Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-xtgtn Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-19T09:14:42.478Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The GATT and the regulation of trade barrier: regime dynamics and functions

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  22 May 2009

Jock A. Finalyzson
Affiliation:
Institute of International Relations at the University of British Columbia.
Mark W. Zacher
Affiliation:
Institute of International Relations and Professor of Political Science at the University of British Columbia.
Get access

Abstract

Since the Second World War complex and changing sets of norms and rules have governed trade relations among most countries. They have largely originated from a unique and accidental international organization, the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT). We have labeled these norms, rules, and decision-making mechanisms the GATT regime or global trade barriers regime. The importance that GATT members have attached to certain norms has shaped the regime's procedural mechanisms, rules, and implementation of rules. Classifying those norms as sovereignty or interdependence norms, we posit that the strength or autonomy of the regime can be established by analyzing the prominence of the interdependence norms in the issue area. We close by exploring some of the functions of the regime in international trade and political relations.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © The IO Foundation 1981

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 For a comprehensive analysis of the ITO, consult Brown, W. A., The United States and the Restoration of World Trade (Washington, D. C.: Brookings, 1950)Google Scholar. Also useful, especially for the perspective of a U. S. participant in the negotiations, is Wilcox, Clair, A Charter for World Trade (New York: Macmillan, 1949)Google Scholar.

2 This fascinating story is told in William Diebold, The End of the ITO, Essays in International Finance no. 16 (Princeton University, 1952)Google Scholar.

3 Dam, Kenneth, The GATT-Law and International Economic Organization (1970; New York: Midway Reprint, 1977), p. 11Google Scholar.

4 In fact, in the technical legal sense it can be argued that the GATT is not even an international organization today. Dam, , The GATT, p. 335Google Scholar; Jackson, John H., World Trade and the Law of GATT (Indianapolis: Bobbs-Merrill, 1969), pp. 119–22Google Scholar.

5 GATT, Basic Instruments and Selected Documents (hereinafter BISD), 26th Supp., 1980, p. viiiGoogle Scholar. Countries with full membership rights and obligations are known as contracting parties, of which there are currently 85. Two countries have acceded provisionally. A third category, which at present includes 30 countries, is referred to as “Countries applying the General Agreement on a de facto basis.” These are former colonies that have not yet decided whether to join the GATT. They generally do not participate in GATT affairs except during trade rounds. Interviews, Ottawa, September 1980.

6 This definition was accepted by the contributors to the forthcoming special issue of International Organization on “International Regimes.” The conference took place in October 1980 in Los Angeles.

7 Three shorter definitions can be found in Robert Keohane, O. and Nye, Joseph S., Power and Interdependence: World Politics in Transition (Boston: Little, Brown, 1977), p. 19Google Scholar; Haas, Ernst B., “Why Collaborate? Issue-Linkage and International Regimes,” World Politics 32 (04 1980), p. 358CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Young, Oran R., “International Regimes: Problems of Concept Formation,” World Politics 32 (04 1980), p. 332CrossRefGoogle Scholar. Young does elaborate at some length on the terms included in his definition of regimes (pp. 333–39).

8 The authors would like to thank Peter Katzenstein and Lynn Mytelka for their suggestions of terms to describe these two sets of norms.

9 The distinction between sovereignty and interdependence norms is not made by other authors. However, they do implicitly address the issue of how much constraint nonsovereignty norms would have to exert in order to state that a regime exists. In the articles to be included in the special issue of International Organization Young and Puchala and Hopkins basically take the point of view that regimes exist in all issue areas, whereas Keohane, Stein, Jervis, and Haas are concerned that a significant constraining effect of nonsovereignty or interdependence norms be established before one concludes that a regime exists.

10 Wyndham-White, Eric, “Negotiations in Prospect,” in Bergsten, C. Fred, ed., Toward A New World Trade Policy: The Maidenhead Papers (Lexington, Mass.: D. C. Heath, 1975), p. 321Google Scholar.

