North–south trade in reusable goods: Green design meets illegal shipments of waste

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jeem.2014.10.004Get rights and content

Highlights

  • The pollution haven hypothesis PHH and the level of illegal shipments are examined.

  • With green design, results depend on differences in standards and illegal markets.

  • Stronger regulation in the North may induce firms to reduce reusability.

  • Higher reusability can reduce pollution in the South, contradicting the PHH.

  • Stronger international monitoring may also induce firms to reduce reusability.

Abstract

In a stylized model of international trade, firms in the North indirectly export second-hand products to a representative firm in the South to be reused as intermediate goods, with potential trade gains. The level of reusability of waste products – or green design – is a crucial choice variable in the North. This is because, in the presence of imperfect international monitoring, non-reusable waste can be illegally mixed with reusable waste. I explore the driving forces for illegal waste movement, with a particular focus on local waste regulations such as the EU׳s Directive on Waste Electrical and Electronic Equipment. Under mild conditions, it is shown that increasingly stringent regulations in the North can induce Northern firms to reduce product reusability. Consequently, the flow of non-reusable waste to the South increases, magnifying the pollution haven effect.

Introduction

The scarcity of traditional landfill capacity combined with growing amounts of post-consumer waste has become a major concern for industrialized countries. Accordingly, governments have introduced new regulations, called extended producer responsibility (EPR) regulations, which make producers accountable for waste disposal costs and establish recycling and reuse objectives. The European Union׳s directives on Waste Electrical and Electronic Equipment (WEEE) and End of Life Vehicle (ELV), which entered into force in 2003 and 2000, are examples.

The present paper examines the effect of more stringent EPR regulations, or higher disposal costs, in the presence of an international second-hand goods market. According to the type of contract, the EPR program may or may not foster green design for greater reusability. EPR contracts are detailed in the section “Contracts under extended producer responsibility”. In a North–South model, a representative firm in the South can purchase second-hand products from a firm in the North as intermediate goods. Due to imperfect monitoring, illegal shipments of non-reusable waste are mixed with the exported goods. The model explores the driving forces of illegal waste movement and pollution, with a focus on differences in local disposal costs. The impact of improved international monitoring is also considered.

The wealth gap between industrialized and industrializing economies explains the greater demand in developing countries for many types of e-waste, used vehicles, and recycled materials.1 However, two important sets of regulations govern transboundary waste movement. Both the Basel Convention and the EU regulations restrict waste shipments and disposal. Non-OECD countries often have low-cost, albeit environmentally inadequate, facilities. For instance, exported e-waste often ends up incinerated in open fires, an unsafe practice for both the environment and human health [EEA, 2009]. Under the above-cited international regulations, exporting hazardous waste from OECD to non-OECD countries is prohibited. Note however that under the Basel Convention, the so-called Ban Amendment comes into force on a voluntary basis. Ratification by 17 additional parties is needed for the Amendment to enter into force. Moreover, the US did not ratify the Basel Convention. Consequently, US waste shipments are generally legal.

In order to minimize the cost of complying with EPR programs, firms may undertake both legal and illegal waste shipments. Few numbers exist on the illegal waste shipment. The European Union Network for the Implementation and Enforcement of Environmental Law (IMPEL) had performed several inspection periods between 2008 and 2010. In 21% of the cases, violations were detected [IMPEL, 2011]. These illegal activities take different forms: transporting waste on the black market, mixing different types of waste, or declaring hazardous waste as non-hazardous. This study focuses on yet another illegal practice: classifying waste as second-hand goods. When products are classified as second-hand goods, they are no longer governed by international waste regulations, and can be traded to developing countries. Bads turned into goods constitute an economic incentive for misclassification. For instance, it costs about £5 to recycle a ‘visibly undamaged’ PC monitor in the UK, whereas traders are willing to pay up to £3 on the international market [Czarnomski et al., 2006]. Such misclassifications have been observed for e-waste, used vehicles, used clothes, car tires, and other types of waste,2 and hence testify to imperfect international monitoring.3

The current paper is at the crossroads of the literature on EPR, green design and international trade. The literature on EPR programs has grown substantially in recent years.4 For instance, Fleckinger and Glachant (2010) are concerned with the fact that these programs are designed precisely for producers to fulfill their obligations as they see fit. They examined a duopoly of producers and compared scenarios where producers managed their waste on their own or colluded through a producer responsibility organization.5 They concluded that this type of collusion could lead to suboptimal outcomes, justifying government intervention. Similarly to the current model, some authors have considered the potential impact of EPR on green design. Runkel (2003) studied the influence of four instruments on product durability and welfare. He explored different competitive environments and showed that EPR programs applied under imperfect competition can lead to reduced welfare. Subramanian et al. (2009) underlined the importance of coordination and contracts between producers and consumers for EPR to improve products green design. Other noteworthy contributions on policies for green design include Fullerton and Wu (1998) who showed that the social optimal level of recyclability can be achieved either when consumers pay the social cost of disposal or when the optimal design is subsidized. Eichner and Pethig (2001) studied recyclability as the choice of material, considering material flow and balance through the value chain. In the case of market failure for embodied material per output, they proposed a policy combination of consumption tax and subsidy on material demand. In a dynamic model that includes the recyclability level, Eichner and Runkel (2005) showed how the optimal allocation is obtained through a deposit-refund system.

Few authors have studied the trade in waste and used products. From a theoretical perspective, Copeland (1991) studied international trade in waste disposal services. He found that in the presence of local illegal waste disposal, trade restrictions may improve welfare. Kinnaman and Yokoo (2011) proposed a North–South model of trade in waste reuse. They found that Pareto optimality is reached when the difference in e-waste taxation rates between the two countries is equal to the difference in their respective external marginal cost of e-waste. Empirically, Bond (1983) developed a model based on differences in factor prices and technologies to explain trade in used equipment between firms. Frazer (2008) explained the decline in apparel production in Africa due to used-clothing donations,6 and Clerides (2008) described the gains from trade in used vehicles.

