentive as—if not more attentive than—those drawn from other subject pools, such as college students (Goodman, Cryder, and Cheema Reference Goodman, Cryder and Cheema2013; Hauser and Schwarz Reference Hauser and Schwarz2016; Paolacci, Chandler, and Ipeirotis Reference Paolacci, Chandler and Ipeirotis2010) and some commonly used Internet panels (Berinsky, Huber, and Lenz Reference Berinsky, Huber and Lenz2012, 366). For these reasons, many experiments in political science have used AMT, including Huff and Kertzer's Reference Huff and Kertzer2018 experiment on terrorism, Jones and Bejan's Reference Jones and Bejan2021 study on tolerance, and Rho and Tomz's Reference Rho and Tomz2017 survey experiment on trade preferences.

52. Rho and Tomz Reference Rho and Tomz2017.

53. Crocker, Olivier, and Nuer Reference Crocker, Olivier and Nuer2009.

54. Baumeister Reference Baumeister, Gilbert, Fiske and Lindzey1998. Consistent with the social psychology literature, the economists Roland Bénabou and Jean Tirole observed that studies have “confirm[ed] the importance of such self-image concerns in explaining prosocial behavior in anonymous settings.” Bénabou and Tirole Reference Bénabou and Tirole2006, 1653.

56. Deci and Ryan Reference Deci and Ryan2000, 231.

57. Brekke, Kverndokk, and Nyborg Reference Brekke, Kverndokk and Nyborg2003; Kahneman and Knetsch Reference Kahneman and Knetsch1992.

58. Prospect theory might also help us understand the results. If individuals are less risk seeking and aggressive in the domain of gains than in the domain of losses (see, for example, Davis Reference Davis2000, 37; Jervis Reference Jervis1992; Levy Reference Levy1992, 285–86), the win-lose scenario (where relative gains are made by the US) should be more conducive to other-regarding social considerations than the win-win scenario (where relative losses are incurred). We thank an anonymous reviewer for suggesting the potential relevance of prospect theory.

59. Lü, Scheve, and Slaughter Reference Lü, Scheve and Slaughter2012; Rho and Tomz Reference Rho and Tomz2017.

60. Blonigen Reference Blonigen2008; Hainmueller and Hiscox Reference Hainmueller and Hiscox2006; Hays, Ehrlich, and Peinhardt Reference Hays, Ehrlich and Peinhardt2005; Scheve and Slaughter Reference Scheve and Slaughter2001.

61. See, for example, Hiscox Reference Hiscox2006; Mutz and Kim Reference Mutz and Kim2017; Rho and Tomz Reference Rho and Tomz2017.

62. In spring 2018, about half of the adult American population expressed disfavor toward China, compared to only 38 percent who reported a favorable opinion. Wike and Devlin Reference Wike and Devlin2018.

63. Political scientists, particularly in IR, often use unnamed countries in experiments. See, for example, Johns and Davies Reference Johns and Davies2012; Tomz and Weeks Reference Tomz and Weeks2013; Yarhi-Milo, Kertzer, and Renshon Reference Yarhi-Milo, Kertzer and Renshon2018. Reference Brutger, Kertzer, Renshon, Tingley and WeissForthcoming research by Brutger and colleagues has also examined the advantages of, and provided justifications for, the use of unnamed countries in survey experiments.

65. That the US can gain in the “remove” scenario is consistent with economic theory. For a large economy like the US, removing import limits can decrease or increase its welfare—both can happen in the real world (Krugman, Obstfeld, and Melitz Reference Krugman, Obstfeld and Melitz2012, chapter 10). We also note that if some respondents disagreed with the vignette, we should end up having weaker average treatment effects. In the case where a randomized segment of respondents disagreed with the vignette, they would not be “treated” as intended in our experiment, thereby weakening the overall average treatment effects in the full sample. Therefore, having some respondents disagree with the vignette should weaken, rather than strengthen, our results.