11 For example, in Article XIII: 1 (nondiscriminatory application of quantitative restrictions), Article XVII:1 (state trading practices), and Article XVIII:20 (economic development measures). For a fuller list, see Jackson, , World Trade, pp. 255–56Google Scholar.

12 Ibid., pp. 502–503; Dam, , The GATT, pp. 276–83Google Scholar.

13 Articles XIV, VI, and XXIII, respectively.

14 Dam, , The GATT, p. 290Google Scholar.

15 BISD, 2nd Supp., 1954, pp. 101–109.

16 BISD, 7th Supp., 1959, pp. 69–71.

17 Tovias, Alfred, Tariff Preferences in Mediterranean Diplomacy (London: Macmillan, 1977)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Lomé ll, Overseas Development Institute Briefing Paper no. 1 (London: ODI, 1980)Google Scholar.

18 Gerard, and Curzon, Victoria, “The Management of Trade Relations in the GATT,” in Shonfield, Andrew, ed., International Economic Relations of the Western World, 19591971, volume 1 Politics and Trade (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1976), p. 231Google Scholar

19 BISD, 18th supp., 1972, pp. 24–28 for the 1971 waivers. See Murray, Tracy, Trade Preferences for Developing Countries (London: Macmillan, 1977)CrossRefGoogle Scholar, for an analysis of GSP, and Espiel, H., “GATT: Accommodating Generalized Preferences,” Journal of World Trade Law 8 (05-06 1974)Google Scholar, for a discussion of GATT's response to the GSP. See BISD, 26th supp., 1980, pp. 201–11 for the Tokyo Round decisions on GSP and preferences among LDCs.

20 Baldwin, Robert E., Beyond the Tokyo Round Negotiations, Thames Essay no. 22 (London: Trade Policy Research Centre, 1979)Google Scholar.

21 MCCulloch, Rachel, “Trade and Direct Investment: Recent Policy Trends,” in Dornbusch, Rudiger and Frenkel, Jacob A., eds., International Economic Policy: Theory and Evidence (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1979), p. 90Google Scholar.

22 Curzon, , “Management of Trade Relations,” p. 229Google Scholar.

23 Interviews, Ottawa, September 1980.

24 Section 102(f) of the 1974 Trade Act allows the president to recommend to Congress that the U. S. implementing law for the codes apply only to signatories. U. S., Senate, Committee on Finance, Subcommittee on International Trade, MTN Studies, vol. 4, Part 1 (Washington, D. C.: Government Printing Office, 1979), pp. 220–24Google Scholar (hereinafter MTN Studies); Krasner, Stephen D., “The Tokyo Round: Particularistic Interests and Prospects for Stability in the Global Trading System,” International Studies Quarterly 23 (December 1979), p. 515CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

25 Interviews with U. S. and Canadian trade officials.

26 MTN Studies, vol. 4, p. 4; Krasner, “Tokyo Round,” pp. 500–24.

27 Bergsten, C. Fred, “On the Non-Equivalence of Import Quotas and ‘Voluntary’ Export Restraints,” Bergsten, in, ed., New World Trade Policy, p. 242Google Scholar; OECD, Policy Perspectives for International Trade and Economic Relations: Report by the High-Level Group on Trade and Related Problems (Paris, 1972), p. 82Google Scholar.

28 Bergsten, “On Non-Equivalence”; Bhagwati, Jagdish, “Market Disruption, Export Market Disruption, Compensation and GATT Reform,” in Bhagwati, Jagdish, ed., The New International Economic Order: The North-South Debate (Cambridge: MIT Press, 1977)Google Scholar.

29 Curzon, , “Management of Trade Relations,” pp. 274–78Google Scholar.

30 MCCulloch, , “Trade and Direct Investment,” p. 90Google Scholar.

31 Murray, Trade Preferences, passim.

32 White, , “Negotiations,” p. 323Google Scholar.

33 Curzon, , “Management of Trade Relations,” p. 148Google Scholar.

34 Meyer, F. V., International Trade Policy (London: Croom Helm, 1978), pp. 137–38Google Scholar.

35 Article XII of the General Agreement permits the use of quotas for balance-of-payments purposes. Dam, , The GATT, pp. 150–53Google Scholar.

