Elsevier

World Development

Volume 52, December 2013, Pages 120-131
World Development

Oil Exporters’ Dilemma: How Much to Save and How Much to Invest

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2013.06.006Get rights and content

Summary

Policymakers in oil-exporting countries confront the question of how to allocate oil revenues among consumption, saving, and investment in the face of high income volatility. We study this allocation problem in a precautionary saving and investment model under uncertainty. Consistent with data in the 2000s, precautionary saving is sizable and the marginal propensity to consume out of permanent shocks is below one, in stark contrast to the predictions of the perfect foresight model. The optimal investment rate is high if productivity in the tradable sector is high enough.

Introduction

Policymakers in many commodity-exporting countries confront the question of how much to consume, save, and invest out of revenues from commodity exports. In the face of highly volatile commodity (especially, oil) revenues, governments have to balance several objectives at the same time. These include smoothing consumption, ensuring intergenerational equity if a natural resource is exhaustible, managing volatility by building buffer-stock/precautionary savings,1 and investing in capital to promote economic development. This paper studies how oil exporters should allocate their volatile tradable income among safe liquid assets, domestic investment, and consumption, over a long horizon.

Large oil exporters face high income volatility and have sizable saving but relatively low investment (Figure 1, Figure 2).2 It seems intuitive that oil exporters should save a great deal because they are often hit by adverse income shocks. However, it is not obvious how large their savings should be and how savings should relate to the level of income uncertainty. Most oil exporters also have low investment despite their high saving rates (Figure 2).3 Should they not invest more to grow faster, promote development, and have alternative industries when oil runs out? As we discuss below, the returns to investment are also uncertain, and as a consequence, there is a tradeoff between saving in safe liquid assets and undertaking risky domestic investment. In the late 1970s when the real oil price was high, oil exporters on average invested about 30% of GDP. In contrast, in the 2000s when the oil price was at a comparable level, investment fell to about 20% of GDP (Figure 3).4 Moreover, oil-producing countries’ current accounts and their buildup of foreign reserves fluctuated significantly over time, with broadly balanced current account positions in the 1990s and large surpluses in the 2000s.

We present a stylized model of optimal buffer-stock/precautionary saving and investment under uncertainty to study the allocation dilemma of oil exporters. The model is based on the “silo” model of Cherif and Hasanov (2012) in which we incorporate nontradable goods.5 It features permanent and temporary shocks to income and has two assets: a safe asset (e.g., in the form of a sovereign wealth fund) and risky capital. Assuming that investment is a constant share of income, we compute the “golden rule” of investment, that is, the optimal share of income invested. Based on the optimal share of investment, optimal consumption and saving policies are obtained. The model could also be interpreted as a stochastic model of the current account.6

We compute the marginal propensity to consume (MPC) out of wealth (including revenue windfalls) and out of permanent shocks.7 The model’s results are compared to the predictions of the standard perfect foresight model and the data on government revenue and spending in the last decade. We simulate average time paths and confidence bands of income, consumption, and buffer-stock savings, to help gauge risks to the dynamics of these variables over the finite planning horizon.

We find that precautionary saving of oil exporters is sizable (30% of income), whereas investment is relatively low (15% of income) given high volatility of permanent shocks to oil revenues and relatively low productivity of the tradable sector. This result is in stark contrast to the perfect foresight model, which predicts large borrowing rather than saving. The optimal investment rate in our model depends primarily on the productivity of investment in the tradable sector and directly affects the growth rate of output. In contrast, the productivity of the nontradable sector does not affect the optimal investment rate much. Since investment is risky, the more the country invests, the faster it grows but at the expense of larger buffer-stock savings and lower income volatility. Thus, there is a tradeoff between higher growth/higher volatility and lower growth/lower volatility regimes. Faced with highly volatile income, the government would optimally accumulate substantial buffer-stock savings and invest relatively little if investment productivity in the tradable sector was low, a policy associated with lower growth/lower volatility regime. In contrast, with higher productivity in the tradable sector, investment and growth rates would be high, facilitating a faster recovery in case of negative income shocks and reducing the need for large buffer-stock savings.

The MPC out of permanent shocks obtained from the model, which is below one, is at odds with the perfect foresight model, but it is broadly consistent with the government revenue and consumption data in the recent decade. If we take the model and the implied MPC at face value, oil exporters on average treated most shocks in the 2000s as permanent. The oil-exporting countries accumulated buffer-stock savings from extra oil revenues rather than spending all or borrowing (Figure 3).