66. Lü, Scheve, and Slaughter Reference Lü, Scheve and Slaughter2012.

67. Coding respondents whose support for the proposed trade policy ranged from 4 to 6 as supporters of the policy, we found that among the groups facing the “remove” scenario, decreases in support were 10.74 percentage points when China was the trade partner (p = 0.0171, n = 435) and 5.89 percentage points when Country X was the trade partner (p = 0.1456, n = 415). Among the groups facing the “impose” scenario, decreases in support were 8.22 percentage points when China was the trade partner (p = 0.0842, n = 438) and 14.72 percentage points when Country X was the trade partner (p = 0.0016, n = 445).

68. To identify nationalists in our sample, we use a prompt from Quek and Johnston Reference Quek and Johnston2018: “Everyone should support their country even when it is wrong.” Those who agree with this statement are classified as nationalists. This test is randomly administered to three-quarters of our sample, n = 1,305 (see Appendix D).

70. Reviewed in Crockett et al. Reference Crockett, Kurth-Nelson, Siegel, Dayan and Dolan2014, 17,320. Crockett and colleagues also noted that one strand of the literature “predicts that people will value others’ pain similarly to how they value their own pain, to the extent that they empathize with the other person,” with another strand further suggesting that moral sentiment “could lead some people to evaluate the cost of others’ pain as higher than their own in a setting where they feel a degree of responsibility for that pain.”

71. Lü, Scheve, and Slaughter Reference Lü, Scheve and Slaughter2012, 639.

72. Inferring other-regarding preferences from the data is common in experimental work that studies social preferences. See, for example, Lü, Scheve, and Slaughter Reference Lü, Scheve and Slaughter2012.

73. Thirteen percent (115 out of 883) of the responses were removed because they were not interpretable. This is comparable to the proportions in Davies and Johns Reference Davies and Johns2013 (17%) and Tomz Reference Tomz2007 (17%).

74. The proportion of self-serving responses dropped by sixteen percentage points (p = 0.0016, n = 380), and the proportion of other-regarding responses rose by thirteen percentage points (p = 0.0111, n = 380).

75. For example, “I don't agree with anything that would take away something from one party in order to benefit another. I believe there are solutions that can only benefit everyone without harming anyone.” Another reads, “I don't want anyone to suffer.”

76. For example, “The welfare of the citizens of China are of equal importance.” Another reads: “This is not fair to humanity.”

77. For example, “I don't agree with all these tariffs and import restrictions. While I am proud of being an American, I see us as part of a larger world, not just looking out for ourselves.” Another reads: “It is against globalization. We should think about not only our own country but also think about mutual prosperity as [a] member of the world.”

78. We thank an anonymous reviewer for highlighting this possibility.

79. Graham et al. Reference Graham, Nosek, Haidt, Iyer, Koleva and Ditto2011. See Appendix F for details.

80. Lü, Scheve, and Slaughter Reference Lü, Scheve and Slaughter2012; Mutz and Kim Reference Mutz and Kim2017.

81. Mutz and Kim Reference Mutz and Kim2017, 843.

82. To confirm that this result is not entirely driven by Republicans, we remove the Republicans from our data set and analyze the average treatment effect among groups facing the “remove” scenario against China. The approval rating for the policy is 4.71 in the control group, compared to 4.13 in the treatment group (p = 0.0070, n = 297).

83. Mutz and Kim Reference Mutz and Kim2017.

84. Lü, Scheve, and Slaughter Reference Lü, Scheve and Slaughter2012.

85. Brutger and Rathbun Reference Brutger and Rathbun2021.

87. For relevant work that also focused on the trade impact on citizens, see Hiscox Reference Hiscox2006; Mutz and Kim Reference Mutz and Kim2017; Rho and Tomz Reference Rho and Tomz2017.

