Why people reject advantageous offers—Non-monotonic strategies in ultimatum bargaining: Evaluating a video experiment run in PR China

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jebo.2005.10.003Get rights and content

Abstract

Asking responders in ultimatum bargaining for only minimal acceptable offers, implicitly assumes strategies to be monotonic. This assumption seems at odds with actual behavior. We report on a group experiment where 53 percent of the responders state non-monotonic strategies. Content analysis of the video-taped discussions show that social concern, non-expectancy of high offers, emotional, ethical, and moral reasons, group-specific decision rules and aversion against unpleasant numbers are main motives for rejecting advantageous offers. A control experiment with individuals not being observed also displays non-monotonic strategies. Our findings speak to reconsidering assumptions on the parameter space in models of inequity aversion.

Introduction

Experiments on the ultimatum game have shown remarkably stable deviations from purely selfish behavior. In the standard ultimatum game (Güth et al., 1982), a proposer can decide on how to split a given amount of money (the pie) between herself and a responder. The responder can either accept or reject the proposal. In case of acceptance, both receive the amounts as allocated; in case of rejection, both receive nothing.

Numerous symmetric ultimatum game experiments (UG in the following) with zero outside options have shown that individual proposers typically offer 30–50 percent of the pie, with the equal split often being the modal and median offer. Proposers who offer the responders less than 20 percent face rejection with high probability. These findings have been replicated across different subject populations, with different monetary stakes and different experimental procedures (Fehr and Gächter, 2000).

Apparently, responders perceive highly disadvantageous allocations as unfair. In this situation, being treated unfairly corresponds to low payoffs. The monetary and the motivational incentive are not at odds. Thus, rejecting a low offer becomes a likely action.

How do responders behave, however, if confronted with advantageous allocations (i.e. offers higher than 50 percent of the pie)? In this situation, being treated unfairly corresponds to high payoffs. Are unfair yet advantageous offers rejected as well although the monetary and the motivational incentive are in conflict?

In the present paper, we report on a remarkably high number of advantageous offer rejections in a UG video experiment we have been conducting in the People's Republic of China. Here, subjects were observed during decision making. Participants acted together in responder or proposer groups of three people, each being video taped while making their decision.4 Our research agenda requires information on discussions of all potential offers. We therefore modified the standard sequential protocol by using a variant of the strategy method (Selten, 1967) where responders have to state acceptance or rejection for the full strategy space. The combination of the video and the strategy method provides the unique opportunity to learn from participants’ spontaneous discussions about their reasons and motivations for rejecting advantageous offers.

Why is it important to analyze discussions on advantageous offer rejections? For one thing, there is growing experimental evidence on high offer refutations (Bahry and Wilson, 2006, Bellemare et al., 2005, Bolton et al., 2005, Cardenas, 2003, Güth et al., 2003, Henrich et al., 2001, Huck, 1999), yet the literature is far from giving a consistent explanation for such seemingly implausible behavior. Most of the available data allow indirect inferences only, based on observed decisions, participants’ social characteristics, questionnaires, debriefings and conversations, or on analyzing participants’ cultural environment. To the best of our knowledge, no data on high offer rejections is analyzed so far that allow an investigation of subjects’ spontaneous articulations not being mediated by the researcher's personal interpretation.

Our study provides new insights in several respects. First, we found social concern to be the main motivation for refusing advantageous offers. This is in agreement with models of inequity aversion. An inequity averse responder suffers a loss in utility when he is worse off and when he is better off than the proposer (Bolton and Ockenfels, 2000, Fehr and Schmidt, 1999). Second, other motives turn out to be important as well. Among these are beliefs about proposer behavior, in particular non-expectancy of high offers, but also emotional, ethical, and moral reasons, special decision rules employed in some groups and aversion against unpleasant numbers. Finally, the empirical findings on advantageous offer rejections might induce a reconsideration of the assumptions on the parameter space in the models of inequity aversion.

