Elsevier

Forest Policy and Economics

Volume 104, July 2019, Pages 146-156
Forest Policy and Economics

Afforestation as a real option with joint production of environmental services

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.forpol.2019.04.015Get rights and content

Highlights

  • Many land use decisions are irreversible and involve uncertainty.

  • Often ecosystem services are jointly produced.

  • We extend real option decision models to handle two additive ecosystem services.

  • Values of ecosystem services from afforestation are uncertain and may be correlated.

  • Joint production increases the value of conversion and incentives to afforest.

Abstract

Real option applications in conservation have showed that with irreversibility and uncertainty about the value of preservation decisions may change. More specifically, returns must be high enough to also pay out the value of waiting if conversion into more intensive land uses is to become optimal. However, many environmental policies today focus on nature restoration, where conversion has previously taken place. In this study, we therefore reverse the problem and ask when to afforest productive agricultural land, when we face uncertainty about the value of ecosystem services delivered by afforestation. Furthermore, projects such as afforestation are often associated with joint production of forest products and environmental goods, like biodiversity, hunting, groundwater production, carbon storage, recreation etc. Thus, we extend state-of-the-art models to handle two additive ecosystem services, which both are uncertain and may be correlated. The joint production aspect increases the value of conversion, the stopping value, and hence the incentives to afforest. Increasing uncertainty decreases this incentive, as expected. However, contrary to the existing literature evaluating exclusive options, less than perfect correlation between the values of future ecosystem services decreases the value of the real option and increases the set of states, where afforestation is the preferred decision. This causes afforestation to be attractive for a wider set of states of the world than otherwise and has implications where joint production is feasible. We discuss these findings and the potential application of this analysis for handling real options with joint production in other research domains.

Introduction

Around the world, many governments and non-governmental organisations have been engaged in afforesting agricultural and wasteland or reforesting harvested forest stands. There are many reasons for implementing policies, which promote this land use conversion. A range of socioeconomic benefits are expected from afforestation, for example afforestation may result in higher recreational benefits, reduce erosion and desertification problems, protect groundwater, create a supply of fuel wood and timber and contribute to carbon storing and climate change mitigation. The global investments are significant. More than 14 million hectares are annually afforested and reforested (FAO, 2015). To initiate such investment, decision makers at any level from governments to landowners, need to evaluate whether the afforestation is a financially more attractive investment than other land use alternatives. In particular when the investment is subject to great uncertainty about future costs and benefits, irreversibility in the sense of not being able to fully recover investments, and the benefits may be multiple and jointly produced (Nelson et al., 2009). This study discusses and analyses this problem of deciding for what states of nature to invest in afforestation when the values of ecosystem services from forests are stochastic and jointly produced. We analysed this in the context of real option theory and add to the research field by applying a new framework of additive real options. Our focus is in a sense the reverse of earlier studies, focused on when to intensify land use and halt conservation (e.g. Conrad, 1997; Kassar and Lasserre, 2004), as we here focus on reducing land use intensity, switching land use from agriculture to forest.

Even newly established afforestation areas quickly provide a wide range of ecosystem services such as recreation or increased quality of drinking water production (Vesterdal et al., 2002; Zandersen et al., 2007), and increasing the forest area on a property may increase hunting values (Meilby et al., 2006; Lundhede et al., 2015). Other services from afforestation may only happen in the long term, e.g. reaching a suitable habitat for important biodiversity (Hermy and Verheyen, 2007) or significant returns from timber harvest. In valuing such outputs/services of multifunctional forestry, it is important to account for the joint production of services. The joint production properties may fall into categories of fixed, complementarity, independency, and competitive relationships between the services (Randall, 2002). Ignoring these properties, any attempt to value the services provided by forest reserves may fail and inappropriate information may flow into relevant decision processes. The Sustainable Development Goals and the 2030 agenda highlight sustainable use of terrestrial ecosystems and management of forests. The EU Commission has acceded to major international declarations, recommendations, treaties or conventions of immediate relevance to sustainable forest and nature management, e.g. the EU Forest Action Plan and the Strategy of Lisbon‘s environmental pillar, the Convention on Biological Diversity, and has strongly supported the promotion of forest management through its programmes. The EU and EU member countries annually spend billions of euros on contributing to development of sustainable forest and nature management to halt the decline of biodiversity and promote the provision of ecosystem services (e.g. see the EU Natura 2000). The Millennium Ecosystem Assessment of nature's contributions to human well-being (Braat and de Groot, 2012; Carpenter et al., 2006; Pascual et al., 2017; TEEB, 2010) as well as the climate change debate and discussion on the potential roles of forests have increased the research community interest in several issues. Topics include the role of spatial correlation, spatial connection/dis-connection, and potential joint production of provisional services (e.g. forest and agricultural production, drinking water), regulatory services (e.g. carbon, nutrient cycling, biodiversity) or cultural services (e.g. hunting, recreation) and potential for win-win solutions and spin-offs of conservation and restoration projects (Bateman et al., 2013; Carpenter et al., 2006; Nelson et al., 2009; Venter et al., 2009).