References

Andreoni, James. 1990. Impure Altruism and Donations to Public Goods: A Theory of Warm-Glow Giving. Economic Journal 100 (401):464–77.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andreoni, James, and Miller, John. 2002. Giving According to GARP: An Experimental Test of the Consistency of Preferences for Altruism. Econometrica 70 (2):737–53.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baker, Andy. 2005. Who Wants to Globalize? Consumer Tastes and Labor Markets in a Theory of Trade Policy Beliefs. American Journal of Political Science 49 (4):924–38.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baldwin, David Allen. 1993. Neorealism and Neoliberalism: The Contemporary Debate. Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Baldwin, Robert E., and Magee, Christopher S.. 2000. Is Trade Policy for Sale? Congressional Voting on Recent Trade Bills. Public Choice 105 (1–2):79101.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Balistreri, Edward J. 1997. The Performance of the Heckscher–Ohlin–Vanek Model in Predicting Endogenous Policy. Canadian Journal of Economics 30 (1):117.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baumeister, Roy F. 1998. The Self. In The Handbook of Social Psychology, Vol. 1, 4th ed., edited by Gilbert, Daniel, Fiske, Susan, and Lindzey, Gardner, 680740. McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Baumeister, Roy F. 2010. The Self. In Advanced Social Psychology: The State of the Science, edited by Baumeister, Roy F. and Finkel, Eli J., 139–75. Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Beaulieu, Eugene. 2002a. Factor or Industry Cleavages in Trade Policy? An Empirical Analysis of the Stolper–Samuelson Theorem. Economics and Politics 14 (2):99131.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beaulieu, Eugene. 2002b. The Stolper–Samuelson Theorem Faces Congress. Review of International Economics 10 (2):343–60.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beaulieu, Eugene, and Magee, Christopher. 2004. Four Simple Tests of Campaign Contributions and Trade Policy Preferences. Economics and Politics 16 (2):163–87.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bellemare, Charles, Kröger, Sabine, and van Soest, Arthur. 2008. Measuring Inequity Aversion in a Heterogeneous Population Using Experimental Decisions and Subjective Probabilities. Econometrica 76 (4):815–39.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bénabou, Roland, and Tirole, Jean. 2006. Incentives and Prosocial Behavior. American Economic Review 96 (5):1652–78.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berg, Joyce, Dickhaut, John, and McCabe, Kevin. 1995. Trust, Reciprocity, and Social History. Games and Economic Behavior 10 (1):122–42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berinsky, Adam J., Huber, Gregory A., and Lenz, Gabriel S.. 2012. Evaluating Online Labor Markets for Experimental Research: Amazon.com's Mechanical Turk. Political Analysis 20 (3):351–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bernhard, Helen, Fischbacher, Urs, and Fehr, Ernst. 2006. Parochial Altruism in Humans. Nature 442:912–15.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Blonigen, Bruce A. 2008. New Evidence on the Formation of Trade Policy Preferences. Working paper no. 14627, National Bureau of Economic Research.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brekke, Kjell Arne, Kverndokk, Snorre, and Nyborg, Karine. 2003. An Economic Model of Moral Motivation. Journal of Public Economics 87 (9–10):1967–83.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brutger, Ryan, and Rathbun, Brian. 2021. Fair Share? Equality and Equity in American Attitudes Toward Trade. International Organization 75 (3):880900.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brutger, Ryan, Kertzer, Joshua D., Renshon, Jonathan, Tingley, Dustin, and Weiss, Chagai M.. Forthcoming. Abstraction and Detail in Experimental Design. American Journal of Political Science.Google Scholar