36 Meyer, , Trade Policy, pp. 138–40Google Scholar; Kock, Karin, International Trade Policy and the GATT: 1947–1967 (Stockholm: Almqvist and Wiksell, 1969), pp. 9596Google Scholar.

37 Meyer, , Trade Policy, p. 142Google Scholar; Kock, , International Trade Policy, p. 99Google Scholar.

38 Curzon, , “Management of Trade Relations,” pp. 149”–50Google Scholar; Dam, , The GATT, p. 57Google Scholar.

39 Curzon, , “Management of Trade Relations,” pp. 149–50Google Scholar.

40 Ibid., pp. 168–75; Meyer, , Trade Policy, pp. 146–47Google Scholar; Dam, , The GATT, p. 67Google Scholar.

41 Curzon, , “Management of Trade Relations,” p. 170Google Scholar; Preeg, Ernest H., Traders and Diplomats: An Analysis of the Kennedy Round of Negotiations Under the General Agreement For Tariffsand Trade (Washington, D. C.: Brookings, 1970), p. 12Google Scholar.

42 Ibid., pp. 47–49.

43 Ibid., p. 29.

44 Canada, New Zealand, South Africa, Australia, and the LDCs were not participants in the linear tariff negotiations. Dam, , The GATT, pp. 7273Google Scholar.

45 Derived from Preeg, , Traders and Diplomats, pp. 208–11Google Scholar (Tables 13–1, 13–2,13–3, 13–4).

46 Ibid., p. 251.

47 On the Antidumping Code consult Dam, , The GATT, pp. 174–77Google Scholar; and Lloyd, Peter, Antidumping Actions and the GATT System, Thames Essay no. 9 (London: Trade Policy Research Centre, 1977)Google Scholar. See also the first report of the GATT committee of signatories, BISD, 17th supp., 1970, pp. 43–46.

48 Recent treatments of the current protectionist drift include Balassa, Bela, “The ‘New Protectionism’ and the International Economy,” Journal of World Trade Law 12 (09-10 1978)Google Scholar; Strange, Susan, “The Management of Surplus Capacity,” International Organization 33 (Summer 1979)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Blackhurst, R., Marian, N., and Tumlir, J., “Trade Liberalization, Protectionism and Interdependence,” GATT Studies in International Trade no. 5 (11 1977)Google Scholar. The next two paragraphs draw heavily on Balassa. He estimates that industrial countries' “new” protective measures affected 3–5% of world trade, or $30–50 billion, in 1976 and 1977, and that, partly as a result, world trade growth was more than halved in 1977 over 1976 (pp. 418, 429).

49 BISD, 25th Supp., 1979, pp. 32–33; BISD, 26th supp., 1980, pp. 276–79.

50 Following the establishment of a Working Party on “Market Disruption” in 1959, a Long-Term Arrangement Regarding International Trade in Cotton Textiles (LTA) was agreed to in 1962, under the auspices of the GATT (which struck a committee to administer the Arrangement); the LTA was extended for three years in 1967 and again in 1970. A broader arrangement to ensure the so-called “orderly expansion” of trade in virtually all classes of textiles and clothing, the MultiFibre Arrangement (MFA), was negotiated in 1973 and renegotiated to cover the period 1978–82. Membership in the committee and participation in the various textile agreements have been open to both members and nonmembers of GATT. For evaluation and description of these schemes, consult Dam, , The GATT, pp. 296315Google Scholar; Strange, , “Surplus Capacity,” pp. 310–18Google Scholar; and Taake, H. and Weiss, D., “The World Textile Arrangement: The Exporters' Viewpoint,” Journal of World Trade Law 8 (11-12 1974)Google Scholar. For the contrasting views of exporters and importers on the impact and utility of the recent MFA, see GATT Doc. COM. TEX/15, 5 February 1980, and BISD, 26th supp., 1980, pp. 340–53.

51 The Tokyo Round of Multilateral Trade Negotiations: Report by the Director-General of GATT (Geneva: GATT, 04 1979), pp. 120–21Google Scholar (hereinafter Tokyo Round).

