Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-gtxcr Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-18T02:32:42.568Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Regimes and the limits of realism: regimes as autonomous variables

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  22 May 2009

Get access

Extract

Two distinct traditions have developed from structural realist perspectives. The first, the billiard ball version, focuses purely on interaction among states. The second, the tectonic plates version, focuses on the relationship between the distribution of power and various international environments. It is the latter tradition that suggests why regimes may be important for a realist orientation. However, it also opens the possibility for viewing regimes as autonomous, not just as intervening, variables. There may be lags between changes in basic causal variables and regime change. There may be feedback from regimes to basic causal variables. Both lags and feedback suggest an importance for regimes that would be rejected by conventional structural arguments.

Type
Conclusions, Con and Pro
Copyright
Copyright © The IO Foundation 1982

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 Rogowski, Ronald, “Rationalist Theories of Politics: A Midterm Report,” World Politics 30, 2 (01 1978), p. 306CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

2 One exception is the additional acquisition of nuclear weapons in a world of assured second-strike capability. See Jervis, Robert, “Why Nuclear Superiority Doesn't Matter,” Political Science Quarterly 94, 4 (Winter 19791980)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

3 Hirschman, Albert, National Power and the Structure of Foreign Trade (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1981)Google Scholar; Feis, Herbert, Europe The World's Banker, 1870–1914 (New York: Norton, 1965)Google Scholar; Staley, Eugene, War and the Private Investor: A Study in the Relations of International Politics and International Private Investment (Garden City, N.Y.: Doubleday, Doran, 1935)Google Scholar.

4 Rosecrance, Richard, “International Theory Revisited,” International Organization 35, 4 (Autumn 1981), pp. 705706CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

5 A succinct statement of North's, Robert argument can be found in his “Toward a Framework for the Analysis of Scarcity and Conflict,” International Studies Quarterly 21, 4 (12 1977)Google Scholar. For a superlative new exposition see Gilpin, Robert, War and Change in World Politics (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1981)Google Scholar.

6 It is, of course, possible to deny that any puzzle exists, to argue that there has not been any fundamental shift in power. Susan Strange takes this position in her article for this volume, as do most European scholars. In this case the higher degree of disorder would be compatible with a marginal shift in power capabilities within a structure that has remained basically hegemonic. One might also argue, as Strange does, that there has always been considerable disorder in the system.

7 This debate in the international relations literature parallels a current debate in the literature on domestic explanations of foreign, especially foreign economic, policy. For a conventional structural analysis with economic sectors as the exogenous variable see Kurth, James R., “The Political Consequences of the Product Cycle: Industrial History and Political Outcomes,” International Organization 33, 1 (Winter 1979)Google Scholar. For an analysis that sees both economic interests and political institutions as independent variables see Gourevitch, Peter A., “International Trade, Domestic Coalitions, and Liberty: Comparative Responses to the Crisis of 1873–1896,” Journal of Interdisciplinary History 8, 2 (Autumn 1977)Google Scholar. For two articles that emphasize the interactive and autonomous roles of institutions once they are firmly implanted see Katzenstein, Peter J., “Capitalism in One Country? Switzerland in the International Economy,” International Organization 34, 4 (Autumn 1980)Google Scholar, and Katzenstein, Peter J., “Problem or Model? West Germany in the 1980s,” World Politics 32, 4 (07 1980)Google Scholar; for the same conceptualization in a Marxist framework see Duvall, Raymond D. and Freeman, John R., “The State and Dependent Capitalism,” International Studies Quarterly 25, 1 (03 1981)Google Scholar.

8 Lags and feedback do not present puzzles for various Grotian orientations illustrated in this volume by Haas's discussion of organic theories emphasizing turbulent fields with multiple feedback loops.

9 Arthur Stein's contribution to this volume, p. 322.

10 George, Alexander L., “Domestic Constraints on Regime Change in U.S. Foreign Policy: The Need for Policy Legitimacy,” in Holsti, Ole R. et al. , Change in the International System (Boulder, Col.: Westview, 1980), p. 248Google Scholar.

11 Stein's contribution to this volume, p. 323.

12 Arrow, Kenneth J., The Limits of Organization (New York: Norton, 1974), p. 28Google Scholar.

13 Oran Young's contribution to this volume, p. 280.

14 Robert 0. Keohane's contribution to this volume, p. 348.

15 Aggarwal, Vinod K., “Regime Transformation: An Analysis of the International Textile/ Apparel System—1955–1978,” paper presented to the International Studies Association, Philadelphia, 03 1981, p. 16Google Scholar.

16 Ernst B. Haas's contribution to this volume, p. 241.

17 Jönsson, Christer, “Sphere of Flying: The Politics of International Aviation,” International Organization 35, 2 (Spring 1981)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

18 Conybeare's, John A. C. imaginative application of the Coase theorem to international organizations, in “International Organization and the Theory of Property Rights,” International Organization 34, 3 (Summer 1980)CrossRefGoogle Scholar, emphasizes the property-rights assigning function of international organizations. It may be preferable to have such institutions create a set of property rights that internalize externalities, rather than have them directly allocate resources.

19 See Finlayson, Jock A. and Zacher, Mark W., “The GATT and the Regulation of Trade Barriers: Regime Dynamics and Functions,” International Organization 35, 4 (Autumn 1981), p. 601Google Scholar, for an elaboration of this point in the context of the international trade regime.

20 This argument is elaborated in Krasner, Stephen D., “Transforming International Regimes: What the Third World Wants and Why,” International Studies Quarterly 25, 1 (03 1981)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

21 Finlayson, and Zacher, , “The GATT,” p. 600Google Scholar.

22 Gilpin, Robert, U.S. Power and the Multinational Corporation (New York: Basic Books, 1975), especially chaps. 7 and 8CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

23 North, Douglass C. and Thomas, Robert Paul, The Rise of the Western World: A New Economic History (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1973), chap. 1CrossRefGoogle Scholar.