Busch, Marc L., and Reinhardt, Eric R.. 1993. Nice Strategies in a World of Relative Gains: The Problem of Cooperation Under Anarchy. Journal of Conflict Resolution 37 (3):427–45.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Charness, Gary, and Rabin, Matthew. 2002. Understanding Social Preferences with Simple Tests. Quarterly Journal of Economics 117 (3):817–69.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coppock, Alexander. 2019. Generalizing from Survey Experiments Conducted on Mechanical Turk: A Replication Approach. Political Science Research and Methods 7 (3):613–28.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coppock, Alexander, Leeper, Thomas J., and Mullinix, Kevin J.. 2018. Generalizability of Heterogeneous Treatment Effect Estimates Across Samples. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 115 (49):12441–46.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Crocker, Jennifer, Olivier, Marc-Andre, and Nuer, Noah. 2009. Self-Image Goals and Compassionate Goals: Costs and Benefits. Self and Identity 8 (2–3):251–69.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Crockett, Molly J., Kurth-Nelson, Zeb, Siegel, Jenifer Z., Dayan, Peter, and Dolan, Raymond J.. 2014. Harm to Others Outweighs Harm to Self in Moral Decision Making. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 111 (48):17320–25.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Davies, Graeme A.M., and Johns, Robert. 2013. Audience Costs Among the British Public: The Impact of Escalation, Crisis Type, and Prime Ministerial Rhetoric. International Studies Quarterly 57 (4):725–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Davis, James W. 2000. Threats and Promises: The Pursuit of International Influence. Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Deci, Edward L., and Ryan, Richard M.. 2000. The “What” and “Why” of Goal Pursuits: Human Needs and the Self-Determination of Behavior. Psychological Inquiry 11 (4):227–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Engelmann, Dirk, and Strobel, Martin. 2004. Inequality Aversion, Efficiency, and Maximin Preferences in Simple Distribution Experiments. American Economic Review 94 (4):857–69.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, Ernst, and Fischbacher, Urs. 2002. Why Social Preferences Matter: The Impact of Non-selfish Motives on Competition, Cooperation and Incentives. Economic Journal 112:C1C33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, Ernst, Glätzle-Rützler, Daniela, and Sutter, Matthias. 2013. The Development of Egalitarianism, Altruism, Spite and Parochialism in Childhood and Adolescence. European Economic Review 64:369–83.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, Ernst, and Schmidt, Klaus M.. 1999. A Theory of Fairness, Competition, and Cooperation. Quarterly Journal of Economics 114 (3):817–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, Ernst, and Schmidt, Klaus M.. 2006. The Economics of Fairness, Reciprocity, and Altruism: Experimental Evidence and New Theories. In Handbook on the Economics of Giving, Reciprocity, and Altruism, edited by Kolm, Serge-Christophe and Ythier, Jean Mercier, 615–91. Elsevier.Google Scholar
Filkowski, Megan M., Cochran, R. Nick, and Haas, Brian W.. 2016. Altruistic Behavior: Mapping Responses in the Brain. Neuroscience and Neuroeconomics 5:6575.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fong, Christina M., Bowles, Samuel, and Gintis, Herbert. 2006. Strong Reciprocity and the Welfare State. In Handbook of the Economics of Giving, Altruism and Reciprocity, edited by Kolm, Serge-Christophe and Ythier, Jean Mercier, 1439–64. Amsterdam: Elsevier.Google Scholar
Fordham, Benjamin O. 2008. Economic Interests and Public Support for American Global Activism. International Organization 62 (1):163–82.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Forsythe, Robert, Horowitz, Joel L., Savin, Nathan E., and Sefton, Martin. 1994. Fairness in Simple Bargaining Experiments. Games and Economic Behavior 6 (3):347–69.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Funk, Carolyn L. 2000. The Dual Influence of Self-Interest and Societal Interest in Public Opinion. Political Research Quarterly 53 (1):3762.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Glaser, Charles L. 1994. Realists As Optimists: Cooperation As Self-Help. International Security 19 (3):5090.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goette, Lorenz, Huffman, David, and Meier, Stephan. 2006. The Impact of Group Membership on Cooperation and Norm Enforcement: Evidence Using Random Assignment to Real Social Groups. American Economic Review 96 (2):212–16.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goodman, Joseph K., Cryder, Cynthia E., and Cheema, Amar. 2013. Data Collection in a Flat World: The Strengths and Weaknesses of Mechanical Turk Samples. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making 26 (3):213–24.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gowa, Joanne. 1989. Bipolarity, Multipolarity, and Free Trade. American Political Science Review 83 (4):1245–56.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gowa, Joanne, and Mansfield, Edward D.. 1993. Power Politics and International Trade. American Political Science Review 87 (2):408–20.