Elsevier

Journal of Public Economics

Volume 135, March 2016, Pages 74-86
Journal of Public Economics

Higher taxes, more evasion? Evidence from border differentials in TV license fees

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jpubeco.2016.01.007Get rights and content

  • We study unique cross-sectional data on the evasion of TV license fees in Austria.

  • We exploit border tax differentials to identify the effect of higher license fees on evasion.

  • We find a highly significant positive effect: higher fees trigger more evasion.

  • Non-parametric analysis and a spatial regression discontinuity design document the robustness of the finding.

Abstract

This paper studies the evasion of TV license fees in Austria. We exploit border differentials to identify the effect of fees on evasion. Comparing municipalities at the low- and high-fee side of state borders reveals that higher fees trigger significantly more evasion. Our preferred estimator indicates that a one percent increase in fees raises the evasion rate by 0.3 percentage points. The positive effect of fees on evasion is confirmed in different parametric and non-parametric approaches and survives several robustness checks.

Introduction

Identifying the link between taxes and evasion is an equally difficult as important task for empirical research: it is difficult, because measuring evasion requires us to work with ‘evidence of the invisible’ (Slemrod and Weber, 2012); at the same time, it is important to quantify evasion responses to taxation, in order to predict revenue consequences of tax reforms and to design optimal tax policies.1 In contrast to studies that exploit exogenous variation in enforcement (e.g., Kleven et al., 2011), however, causal evidence on the impact of taxes on evasion is still scarce. The early literature on income tax evasion provides conflicting evidence (e.g., Clotfelter, 1983, Slemrod, 1985, Feinstein, 1991). Recent studies point to a positive effect: Gorodnichenko et al. (2009), who study a major tax reform in Russia, find a huge positive elasticity of evasion with respect to the tax rate.2 Kleven et al. (2011) examine bunching at kinks in the Danish income tax schedule. Comparing bunching of pre- and post-auditing incomes, they identify a small positive effect of tax rates on evasion. Our paper indirectly contributes to this literature by studying the evasion of TV license fees. Based on unique cross-sectional data from Austria, we examine whether higher fees result in more evasion.

License fees are a widespread tool to finance public broadcasting: two thirds of all European, half of all African and Asian, and a few countries in the Americas collect license fees. In 2005, a total of €20 billion on fees were collected in Europe (see Fellner et al., 2013). Households have an incentive to evade fees because public broadcasting programs can be received without paying fees. Rincke and Traxler (2011) demonstrate that households trade off the gains from evasion against the costs of detection. Beyond this similarity to tax evasion, the institutional framework is attractive as it offers a good measure of evasion: 99% of all Austrian households own a radio or TV (ORF Medienforschung, 2006), which makes them liable to register for license fees, according to federal law. Relating the number of registered to all households thus gives a reasonable proxy for evasion. In addition, the set-up allows us to apply a border based identification strategy in the spirit of Holmes (1998).

Total license fees include a specific state tax. While the collection and enforcement of the fees is harmonized at the federal level, variation in the state tax creates significant border differentials in license fees. We exploit these discontinuities – or ‘border notches' (Slemrod, 2010) – by comparing evasion rates among municipalities on the high- and low-tax side of state borders. In addition, we compute the driving distance of each municipality to the nearest state border and implement a regression discontinuity design (Lee and Lemieux, 2010). Before doing so, we carefully discuss the identifying assumptions that allow us to exploit the border differentials in a quasi-experimental way. Among others, we document that – within the tightly constrained framework of Austria's federalism – other fiscal policies are uncorrelated to the specific state tax. Moreover, we show that a large set of relevant municipality characteristics (including enforcement rates) are balanced and smoothly distributed around the borders.

The analysis of border differentials identifies a precisely estimated, positive effect of fees on evasion. This result is confirmed in different parametric and non-parametric approaches and survives several robustness checks. On average, license fees increase by around 18%– from €206 to €243 – at the state borders. This differential is accompanied by a discontinuous increase in the evasion rate of 5 percentage points. Putting these numbers together, our central estimate indicates that a one percent increase in fees raises the evasion rate by about 0.3 percentage points.