52 Krasner, , “Tokyo Round,” p. 511Google Scholar.

53 Warley, T. K., “Western Trade in Agricultural Products,” in Shonfield, , ed., International Economic Relations, vol. 1, pp. 287404Google Scholar; Josling, T. E., Agriculture in the Tokyo Round Negotiations, Thames Essay no. 10 (London: Trade Policy Research Centre, 1977)Google Scholar.

54 MTN Studies, vol. 2, p. 63Google Scholar and passim. Also see Golt, Sidney, The GATT Negotiations 1973–79: The Closing Stage (Washington, D. C.: British-North American Committee, 1979), pp. 2829Google Scholar; Krasner, , “Tokyo Round,” pp. 518–21Google Scholar; Josling, , Agriculture in Tokyo Round; Tokyo Round, pp. 143– 47, 156–64, 177–79Google Scholar.

55 Golt, , GATT Negotiations, p. 25Google Scholar; Krasner, “Tokyo Round,” pp. 521–23; Tokyo Round, pp. 90–95Google Scholar.

56 See Krasner, , “Tokyo Round,” pp. 512–15Google Scholar; Tokyo Round, pp. 75–82. Article VIII of the code permits exclusion of defense-related purchases, and of purchases in connection with public health and safety practices, from the new rules. BISD, 26th Supp., 1980, p. 51. Krasner (pp. 514–15) reports that 85% of U. S. government purchases will not be covered by the code. See also Dam, , The GATT, pp. 199221Google Scholar.

57 Krasner, , “Tokyo Round,” pp. 515–17Google Scholar; MTN Studies, vol. 6, part 1, pp. 100102Google Scholar.

58 Josling, , Agriculture in Tokyo Round, p. 11Google Scholar.

59 Balassa, Bela, The Structure of Protection in Developing Countries (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins Press, 1971)Google Scholar; Diaz-Alejandro, Carlos, “Trade Policies and Economic Development,” in Kenen, Peter, ed., International Trade and Finance: Frontiers for Research (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1975)Google Scholar.

60 “The representative of a developing country stated that even though his country had liberalized almost completely its trade regime and imports had consequently greatly expanded, difficulties of access impeding the expansion and diversification of exports were being experienced in some developed country markets.” BISD, 26th Supp., 1980, p. 277 (Report of the Committee on Trade and Development, November 1978).

61 Dam, , The GATT, pp. 6768Google Scholar; MTN Studies, vol. 6, part 1, pp. 23, 48–49Google Scholar. Reciprocity is implicit in section 126 of the 1974 Trade Act.

62 Cited in Evans, John, The Kennedy Round and American Trade Policy: The Twilight of the GATT? (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1971), pp. 2122CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

63 Curzon, , “Management of Trade Relations,” p. 156Google Scholar.

64 Dam, , The GATT, p. 59Google Scholar.

65 Curzon, , “Management of Trade Relations,” p. 160Google Scholar.

66 Ibid., p. 159; Evans, , Kennedy Round, pp. 2425Google Scholar; Johnson, Harry, Trade Negotiations and the New International Monetary System (Geneva: Graduate Institute of International Studies, 1976) pp. 1618Google Scholar.

67 Evans, , Kennedy Round, p. 25Google Scholar.

68 Curzon, , “Management of Trade Relations,” pp. 158–59Google Scholar; Johnson, , New Monetary System, pp. 1618Google Scholar. Johnson notes (p. 23) that flexible exchange rates undermine “the balance-of-payments rationale for… reciprocity.” Johnson has elsewhere contrasted the liberal and instinctively mercantilist ways of viewing tariff reductions: An Economic Theory of Protectionism, Tariff Bargaining, and the Formation of Customs Unions,” Journal of Political Economy 73 (1965): 256–82CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

69 Dam, , The GATT, p. 65Google Scholar.

70 Golt (GATT Negotiations) pictures the Tokyo Round as essentially a triangular bargaining process among the “big three,” with Canada, the LDCs, and a few other countries occupying minor roles except when specific issues (e. g., tropical products for the LDCs) were discussed. Preeg similarly discusses the Kennedy Round as if the only players of consequence were the U. S., Japan, the EEC, and the U. K., the latter not then a member of the Community.