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Graham, Jesse, Nosek, Brian A., Haidt, Jonathan, Iyer, Ravi, Koleva, Spassena, and Ditto, Peter H.. 2011. Mapping the Moral Domain. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 101 (2):366–85.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Grieco, Joseph M. 1988a. Anarchy and the Limits of Cooperation: A Realist Critique of the Newest Liberal Institutionalism. International Organization 42 (3):485507.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grieco, Joseph M. 1988b. Realist Theory and the Problem of International Cooperation: Analysis with an Amended Prisoner's Dilemma Model. Journal of Politics 50 (3):600–24.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grieco, Joseph M. 1990. Cooperation Among Nations: Europe, America, and Non-tariff Barriers to Trade. Cornell University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guisinger, Alexandra. 2017. American Opinion on Trade: Preferences without Politics. Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Güth, Werner, Schmittberger, Rolf, and Schwarze, Bernd. 1982. An Experimental Analysis of Ultimatum Bargaining. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 3 (4):367–88.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hainmueller, Jens, and Hiscox, Michael J.. 2006. Learning to Love Globalization: Education and Individual Attitudes Toward International Trade. International Organization 60 (2):469–98.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hainmueller, Jens, and Hopkins, Daniel J.. 2015. The Hidden American Immigration Consensus: A Conjoint Analysis of Attitudes Toward Immigrants. American Journal of Political Science 59 (3):529–48.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hauser, David J., and Schwarz, Norbert. 2016. Attentive Turkers: MTurk Participants Perform Better on Online Attention Checks Than Do Subject Pool Participants. Behavior Research Methods 48 (1):400407.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Hays, Jude C., Ehrlich, Sean, and Peinhardt, Clint. 2005. Government Spending and Public Support for Trade in the OECD: An Empirical Test of the Embedded Liberalism Thesis. International Organization 59 (2):271–88.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hearn, Eddie. 2014. Harm, Fairness and Trade Policy Preferences: An Experimental Examination of Sincere Fair-Trade Preferences. International Politics 51 (4):124–35.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hearn, Eddie. 2020. Disentangling the Relationship Between Sociotropic and Egotropic Trade Attitudes: A Survey Experiment in Japan. Japanese Journal of Political Science 21 (1):3142.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Herrmann, Richard K., Tetlock, Philip E., and Diascro, Matthew N.. 2001. How Americans Think About Trade: Reconciling Conflicts Among Money, Power, and Principles. International Studies Quarterly 45 (2):191218.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hiscox, Michael J. 2006. Through a Glass and Darkly: Attitudes Toward International Trade and the Curious Effects of Issue Framing. International Organization 60 (3):755–80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoffman, Michael E. S. 2010. Job Losses and Perceptions of Globalization. Journal of World Trade 44 (5):967–83.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huff, Connor, and Kertzer, Joshua D.. 2018. How the Public Defines Terrorism. American Journal of Political Science 62 (1):5571.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Irwin, Douglas A. 1994. The Political Economy of Free Trade: Voting in the British General Election. Journal of Law and Economics 37 (1):75108.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Irwin, Douglas A. 1996. Industry or Class Cleavages over Trade Policy? Evidence from the British General Election of 1923. In The Political Economy of Trade Policy: Papers in Honor of Jagdish Bhagwati, edited by Feenstra, Robert C., Grossman, Gene M., and Irwin, Douglas A., 5375. MIT Press.Google Scholar