From society's point of view as well as the private land owner's perspective, it is therefore an issue that the value of these possible effects and correlations are not well known. Nor are the quantitative measures of their provision. Consequently, the values associated with afforestation areas are uncertain. The expected value of e.g. future biodiversity may increase as society grows richer (Jacobsen and Hanley, 2009), as may marketed recreational services like hunting (Lundhede et al., 2015; Meilby et al., 2006). The supply of resources may become increasingly scarce (Schroter et al., 2005). On the other hand, the perceived and expected future value of a specific afforestation areas' value may also decline. An example is if e.g. biophysical limits to growth cause demand from non-consumptive benefits to decrease relative to consumptive goods. Or if changes in surrounding land use decrease the quality and value of ecosystem services provided from the afforestation area. At the same time, the afforestation investment may be seen as irreversible. Converting back to agriculture likely implies a larger cost of removing tree stumps and re-establishing the agricultural field, the more time has passed. As time passes the trees grow valuable which reduce net cost of conversion back to agriculture. However, in many instances legislation may prohibit such conversion. Thus, setting aside agricultural land for afforestation may be seen as a decision problem of when to exercise the option of not only one, but the sum of several jointly produced ecosystem services. The value of which is governed by possibly correlated stochastic processes. Here we address this problem applying two additive real options as an example, recreational hunting and forest products.

The use of real option value models and the timing of (dis-)investment decisions have been investigated in resource economics, building on e.g. McDonald and Siegel (1986) and picking up speed with Dixit and Pindyck (1994). Specifically concerning the issues of different option values and preservation, Arrow and Fisher (1974) and Henry (1974) pointed out the (quasi-) option value related to continued preservation (as opposed to development) of a resource when benefits from development are uncertain. As already mentioned, the problem we analysed here is the reverse one of earlier studies focused on when to intensify land use and halt conservation (e.g. Conrad, 1997; Kassar and Lasserre, 2004). Furthermore, the explicit attention to the joint and additive values being produced following afforestation is a novel contribution to the real option analysis in resource economics. The extension to multiple services is highly relevant, but it comes at the expense of the mathematical tractability of analysing the decision problem. We had to resort, as is often the case in such problems, to numerical solution procedures to solve explicitly defined examples.

Section snippets

State of the art

The first real-option related studies within natural resource economics were the seminal papers by Henry (1974) and Arrow and Fisher (1974), which showed in simple two period models, that with uncertain returns to irreversible development, preservation would be optimal over a larger range of expected values of development.

A different strand of work on the valuation of forest resources and exercise timing under uncertainty, which is essentially also real option problems, was developed in e.g.

The model

We developed a general model for the case where a decision maker holds the option to put down a known fixed one-off payment and in turn receive the sum of two present value processes. In the afforestation context, this has relevance. Consider for example the landowner, who faces the problem of continuing with the present agricultural system, assuming it is generating a constant return of F per unit of time to society or has the option to invest I in an afforestation project. The project will

Numerical solution procedure

Based on Malchow-Møller et al. (2004) we assumed that the value function was finite as long as δ >  max {μB + μG} (McDonald and Siegel, 1986) and the problem could be solved using a value-function iteration procedure (Judd, 1998). To increase stability and iteration speed, the problem was log-normalised, which implied the variance became independent of the state, thereby standardising the calculation of the joint probability distribution. When presenting the results we converted the estimated

Empirical example of two additive ecosystem services: timber production and recreational hunting

Real options of joint production is a generic topic, and the output of our analyses covered a realistic range of possible relative states of values B and G and costs I. As such they are illustrative of the generic aspects of the decision problem. However, for further illustrative purposes, we also evaluated the question using the case of afforestation of agricultural land with jointly produced ecosystem services. We used time series data from Denmark on timber and recreational hunting to derive

Results

We started by analysing the basic properties of the decision problem and the implications of changing parameter settings on the stopping boundaries. Subsequently we estimated the optimal stopping values of the empirical case.

Concluding discussion

The current study addresses the importance of including investment theory and in particular, the implications of uncertainty of the future value of the ecosystem services when the services may rather be jointly produced than mutually exclusive. In addition, the modelling should acknowledge that a decision maker may hesitate to invest in forest and nature restoration or conservation since such decisions may be irreversible (one example is the European Natura 2000 network of set a side areas,

Acknowledgements

The authors thank the Danish National Research Foundation (grant no. DNRF96) for supporting the research at the Center for Macroecology, Evolution and Climate. The authors also thank two anonymous reviewers for their comments on earlier versions of the manuscript.