71 Evans, , Kennedy Round, pp. 24, 31Google Scholar.

72 Dam, , The GATT, p. 19Google Scholar.

73 Curzon, , “Management of Trade Relations,” p. 161Google Scholar; Dam, , The GATT, pp. 6877Google Scholar.

74 Interviews, Ottawa, September 1980; interview, U. S. trade officials, November 1980.

75 Golt, , GATT Negotiations, pp. 2223Google Scholar; Krasner, , “Tokyo Round,” pp. 514–18Google Scholar; interviews, Ottawa, September 1980.

76 Curzon, , “Management of Trade Relations,” p. 206Google Scholar.

77 Hudec, Robert E., Adjudication of International Trade Disputes, Thames Essay no. 16 (London: Trade Policy Research Centre, 1978), p. 17Google Scholar; emphasis added.

78 Preeg, , Traders and Diplomats, pp. 227–30Google Scholar; Kock, , International Trade Policy, p. 245Google Scholar.

79 The submissions of the LDCs to the “framework” negotiating group can be found in GATT Docs. MTN/FR/W/14 (Mexico), MTN/FR/W/9 (India), MTN/FR/W/7 (Pakistan), and MTN/FR/W/1 (Brazil).

80 BISD, 26th Supp., 1980, p. 204.

81 Balassa, Bela, The Tokyo Round and Developing Countries, World Bank Staff Working Paper no. 370 (02 1980)Google Scholar.

82 Interview, Ottawa, September 1980.

83 BISD, 26th Supp., 1980, p. 205. The graduation concept envisages an improvement in LDCs' “trade situation” to the point where they are expected “to participate more fully in the framework of rights and obligations under the General Agreement.”

84 Curzon, , “Management of Trade Relations, p. 152Google Scholar.

85 Articles 111: 3, XXIV, XI: 2, XVI: 3, XX, XXI.

86 Jackson, , World Trade, pp. 6064Google Scholar.

87 These other minor, temporary escape clauses concern the withdrawal or modification of tariff concessions (Article XXVIII) and the authorization of “exceptional” duties in cases where dumping or subsidization allegedly occurs (permitted by Article VI, the Kennedy and Tokyo Round Antidumping Codes, and the Tokyo Round Subsidies/Countervailing Duties Code).

88 BISD, 26th supp., 1980, pp. 205–209.

89 Curzon, Gerard, Multilateral Commercial Diplomacy (London: Michael Joseph, 1965), p. 137Google Scholar.

90 Interview, Ottawa, September 1980.

91 Balassa, , “The ‘New Protectionism’,” p. 422Google Scholar; Dam, , The GATT, pp. 3334Google Scholar.

92 Dam, , The GATT, pp. 3234Google Scholar; Curzon, , “Management of Trade Relations,” pp. 217–20Google Scholar. See the report of the Working Party that examined a 1971 Danish surcharge, where it was concluded that, although “not explicitly covered by any provision of the GATT,” the Danish surcharge was consistent with the “spirit” of GATT. It was further noted: “Quantitative restrictions provided for in Article XII would have had a more serious effect on the interests of its trading partners.” BISD, 19th supp., 1973, pp. 129.

93 For example, all the contracting parties having recourse to quantitative restrictions under the balance-of-payments safeguard provision in 1976, 1977, 1978, and 1979 have been LDCs, and all have done so under Article XVIII.

94 GATT Doc. L/4679, “Modalities of Application of Article XIX,” 5 July 1978.

95 Tumlir, Jan, “A Revised Safeguard Clause for GATT?Journal of World Trade Law 7 (07-08 1973), p. 405Google Scholar and passim; Meier, Gerald, “Externality Law and Market Safeguards: Applications in the GATT Multilateral Trade Negotiations,” Harvard International Law Journal 18 (Summer 1977), pp. 496–97, 523Google Scholar; Bhagwati, “Market Disruption.”