Jervis, Robert. 1992. Political Implications of Loss Aversion. Political Psychology 13 (2):187204.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johns, Robert, and Davies, Graeme A.M.. 2012. Democratic Peace or Clash of Civilizations? Target States and Support for War in Britain and the United States. Journal of Politics 74 (4):1038–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johnson, Tim, Dawes, Christopher T., Fowler, James H., McElreath, Richard, and Smirnov, Oleg. 2009. The Role of Egalitarian Motives in Altruistic Punishment. Economic Letters 102:192–94.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jones, Calvert W., and Bejan, Teresa M.. 2021. Reconsidering Tolerance: Insights from Political Theory and Three Experiments. British Journal of Political Science 51 (2):604–23.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jones, Ronald W. 1971. A Three-Factor Model in Theory, Trade, and History. In Trade, Balance of Payments, and Growth: Papers in Honor of Charles P. Kindleberger, edited by Bhagwati, Jagdish, Ronald Jones, Robert Mundell, and Jaroslav Vanek, 321. North Holland.Google Scholar
Kaempfer, William H., and Marks, Stephen V.. 1993. The Expected Effects of Trade Liberalisation: Evidence from US Congressional Action on Fast-Track Authority. World Economy 16 (6):725–40.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel, and Knetsch, Jack L.. 1992. Valuing Public Goods: The Purchase of Moral Satisfaction. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 22 (1):5770.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kertzer, Joshua D., and Rathbun, Brian C.. 2015. Fair Is Fair: Social Preferences and Reciprocity in International Politics. World Politics 67 (4):613–55.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kinder, Donald R., and Kiewiet, D. Roderick. 1981. Sociotropic Politics: The American Case. British Journal of Political Science 11 (2):129–61.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krugman, Paul R., Obstfeld, Maurice, and Melitz, Marc J.. 2012. International Economics: Theory and Policy, 9th ed. Addison-Wesley.Google Scholar
Krupnikov, Yanna, and Levine, Adam Seth. 2014. Cross-Sample Comparisons and External Validity. Journal of Experimental Political Science 1 (1):5980.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levitt, Steven D., and List, John A.. 2007. What Do Laboratory Experiments Measuring Social Preferences Reveal About the Real World? Journal of Economic Perspectives 21 (2):153–74.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levy, Jack S. 1992. Prospect Theory and International Relations: Theoretical Applications and Analytical Problems. Political Psychology 13 (2):283310.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lipson, Charles. 1984. International Cooperation in Economic and Security Affairs. World Politics 37 (1):123.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
, Xiaobo, Scheve, Kenneth, and Slaughter, Matthew J.. 2012. Inequity Aversion and the International Distribution of Trade Protection. American Journal of Political Science 56 (3):638–54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mansfield, Edward D., and Mutz, Diana C.. 2009. Support for Free Trade: Self-Interest, Sociotropic Politics, and Out-Group Anxiety. International Organization 63 (3):425–57.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Margalit, Yotam. 2011. Costly Jobs: Trade-Related Layoffs, Government Compensation, and Voting in US Elections. American Political Science Review 105 (1):166–88.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Matthews, John C. 1996. Current Gains and Future Outcomes: When Cumulative Relative Gains Matter. International Security 21 (1):112–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mastanduno, Michael. 1991. Do Relative Gains Matter? America's Response to Japanese Industrial Policy. International Security 16 (1):73113.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mayda, Anna M., and Rodrik, Dani. 2005. Why Are Some People (and Countries) More Protectionist than Others? European Economic Review 49 (6):1393–430.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Morrow, James D. 1997. When Do “Relative Gains” Impede Trade? Journal of Conflict Resolution 41 (1):1237.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mutz, Diana C. 1992. Mass Media and the Depoliticization of Personal Experience. American Journal of Political Science 36 (2):483508.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mutz, Diana C., and Kim, Eunji. 2017. The Impact of In-Group Favoritism on Trade Preferences. International Organization 71 (4):827–50.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Naoi, Megumi. 2020. Survey Experiments in International Political Economy: What We (Don't) Know About the Backlash Against Globalization. Annual Review of Political Science 23:333–56.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
O'Rourke, Kevin H., and Sinnott, Richard. 2001. The Determinants of Individual Trade Policy Preferences: International Survey Evidence. In Brookings Trade Forum: 2001, edited by Collins, Susan M. and Rodrik, Dani, 157206. Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