Given that this semi-elasticity reflects a binary response – evasion at the extensive margin – it is hard to directly compare the effect size with the intensive margin responses analyzed in the literature. However, finding a large evasion response is consistent with the huge elasticities of evasion with respect to tax rates documented in the few other studies: Fisman and Wei (2004), for instance, find that a one percent increase in taxes and tariffs increases import tax evasion by more than 3%. Fack and Landais (2016) document that the elasticity of overreporting tax deductions (charitable contributions) is large and above 2. Similarly strong income reporting effects in equally weak enforcement contexts are provided by Gorodnichenko et al., 2009, Kopczuk, 2012. The large effect identified in our institutional set-up seems consistent with these findings.

We make several contributions to the literature. First and foremost, our evidence strongly supports the intuition that higher taxes trigger more evasion. This is important for two reasons. On the one hand, the relationship between taxes and evasion is theoretically ambiguous (Yitzhaki, 1974). We introduce a simple model to study the binary evasion decision which is relevant in our case. Although our set-up differs from the classical income tax evasion theory in several important ways, we show that the ambiguous comparative static from the literature also applies to our context. On the other hand, empirical evidence on the causal link between taxation and evasion is scarce and conflicting (see the survey in Andreoni et al., 1998). In light of this scarcity and in the absence of a clear theoretical prediction, the result that higher fees trigger more evasion marks a valuable contribution. Moreover, by studying a binary evasion decision, we provide a rare piece of evidence on the extensive margin of evasion.

On a more general account, our study provides evidence that further corroborates the rational model of evasion which stresses the economic incentives to cheat. The relevance of these incentives was often questioned in the past. Over the last years, however, several studies convincingly demonstrated that the expected costs from evasion play a significant role in shaping non-compliance (Kleven et al., 2011, Fellner et al., 2013, Dwenger et al., 2016). The present paper contributes to this literature by documenting the impact of the potential gains from cheating.

In terms of methods, the present study is the first to use discontinuities at borders – in the tradition of Holmes, 1998, Black, 1999 – to identify the effect of taxes on evasion. Our approach is closely related to recent work that exploits state tax differentials to analyze cigarette tax avoidance (Merriman, 2010) and the role of the internet as a tax haven (Agrawal, 2014).3 More generally, we contribute to the growing literature on border based identification (e.g., Bayer et al., 2007) and spatial regression discontinuity designs (e.g., Lalive, 2008).

The remainder of the paper is structured as follows. Section 2 introduces the institutional background and describes our data. In Section 3 we discuss a simple theoretical model with a binary evasion decision. Section 4 briefly discusses the outcome from a naive cross-sectional regression and highlights the identification problem. Section 5 discusses our identification strategy and presents the results from a border notch and a spatial RD design. The last section concludes.

Section snippets

TV license fees

Many countries in the world use obligatory TV and radio license fees to finance public broadcasting. A typical system of license fees can be found in Austria, where the Broadcasting License Fee Act stipulates that every ‘household’ (broadly defined, including apartment-sharing communities) must register its broadcasting equipment with Fee Info Service (FIS). FIS, a subsidiary of the public broadcasting company, is responsible for collecting and enforcing the fees. Each year, one license fee has

Model

To set the stage for our empirical analysis, we first study the role of fees for a household's decision to either pay or evade fees. We model this binary choice in the spirit of Allingham and Sandmo (1972). An agent with an exogenous (after-tax) income yi faces a license fee t. If he pays the fee, his available income is yi  t. If he evades the fee, he is detected with probability p, 0 < p < 1. In case of detection, he has to pay the license fee and a fine, s > 0, resulting in an available

Cross-sectional analysis

As a starting point, we analyze the cross-sectional variation in evasion. We estimate the model Evasioni=αcs+βcslog(Feesi)+Xiγcs+ϵics,where Xi includes a large set of control variables that account for municipality differences in, e.g., population size and density, age, educational, religious, household and occupational structure as well as voting outcomes. In addition, we control for the local enforcement rate and average labor income. As license fees only vary at the state level, we compute