96 Bhagwati, , “Market Disruption,” p. 169Google Scholar; Meier, , “Externality Law,” p. 523Google Scholar.

97 Curzon, , “Management of Trade Relations,” p. 152Google Scholar.

98 Waivers are listed in the cumulative index, BISD, 26th supp., 1980, pp. 387–92. Jackson, (World Trade, p. 548)Google Scholar argues that waivers were intended to be temporary, but have become permanent in many cases.

99 In 1955, the U.S. obtained a waiver to permit the use of import quotas regardless of whether production controls were employed, as required by the Agricultural Adjustment Act. This was “a grave blow to GATT's prestige” (Dam, , The GATT, p. 260Google Scholar), and was the first major step to remove agriculture from GATT rules. Jackson, (World Trade, p. 548)Google Scholar notes that because of the size of the U. S. market, the impact of this waiver “on world trade has probably been more extensive” than that of any other. The Community's Common Agricultural Policy has no doubt been infinitely more disruptive, but it is not covered by a waiver. Evans notes that “Community producers are insulated from the effect of any price competition with the outside world” (Kennedy Round, p. 84).

100 Dam, , The GATT, p. 227Google Scholar; Kock, , International Trade Policy, p. 237Google Scholar.

101 Ibid., p. 230.

102 BISD 7thSupp., 1959, p. 28.

103 Dam, (The GATT, pp. 229–35)Google Scholar provides an excellent survey of Committee Ill's work.

104 GATT Press Release 962 (1966).

105 Jackson describes the legal obligations contained in Part IV as “soft” (World Trade, p. 647). Dam notes that the new chapter contains “a great deal of verbiage and very few precise commitments” (The GATT, p. 237).

106 Ibid., p. 239.

107 Tokyo Round, p. 93.

108 BISD, 26th Supp., 1980, p. 203; GATT: A Legal Guide to the Tokyo Round,” Journal of World Trade Law 13 (09-10 1979), pp. 443–44Google Scholar.

109 BISD, 29th Supp., 1980, p. 203; Balassa, , Tokyo Round and Developing Countries, pp. 2830Google Scholar.

110 Ibid., pp. 15–20.

111 Ibid., passim.

112 See Golt, Sidney, Developing Countries and the GATT System, Thames Essay no. 13 (London: Trade Policy Research Centre, 1978)Google Scholar.

113 Young, , “International Regimes,” pp. 336–37Google Scholar.

114 Jackson, World Trade, chapter 8; Dam, The GATT, chapter 19; Hudec, , Adjudication of International Trade Disputes, pp. 125Google Scholar.

115 Jackson, , World Trade, pp. 77 and 122–23Google Scholar.

116 Gerard, and Curzon, Victoria, “GATT: Traders' Club,” in Cox, Robert W. and Jacobson, Harold K., eds., The Anatomy of Influence: Decision-Making in International Organization (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1973), p. 302Google Scholar.

117 Ibid., p. 314.

118 Dam, , The GATT, p. 61Google Scholar.

119 Ibid., pp. 62–63.

120 Jackson, , World Trade, pp. 164–65Google Scholar.

121 BISD, 26th Supp., 1980, p. 211.

122 BISD, 26th Supp., 1980, p. 210.

123 GATT Doc. MTN/FR/W17.

124 Jackson, , World Trade, p. 124Google Scholar.

125 Dam, , The GATT, p. 4Google Scholar.

126 Hudec, Adjudication of International Trade Disputes; Jackson, John H., “The Crumbling Institutions of the Liberal Trade System,” Journal of World Trade Law 12 (03-04 1978)Google Scholar, and Governmental Disputes in International Trade Relations: A Proposal in the Context of GATT,Journal of World Trade Law 12 (01-02 1979)Google Scholar; Roschke, Thomas, “The GATT: Problems and Prospects,” Journal of Law and Economics 12 (1977)Google Scholar.