Paolacci, Gabriele, Chandler, Jesse, and Ipeirotis, Panagiotis G.. 2010. Running Experiments on Amazon Mechanical Turk. Judgment and Decision Making 5 (5):411–19.Google Scholar
Powell, Robert. 1991. Absolute and Relative Gains in International Relations Theory. American Political Science Review 85 (4):1303–20.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Quek, Kai, and Johnston, Alastair Iain. 2018. Can China Back Down? Crisis De-escalation in the Shadow of Popular Opposition. International Security 42 (3):736.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ray, Edward John. 1987. Changing Patterns of Protectionism: The Fall in Tariffs and the Rise in Non-Tariff Barriers. Northwestern Journal of International Law and Business 8 (2):285327.Google Scholar
Rho, Sungmin, and Tomz, Michael. 2017. Why Don't Trade Preferences Reflect Economic Self-Interest? International Organization 71 (S1):S85S108.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rousseau, David L. 2002. Motivations for Choice: The Salience of Relative Gains in International Politics. Journal of Conflict Resolution 46 (3):394426.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Samuelson, Paul A. 1971. Ohlin Was Right. Swedish Journal of Economics 73 (4):365–84.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Scheve, Kenneth F., and Slaughter, Matthew J.. 2001. What Determines Individual Trade-Policy Preferences? Journal of International Economics 54 (2):267–92.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sears, David O., and Funk, Carolyn L.. 1990. Self-Interest in Americans’ Political Opinions. In Beyond Self-Interest, edited by Mansbridge, Jane J., 147–70. University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Snidal, Duncan. 1991a. International Cooperation Among Relative Gains Maximizers. International Studies Quarterly 35 (4):387402.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Snidal, Duncan. 1991b. Relative Gains and the Pattern of International Cooperation. American Political Science Review 85 (3):701–26.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stolper, Wolfgang F., and Samuelson, Paul A.. 1941. Protection and Real Wages. Review of Economic Studies 9 (1):5873.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tomz, Michael. 2007. Domestic Audience Costs in International Relations: An Experimental Approach. International Organization 61 (4):821–40.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tomz, Michael R., and Weeks, Jessica L.P.. 2013. Public Opinion and the Democratic Peace. American Political Science Review 107 (4):849–65.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tricomi, Elizabeth, Rangel, Antonio, Camerer, Colin F., and John P. O'Doherty. 2010. Neural Evidence for Inequality-Averse Social Preferences. Nature 463:1089–91.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Waltz, Kenneth. 1959. Man, the State, and War: A Theoretical Analysis. Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Waltz, Kenneth. 1979. Theory of International Politics. Addison-Wesley.Google Scholar
Werner, Suzanne. 1997. In Search of Security: Relative Gains and Losses in Dyadic Relations. Journal of Peace Research 34 (3):289302.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wike, Richard, and Devlin, Kat. 2018. As Trade Tensions Rise, Fewer Americans See China Favorably. Pew Research Center, 28 August. Available at <http://pewrsr.ch/37BTlGe>..>Google Scholar
Yarhi-Milo, Keren, Kertzer, Joshua D., and Renshon, Jonathan. 2018. Tying Hands, Sinking Costs, and Leader Attributes. Journal of Conflict Resolution 62 (10):2150–79.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. Design of study

Figure 1

Table 1. Average treatment effect among groups presented with the removal of import limits

Figure 2

Table 2. Average treatment effect among groups presented with the imposition of import limits

Figure 3

Figure 2. Approval rate for removal of import limits by nationalism

Figure 4

Figure 3. Approval rate for imposition of import limits by nationalism

Figure 5

Figure 4. Coding of open-ended responses by treatment condition in the win-lose scenario

Figure 6

Figure 5. Disaggregation of other-regarding responses by treatment condition in the win-lose scenario

Supplementary material: PDF

Yeung and Quek supplementary material

Yeung and Quek supplementary material

Download Yeung and Quek supplementary material(PDF)
PDF 1.3 MB
Supplementary material: Link

Yeung and Quek Dataset

Link