Border notches

Our first approach to identify the effect of fees on evasion relates to the notion of ‘border notches' (Slemrod, 2010), i.e., the idea that borders create discontinuous changes in a certain treatment. In our context, there are border tax differentials (similar as, e.g., in Agrawal, 2015) which produce discontinuous changes in license fees at state borders (see Section 2). The comparison of evasion rates between municipalities on the ‘high tax’- and ‘low tax’-side of a state border then captures

Conclusions

Based on unique cross-sectional data that offer a proxy for the evasion of TV license fees in all 2380 Austrian municipalities, we study the effect of higher fees on evasion. While the collection and enforcement of license fees is harmonized at the federal level, the total fee due includes federal and state taxes. Variation in the state taxes creates border differentials in fees. Exploiting these border discontinuities, we identify a robust, positive effect of fees on evasion. Our preferred

Acknowledgments

We would like to thank two anonymous referees and the editor, Fernando Ferreira, for their fruitful comments and suggestions. The paper further benefited from discussions with David Agrawal, Benjamin Bittschi, Ronny Freier, Martin Halla, Nadine Riedel, Johannes Rincke and numerous seminar and workshop participants. The support by Annette Chemnitz and Gabriela Jerome (FIS) and Andreas Marth (WIGeoGIS) is gratefully acknowledged. Any remaining errors are our own.

References (39)

  • BlackS.E.

    Do better schools matter? Parental valuation of elementary education

    Q. J. Econ.

    (1999)
  • CalonicoS. et al.

    Robust nonparametric confidence intervals for regression-discontinuity designs

    Econometrica

    (2014)
  • CameronA.C. et al.

    Bootstrap-based improvements for inference with clustered errors

    Rev. Econ. Stat.

    (2008)
  • ChettyR.

    Is the taxable income elasticity sufficient to calculate deadweight loss? The implications of evasion and avoidance

    Am. Econ. J. Econ. Policy

    (2009)
  • ClotfelterC.T.

    Tax evasion and tax rates: an analysis of individual returns

    Rev. Econ. Stat.

    (1983)
  • DwengerN. et al.

    Extrinsic and intrinsic motivations for tax compliance: evidence from a field experiment in Germany

    Am. Econ. J. Econ. Policy

    (2016)
  • EugsterB. et al.

    Culture and taxes: towards identifying tax competition

    Working Paper

    (2013)
  • FackG. et al.

    The effect of tax enforcement on tax elasticities: evidence from charitable contributions in France

    J. Public Econ.

    (2016)
  • FeinsteinJ.S.

    An econometric analysis of income tax evasion and its detection

    RAND J. Econ.

    (1991)
  • Cited by (20)

    • Earthquake hazard and civic capital

      2023, European Journal of Political Economy
    • The cost of honesty: Field evidence <sup>☆</sup>

      2022, Journal of Behavioral and Experimental Economics
      Citation Excerpt :

      Instead, the findings suggest that material incentives should not be discarded as an important factor to explain dishonest behavior. A relatively modest price increase leads to more dishonesty, which aligns with empirical work from other domains, such as taxation (Berger et al., 2016). However, the results and their implications should be interpreted in the light of the present study’s limitations.

    • Will destination-based taxes be fully exploited when available? An application to the U.S. commodity tax system

      2019, Journal of Public Economics
      Citation Excerpt :

      Instead, if the probability of detection is sufficiently low, it is optimal for municipalities to tax discriminate in favor of residents cross-border shopping in the neighboring municipality by reducing the use tax rate below the sales tax rate which implies that the destination-based use tax will not be fully exploited. The reason is that, in the presence of tax-driven cross-border shopping, reducing the use tax rate below the sales tax rate ultimately reduces tax evasion (see Berger et al., 2016 for a similar argument, in a different context). Thus, the use tax is not exploited to achieve destination-based taxation at the full rate and fight tax avoidance, but rather to reduce tax evasion.

    • The role of civic capital on vaccination

      2023, Health Economics (United Kingdom)
    View all citing articles on Scopus
    View full text