The pattern of growth and poverty reduction in China

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jce.2009.10.005Get rights and content

Abstract

China’s rapid economic growth has been the proximate cause of the huge reduction in the incidence of poverty since 1980. Yet, the growth process has been highly uneven across sectors and regions. We test whether the pattern of China’s growth mattered to poverty reduction using a new provincial panel data set constructed for this purpose. Our econometric tests support the view that the primary sector (mainly agriculture) has been the main driving force in poverty reduction. We note a number of similarities, and differences, with India.

Introduction

Based on cross-country comparisons, a number of papers in the literature have found that measures of absolute poverty tend to fall with economic growth.1 However, it is also evident that there is a sizeable variance in the impacts of a given rate of growth on poverty. Some of this is measurement error, but it has also been argued that there are systematic factors influencing the elasticity of poverty measures to higher mean income.

Probably the main reason advanced in the literature and in policy discussions as to why a given rate of growth can deliver diverse outcomes for poor people is that the “pattern of growth” matters independently of the overall rate of growth. We can state this hypothesis in slightly more formal terms as follows:

Pattern of growth hypothesis (PGH): The sectoral and/or geographic composition of economic activity affects the aggregate rate of poverty reduction independently of the aggregate rate of growth.

If true, then the often-heard claim that the policies that are good for growth are necessarily also good for poverty reduction becomes questionable, given that the actions needed for growth in one sector or place need not accord with those needed elsewhere. This is particularly salient to the role of agricultural growth, which is likely to require rather different policies to other sectors (Headey, 2008).

In principle one can think of two reasons why PGH might hold. The first is that the relevant between-group component of inequality is sufficiently large that the pattern of growth across those groups systematically alters the distribution of income and (hence) the extent of poverty at any given mean income. Intuitively, if economic growth is very intense in sectors that do not benefit poor people then inequality will rise, choking off the gains to the poor from growth.

The second reason is that the composition of economic activity is one factor influencing the initial level of inequality. This holds even if the subsequent growth process is distribution-neutral (all incomes grow at the same rate). Intuitively, when the poor have a low initial share of total income they will tend to have a lower share of the gains in aggregate income during the growth process. Empirically, the initial distribution of income is known to be important for the subsequent effect of economic growth on poverty (Ravallion, 1997, Bourguignon, 2003).

In the context of India, Ravallion and Datt, 1996, Ravallion and Datt, 2002 and Datt and Ravallion (2002) report results indicating that the sectoral and geographic composition of growth has mattered to aggregate poverty reduction. Rural economic growth has had more impact on poverty in India than urban economic growth, and growth in the tertiary (mainly services) sector has had more impact than the primary (mainly agriculture) sector, while the secondary (mainly manufacturing) sector appears to have brought little direct gain to India’s poor. Empirical support for the PGH has also come from cross-country evidence suggesting that more labor-intensive growth processes have greater impact on poverty, as found by Loayza and Raddatz (forthcoming).

However, all this sits uneasily with the observation that the country that has undoubtedly made the most impressive progress against absolute poverty over recent decades has also had one of the most sectorally and geographically unbalanced growth processes. We refer to China. While the impressive growth performance of China since the early 1980s is well known, there has been much concern in recent times that this growth process has been “unbalanced,” and in particular that growth rates in agriculture have appreciably lagged those in other sectors, notably industry and services (Kuijs and Wang, 2006, Chaudhuri and Ravallion, 2006). The primary sector’s share fell from 30% in 1980 to 15% in 2001, though not montonically. Yet China’s record against absolute poverty has been impressive. Using their national poverty line, Ravallion and Chen (2007) found that the poverty rate (headcount index) fell from 53% in 1981 to 8% in 2001. Using decomposition methods, the same authors found that about three-quarters of this reduction in poverty nationally was due to poverty reduction solely within rural areas.

These observations motivate the main questions addressed by this paper: What role did the apparent “imbalances” of China’s growth process play in China’s progress against poverty? Would a more balanced growth process have had a larger impact on poverty? Or could it be that the unbalanced growth actually fostered poverty reduction, by allowing a higher overall growth rate?

There is already evidence in the literature to suggest that China’s rate of poverty reduction would have been even higher if not for the pattern of growth. Using aggregate (national level) time series data for China, Ravallion and Chen (2007) find evidence that the sectoral composition of growth (how much comes from agriculture versus manufacturing versus services) matters to both poverty and inequality independently of the rate of growth. If the same rate of growth had been possible without the sectoral imbalances observed then the Ravallion and Chen results suggest that it would have taken half the time to achieve the reduction in poverty observed over 1981–2001.

This type of calculation assumes that the same overall rate of growth would have been possible without the sectoral imbalances. In principle, that is a strong assumption. However, it is not as strong as one might guess in the China context. The sectoral imbalance in China’s growth process is in part the result of deliberate policies on the part of the government. A number of specific policy instruments were used for this purpose, including2:

  • subsidized prices for key inputs (including energy, utilities and land), weak or weakly enforced regulations (including environmental protection);

  • favoured treatment for industry in access to finance, especially for large (private and state-owned) enterprises;

  • restrictions on labor movement through the Hukou system and discriminatory regulations against migrant workers in cities; and

  • local administrative allocation of land, with the effect that out migrants from rural areas face a high likelihood that they will lose their agricultural land rights.3

Given that the sectoral pattern of growth was far from being a wholly market-driven process, it would clearly be hazardous to assume that the specific pattern of growth was efficient and (hence) promoted the maximum overall rate of growth. Ravallion and Chen (2007) address this issue empirically, and argue that the national-level data do not provide compelling evidence for believing that lower growth rates in the primary sector were the “price” of higher growth in the secondary and tertiary sectors.