References (71)

  • T.H. Lundhede et al.

    A hedonic analysis of the complex hunting experience

    J. For. Econ.

    (2015)
  • L.M. Madsen

    The Danish afforestation programme and spatial planning: new challenges

    Landsc. Urban Plan.

    (2002)
  • N. Malchow-Moller et al.

    Repeated real options: optimal investment behaviour and a good rule of thumb

    J. Econ. Dyn. Control.

    (2006)
  • N. Malchow-Møller et al.

    Real-options aspects of adjacency constraints

    For. Policy Econ.

    (2004)
  • H. Meilby et al.

    Optimal spatial harvest planning under risk of windthrow

    For. Ecol. Manag.

    (2001)
  • U. Pascual et al.

    Valuing nature's contributions to people: the IPBES approach

    Curr. Opin. Environ. Sustain.

    (2017)
  • W.J. Reed

    The effects of the risk of fire on the optimal rotation of a forest

    J. Environ. Econ. Manag.

    (1984)
  • W.J. Reed

    The decision to conserve or harvest old-growth forest

    Ecol. Econ.

    (1993)
  • J.D.M. Saphores et al.

    Managing exotic pests under uncertainty: optimal control actions and bioeconomic investigations

    Ecol. Econ.

    (2005)
  • L. Vesterdal et al.

    Change in soil organic carbon following afforestation of former arable land

    For. Ecol. Manag.

    (2002)
  • F. Wirl

    Consequences of irreversibilities on optimal intertemporal CO2 emission policies under uncertainty

    Resour. Energy Econ.

    (2006)
  • D. Yemshanov et al.

    A real options-net present value approach to assessing land use change: a case study of afforestation in Canada

    For. Policy Econ.

    (2015)
  • M. Zandersen et al.

    Evaluating approaches to predict recreation values of new forest sites

    J. For. Econ.

    (2007)
  • J. Abildtrup et al.

    Groundwater protection and forest management - an option value analysis

  • K.J. Arrow et al.

    Environmental preservation, uncertainty, and irreversibility

    Q. J. Econ.

    (1974)
  • I.J. Bateman et al.

    Bringing ecosystem services into economic decision-making: land use in the United Kingdom

    Science

    (2013)
  • E.M. Bennett et al.

    Understanding relationships among multiple ecosystem services

    Ecol. Lett.

    (2009)
  • European Commission

    Natura 2000 - Protecting Europe's biodiversity. European Commission, Directorate General for the Environment. [WWW Document], URL

  • European Commission

    Financing Natura 2000. European Commission. Directorate Generale of the Environment [Web-Document], URL

  • J.A. Bloczynski et al.

    Irreversible investment in wetlands preservation: optimal ecosystem restoration under uncertainty

    Environ. Manag.

    (2000)
  • R. Brazee et al.

    Timber harvesting with fluctuating prices

    For. Sci.

    (1988)
  • S.R. Carpenter et al.

    Millennium ecosystem assessment: research needs

    Science

    (2006)
  • S.R. Carpenter et al.

    Science for managing ecosystem services: beyond the millennium ecosystem assessment

    Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. U. S. A.

    (2009)
  • M. Chesney et al.

    Market uncertainty and risk transfer in REDD projects

    J. Sustain. For.

    (2017)
  • H.R. Clarke et al.

    The tree-cutting problem in a stochastic environment

    J. Econ. Dyn. Control.

    (1989)
  • Cited by (11)

    • Flexible conservation decisions for climate adaptation

      2022, One Earth
      Citation Excerpt :

      Real options analysis quantifies the value (the option value) of holding the right to or ability to make a decision in the future, often once uncertainty has been reduced or resolved.82 Real options analysis has been applied to conservation problems in similar ways to assess the optimal timing of the investment of conservation budgets under uncertainty.83–85 Conservation finance plays an important role in operationalizing this type of flexibility.78

    • Identifying the potential areas of afforestation projects using cost-benefit analysis based on ecosystem services and farmland suitability: A case study of the Grain for Green Project in Jinan, China

      2021, Science of the Total Environment
      Citation Excerpt :

      Problems, including soil erosion, flood, desertification, and biodiversity loss, not only cause economic losses but also threaten human safety and health (Fu et al., 2011). As one of the most effective strategies of ecological restoration, afforestation has been widely implemented all over the world (Deng et al., 2017; Strange et al., 2019), including the Grain for Green Project in China, the One Billion Trees Programme in New Zealand, the Conservation Reserve Programme in the USA, and the National Forest Programme of Denmark. In practice, the implementation of afforestation is limited in certain areas due to the demands for diverse land use types and the limitations on the economic investment for afforestation.

    View all citing articles on Scopus
    View full text