The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 discusses the related literature, and Section 3 presents the model and calibration based on a group of oil exporters. Section 4 analyzes results, and Section 5 concludes.

Section snippets

Related literature

A few recent papers have analyzed optimal government policies in resource abundant countries.8

The silo model of oil exporters

The main components of the model and its solution are described below.14 Readers who are not interested in the model details could skip this section and proceed to Section 4.

We think of fiscal policy in oil-exporting countries as a social planner’s life-cycle optimal consumption program under uncertainty.

Excluding nontradable production

The model predicts large saving at the beginning of the planning horizon and a relatively low investment rate, consistent with the empirical observations reported in Figure 2. In this section, we assume that the investment rate in the tradable sector does not affect the nontradable output process (τ̃ is a fixed parameter) abstracting from the link between tradable and nontradable production. Figure 4 shows simulated time paths of average optimal consumption and income. Precautionary saving (the

Concluding remarks

In this paper, we study optimal consumption, saving, and investment policies of oil exporters. We show that, faced with high permanent rather than temporary shocks to oil income, policymakers should spend conservatively and build up buffer-stock savings to prepare for possible negative persistent income shocks. Our model shows that, in general, precautionary saving should be sizable, about 30% of initial income. In addition, the tradable sector plays a paramount role in investment-saving

Acknowledgments

We would like to thank the editors, Arun Agrawal and Oliver Coomes, and two anonymous referees for substantially improving the paper. We are grateful to participants of the IMF Institute’s course on Macroeconomic Management and Fiscal Policy in November 2009 and various IMF seminars for helpful discussions and comments. In particular, we thank Rudolfs Bems, Paul Cashin, Aasim Husain, Joong Shik Kang, Grace Li, Amine Mati, Paolo Mauro, David O. Robinson, Ratna Sahay, Axel Schimmelpfennig,

References (27)

  • Carroll, C. (2001). A theory of the consumption function, with and without liquidity constraints (Expanded Version)....
  • C. Carroll

    Buffer-stock saving and the life cycle/permanent income hypothesis

    The Quarterly Journal of Economics

    (1997)
  • Cavalcanti, T., Mohaddes, K., & Raissi, M. (2012). Commodity price volatility and the sources of growth. IMF Working...
  • Cited by (31)

    • Fiscal windfall curse

      2020, European Economic Review
      Citation Excerpt :

      From this perspective, our transitory fiscal windfall is equivalent to a transitory positive shock to taxable incomes, and hence, current revenues. Seen as a revenue management problem (e.g., van der Ploeg and Venables 2011; Cherif and Hasanov 2013), we could reformulate the problem as one in which local governments seek to transform an extraordinary one-off revenue into a continuous flow of income. Here, the municipalities should either invest in projects and assets with positive net present value, or decrease the stock of debt and reduce future debt service.

    • Assessing Alternative Investment Policies in a Resource-Rich Capital-Scarce Country: Results from a DSGE analysis for Iran

      2020, Energy Policy
      Citation Excerpt :

      They concluded that the public investment-based scenario, along with saving in the Sovereign Wealth Fund, is an appropriate scenario compared with the scenario of saving the whole oil revenues into the fund and domestic investment. Cherif and Hasanov (2013), using an intertemporal optimization model, found that the tradable sector plays an important role in investment and saving dynamics. Also, if internal productivity is high, lower saving in the Oil Fund (buffer-stock) and higher domestic investment would be optimal.

    • Stochastic trends and fiscal policy

      2018, Economic Modelling
    • Emergence of sovereign wealth funds

      2018, Journal of Commodity Markets
    • Fuel saving strategies in the Andes: Long-term impacts for Peru, Colombia and Ecuador

      2018, Energy Strategy Reviews
      Citation Excerpt :

      Some oil-exporting countries apply energy subsidies to distribute benefits across the population, promote industrialization and economic diversification and create jobs and enhance competitiveness [10]. The efficiency of domestic investments based on oil revenues is constrained by the productivity of tradable sectors [11]. For instance, scaling up public investments too high and too fast could expose the economy to instability due to absorptive capacity constraints, possible Dutch disease and risks of currency depreciation [12,13].

    View all citing articles on Scopus
    View full text