127 Jackson, , World Trade, p. 757Google Scholar.

128 Dam, , The GATT, pp. 3032Google Scholar.

129 Jackson, , World Trade, pp. 3031Google Scholar.

130 Hudec, , Adjudication of International Trade Disputes, p. 5Google Scholar.

131 Curzon, , “GATT: Traders' Club,” p. 134Google Scholar.

132 Ibid., p. 137; Dam, , The GATT, p. 61Google Scholar. Note that this technique was made necessary by U. S. law.

132 Cited in Kock, , International Trade Policy, p. 100Google Scholar.

134 Dam, , The GATT, p. 62Google Scholar.

135 Ibid.

136 BISD, 4th Supp., 1956, p. 80.

137 Curzon, , “Management of Trade Relations,” p. 173Google Scholar.

138 Dam, , The GATT, p. 62Google Scholar.

139 Ibid., pp. 61–77; MTN Studies, vol. 2, p 34–35.

140 Curzon, , “Management of Trade Relations,” p. 205Google Scholar.

141 Golt, GATT Negotiations, passim.

142 Curzon, , “Management of Trade Relations,” p. 205Google Scholar.

143 Tumlir, Jan, “A Revised Safeguards Clause for GATT?Journal of World Trade Law 7 (07-08 1973), p. 407Google Scholar; Bhagwati, “Market Disruption.”

144 Curzon, , “Management of Trade Relations,” p. 205Google Scholar.

145 Curzon, , “GATT: Traders' Club,” p. 316Google Scholar.

146 Curzon, , “Management of Trade Relations,” p. 206Google Scholar.

147 Hudec, Adjudication of International Trade Disputes; Maciel, George A., The International Framework for World Trade: Brazilian Proposals for GATT Reform (London: Trade Policy Research Centre, 1977), pp. 1112Google Scholar.

148 Hudec, , Adjudication of International Trade Disputes, pp. 711Google Scholar.

149 Cline, William et al. , Trade Negotiations in the Tokyo Round (Washington, D.C.: Brookings, 1978), p. 30Google Scholar.

150 Shonfield, , International Economic Relations of the Western World: An Overall View,” in Shonfield, , ed., International Economic Relations, vol. 1, pp. 4748Google Scholar.

151 Tumlir, Jan, “Emergency Action Against Sharp Increases in Imports,” in Corbet, Hugh and Jackson, Robert, eds., In Search of a New World Economic Order (London: Croom Helm, 1974), p. 266Google Scholar.

152 Dam, , The GATT, pp. 45Google Scholar.

153 Cox, Robert and Jacobson, Harold, “Introduction,” in Cox, and Jacobson, , eds., The Anatomy of Influence, pp. 56.Google Scholar.

154 See Keohane's article in the forthcoming special issue of International Organization.

155 Keohane also notes that this is a function of regimes.

156 Young, Oran R., Compliance and Public Authority: A Theory With International Applications (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1979), pp. 1825Google Scholar.

157 Interviews.

158 Shonfield, , “An Overall View,” p. 126Google Scholar; Curzon, “GATT: Traders' Club,” passim.

159 Jackson, , “Governmental Trade Disputes,” p. 2Google Scholar.

160 Jackson, , “The Birth of the GATT-MTN System,” p. 26Google Scholar.

161 Evans, , Kennedy Round, p. 318Google Scholar.

162 Hudec, , Adjudication, p. 36Google Scholar.

163 Interviews with Canadian trade policy officials, September 1980, and with U. S. officials, November 1980.

164 Curzon, , “GATT: Traders' Club,” pp. 325–26Google Scholar, for a discussion of influence in the GATT.

165 Golt, GATT Negotiations, passim.

166 MTN Studies, vol. 4, p. 7.

167 Blackhurst, , Marian, and Tumlir, , “Trade Liberalization,” p. 9Google Scholar.

168 Between 1948 and 1973, the volume of world trade increased sixfold, growing at an average annual rate of 7.This growth rate surpassed that of world production, which was also growing rapidly. Since 1973, growth rates have slowed, but trade has generally continued to expand faster than production. See ibid., pp. 7–19, and Cooper, Richard, The Economics of Interdependence (New York: MCGraw-Hill, 1968), chap. 3Google Scholar.