Last but not least, we assessed the robustness of our results as to advantageous offer rejections. To this end, we repeated the experiment with participants that decided individually and were not observed. We found individuals to show the same rejection behavior regarding high offers as groups do. For that reason, the assumption seems justified that motivations revealed during group discussions in the UG pertain to individuals as well.

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, we state our research goals, give a detailed description of the video and strategy method and report the experimental design. Section 3 presents the results. In the final Section 4, we discuss our findings and conclude.

Section snippets

Research questions

Our main research goal is to identify reasons and motivations that might cause subjects to reject advantageous offers. We use content analysis as our research method. Two coders independently assigned segments of the video-taped discussions to categories constructed to capture potential motives for refusing high offers. The frequency of groups articulating a category at least once is taken as the measure of importance for the underlying motive.

Our research might prove important for model

Choices

Results in the standard treatment T1 are in line with individual non-observation UG experiments discussed in the introduction.

Proposers’ mean offer is 41 percent of the pie, and responders on average reject offers lower than 20 percent (Table 2). These numbers are far above the standard game theoretic predictions stated in Section 2. In T2 and T3, average offers and average lowest acceptance levels (LAL, in the following) are higher than predicted, too.

Classification of strategies

Fig. A1 in Appendix A in Supplementary data

Discussion and conclusion

Our study showed that rejecting advantageous offers is quite common in Chinese responder groups. It has been argued that advantageous offers in our video setting are rejected because subjects play in groups, are observed and do not want to appear greedy by accepting the larger part of the pie. There are two major objections against this critique. First, the observation effect can be ruled out if experimental subjects decide individually, are not observed and still reject advantageous offers.

Acknowledgements

We thank Hong Geng, Wei Deng and Ziyin Yan for transcribing the videos as well as for their assistance in text analyzing the transcripts. We are grateful to Heiko A. Schmidt for providing programming assistance. Valuable comments and suggestions that improved the paper substantially were given by the co-editor of this journal and by participants attending the following presentations: 2003 European Meeting of the Economic Science Association, Erfurt, Germany, 2004 Annual Meeting of

References (37)

  • G. Bolton et al.

    A theory of equity, reciprocity and competition

    American Economic Review

    (2000)
  • G. Bolton et al.

    Fair procedures. Evidence from games involving lotteries

    Economic Journal

    (2005)
  • M.H. Bond

    Chinese values

  • G. Bornstein et al.

    Individual and group behavior in the ultimatum game: are groups more rational players?

    Experimental Economics

    (1998)
  • R. Bosman et al.

    Exploring group decision making in a power-to-take experiment

    Experimental Economics

    (2006)
  • J. Brandts et al.

    Hot vs. cold: sequential responses and preference stability in experimental games

    Experimental Economics

    (2000)
  • J. Brosig et al.

    The hot versus cold effect in a simple bargaining experiment

    Experimental Economics

    (2003)
  • J. Brosig et al.

    Bargaining Among Groups: The Role of Pre-play Communication and the Decision Making Design. Working Paper

    (2006)
  • Cited by (61)

    • Pledge-and-review in the laboratory

      2021, Games and Economic Behavior
    • Concerns for future generations in societies: A deliberative analysis of the intergenerational sustainability dilemma

      2021, Journal of Behavioral and Experimental Economics
      Citation Excerpt :

      Specifically, the Nepalese rural lifestyle requires or induces people to consider and behave more toward future generations with regard to their human interactions. As discussed in Hennig-Schmidt et al. (2008), Carpenter and Seki (2011) and Fehr and Leibbrandt (2011), we conjecture that such daily life practices and cultures among rural people reflect the experimental results, even if choosing B goes against their immediate benefit. As demonstrated in the Chi-squared test, a clear difference between rural and urban areas is shown in the histograms for concepts 1 to 7, which are associated with arguments for not considering future generations (compare to the two histograms in Fig. 3).

    View all citing articles on Scopus
    1

    Tel.: +86 28 5417673; fax: +86 28 5417673.

    2

    Tel.: +49 228 73 9195; fax: +49 228 73 9193.

    3

    URL: www.bonneconlab.uni-bonn.de.

    View full text