Several works corroborate the pollution haven hypothesis (PHH), which stipulates that larger differences in environmental regulations between two countries induce polluting industries to delocalize where the standards are weak. This is the case of Baggs (2009) and Kellenberg (2012). In particular, Kellenberg found that waste moves toward countries with less stringent regulations.

Results show that in the absence of green-design incentives, a greater difference in environmental standards between the North and South causes a greater flow of waste toward the laxest country. This is predicted by the PHH. When green-design incentives are introduced, the outcomes depend on the sign and amplitude of the incentives, which in turn depend on the initial difference in standards and the presence of an illegal channel. In particular, if there is a small initial difference, then the tightening of the regulations in the North (i.e., the increased difference in standards between the two countries) stimulates green design, reduces illegal shipments, and reduces pollution in the South, thereby contradicting the PHH. This is because the North does not benefit from lower foreign disposal cost and mitigate the rise in local standard by improving reusability. However, the existence of an illegal channel combined with a substantial difference between Northern and Southern local regulations may induce firms in the North to reduce reusability in response to more stringent environmental regulations. This counterintuitive behaviour exacerbates the pollution haven effect. Increased international monitoring leads to similar results, depending on the firms׳ green-design response. The model underscores how more stringent environmental regulations or international monitoring that ignore the impact on green design can have adverse consequences on the environment and illegal shipments.

Section snippets

Contracts under extended producer responsibility

In the model, producers must join a producer responsibility organization (PRO). PROs are non-profit, government-recognized consortia that collect and manage end-of-life products. Member producers are either owners or stockholders of the PROs.7 Decisions on the classification of

The model

The problem is set in a basic model of international trade for a specific industry, e.g. electronic products. New final goods are produced in quantity xN by the representative firm in the North and they are consumed at home. The firm faces a decreasing inverse demand for its new products: pN=βxN,where β stands for the North׳s market size.

Firms in the North are subjected to an EPR program and must join one single PRO, which collect and manage end-of-life products. As a nonprofit organization,

The equilibrium

The profit functions for the firm in the North and South are respectively,10πN=pNxNcN(q)xNNDCwhereNDC=(xNw)dNpwwandw(q+(1q)σ)xN,πS=pSxScS(xS;ρ)(pw+dS)wwherecS(xs;ρ)=xs2/2ρandxSρw.

NDC is

Disposal costs and international monitoring

The following set of results presents what occurs when there is a change in disposal costs or international monitoring. First, the impact of a change in policy on green design is presented. According to equations in (10), i.e. the optimality conditions for the level of reusability, it is straightforward to see that green design varies in the collusion case but remains unchanged in the non-cooperation case. Hence, this section compares the two cases by highlighting the importance of incentives

Discussion

In light of the results, EPR programs must come with appropriate incentives to promote green design since it reduces both illegal shipment and global pollution. In Europe, the first years in the application of the WEEE directive showed the weaknesses of PROs contracts to promote greener design. However, contracts now evolve in that direction with, for instance, the Grenelle law in France, which gives PROs the obligation of creating incentives for better recyclability, reusability and products

Conclusion

This paper considered a North–South model whereby used durable goods in the North are imported by a firm in the South as inputs to production. Imperfect international monitoring allows illegal waste to be mixed with reusable products.

The Pollution Haven Hypothesis (PHH) was examined, with special attention given to the impact of incentives for green design. In the presence of an illegal channel and large differences in local waste regulations between the two countries, it appears that extended

Acknowledgments

Thanks to the editor and two anonymous reviewers for their invaluable comments. Special thanks to Brian Copeland, Louis Hotte, Stan Winer, Hide-Fumi Yokoo, Matthieu Glachant, Titouan Blaize, Arnaud Cerbelaud, and seminar participants at McGill University, 4th Workshop on Game Theory in Energy, Resources and Environment, 44th Annual Conference of the Canadian Economic Association, University Paris 1, CERDI, ENGREF Nancy, and the Toulouse School of Economics. Research partly supported by the FQRSC

References (25)

  • Eric W. Bond

    Trade in used equipment with heterogeneous firms

    J. Polit. Econ.

    (1983)
  • Czarnomski, Sarah, Webb, Barry, and Holmes, Alan, 2006. IMPEL-TFS Threat Assessment Project: The Illegal Shipment of...
  • Cited by (26)

    • Economic policy instruments

      2023, Handbook of Recycling: State-of-the-art for Practitioners, Analysts, and Scientists
    • EKC and carbon footprint of cross-border waste transfer: Evidence from 134 countries

      2021, Ecological Indicators
      Citation Excerpt :

      As a result, increased non-reusable waste export to the developing countries. Developing countries without strict environmental regulations are likely to become new “pollution havens” (Kellenberg, 2012; Bernard, 2015; Qu et al., 2019). Import markets, usually the developing countries, are more sensitive to environmental policies and economic events (Pu et al., 2019).

    • Transboundary inflow of solid waste: Governance and improvement path in China

      2021, Chinese Journal of Population Resources and Environment
      Citation Excerpt :

      Bao and Lang, 2009; Bernard, 2015; Dang and Sheng, 2018; Hacking and Flynn, 2018; Li et al., 2016a; Li et al., 2016b; Liu et al., 2018; Liu et al., 2017; Sander and Schilling, 2010; Shinkuma and Managi, 2010; Wang et al., 2016; Zhang and Zhang, 2020.

    View all citing articles on Scopus
    View full text