The main contribution of the present paper is to assess the contribution to poverty reduction of the sectoral and geographic pattern of China’s growth, by extending the Ravallion–Chen analysis to the provincial level. By adding the extra variability in the geographic (inter-provincial) dimension we are able to enhance the power of the various tests of the PGH that we undertake—enhancing the scope for identification and precision of the estimates over past studies. By allowing us to introduce a latent provincial effect in the error term, our provincial panel-data analysis also addresses concerns about omitted variables. Additionally, the common origin and methodology of the primary data make this empirical exercise more immune to the comparability problems facing cross-country studies.4

In addition to testing whether the pattern of growth has mattered to poverty reduction, we aim to assess how quantitatively important the pattern of growth has been to China’s (very high) overall rate of poverty reduction. We may not reject the PGH, but find that the effect is small. Or we might find that far larger reductions in poverty could have been possible if the same growth rate was more even across sectors and areas. We investigate this issue more deeply using the sub-national data, and also see if there is any evidence of a significant trade-off between the overall growth rate and its sectoral composition.

We shall also make a number of observations comparing China with India in terms of the relevance of the pattern of growth to poverty reduction. The fact that a similar study was already conducted at the provincial level for the case of India by Ravallion and Datt (2002) allows us to compare the results of China and India.

The following section describes the trends in poverty reduction across China’s provinces that we find in the data. Section 3 examines the role played by the sectoral composition of growth, and Section 4 extends this analysis to allow for differing parameters across provinces. Section 5 uses counterfactual analysis to quantify the importance of the pattern of growth to poverty reduction. Section 6 concludes.

Section snippets

Provincial poverty trends

While the reduction of poverty in China has been dramatic during the last twenty-five years, it has also been quite uneven in both the temporal and the spatial dimensions (Ravallion and Chen, 2007). Table 1 shows the trend rates of poverty reduction, measured using the headcount index of poverty (H), by province

The role played by the sectoral pattern of growth

We now examine to what extent the diverse trends in China’s progress against poverty revealed by the results of the previous section are explicable in terms of the sectoral pattern of economic growth. We use the standard classification of the origins of GDP, namely “primary” (mainly agriculture), “secondary” (manufacturing and construction) and “tertiary” (services and trade). We let these three sectors “compete” in explaining the variance in poverty measures over time and across provinces.

Allowing for different parameters across provinces

The various tests on provincial data reported in the last section confirm the finding of Ravallion and Chen (2007) on national-level data that it is the primary sector that has been the main driving force of China’s poverty reduction, rather than the secondary or tertiary sectors. However, in the previous section we only considered regressions with constant elasticities across provinces for each sector. As we argued before, and was shown by Ravallion and Datt (2002) for the case of the states

Counterfactual analysis

We now consider the evolution of rural poverty in China under alternative counterfactual scenarios, which are designed to quantify the contribution of the pattern of growth to overall poverty reduction. We focus on rural poverty and we continue using the sub-sample excluding the municipalities (Beijing, Tianjin, Shanghai, Chongqing) and Tibet. The reason why we dropped the municipalities is the problematic, and changing, definition of rural areas in those provinces (and therefore the poverty of

Conclusions

A long-standing development policy debate has concerned the priority to be given to agriculture versus industrialization or an expanding services sector as the routes out of poverty. We have studied the experience of the country that has almost certainly had the greatest success in reducing poverty in modern times, China. A newly constructed sub-national panel data set offers a powerful lens on the role played by the geographic and sectoral pattern of growth in China’s progress against poverty.

Acknowledgments

The authors are grateful to Shaohua Chen and the staff of China’s National and Provincial Bureaus of Statistics for their invaluable help in assembling the data base we use in this paper. Montalvo also acknowledges the financial support of Project SEJ2007-64340 and the Fellowship ICREA Academia for Excellence in Research funded by the Generalitat de Catalunya. These are the views of the authors and should not be attributed to their employers, including the World Bank or any affiliated

References (21)

  • Dirk Bezemer et al.

    Agriculture, development and urban bias

    World Development

    (2008)
  • Francois Bourguignon

    The growth elasticity of poverty reduction: explaining heterogeneity across countries and time-periods

  • Shubham Chaudhuri et al.

    Partially awakened giants: uneven growth in China and India

  • Gaurav Datt et al.

    Has India’s post-reform economic growth left the poor behind

    Journal of Economic Perspectives

    (2002)
  • Gary S. Fields

    Distribution and Development

    (2001)
  • Derek D. Headey

    National policies and the sectoral pattern of economic growth

    Agricultural Economics

    (2008)
  • Louis Kuijs et al.

    China’s pattern of growth: moving to sustainability and reducing inequality

    China and the World Economy

    (2006)
  • Aart Kraay

    When is growth pro-poor? Evidence from a panel of countries

    Journal of Development Economics

    (2006)
  • Loayza, Norman, Raddatz, Claudio, forthcoming. The composition of growth matters for poverty alleviation. Journal of...
  • Martin Ravallion

    Growth and poverty: evidence for developing countries in the 1980s

    Economics Letters

    (1995)
There are more references available in the full text version of this article.

Cited by (141)

  • Anti-corruption and poverty alleviation: Evidence from China

    2022, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization
View all citing articles on Scopus
View full text