Elsevier

Ecological Economics

Volume 52, Issue 3, 15 February 2005, Pages 383-396
Ecological Economics

The bioeconomics of tritrophic systems: applications to invasive species

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2004.05.007Get rights and content

Abstract

Adapted species in nature are assumed to have solved renewable resource management problems, and this is examined here using a physiologically based model of energy acquisition and allocation. Newly established invasive species are merely in an early phase of this process in their new environment. Analogies between the economies of humans and other species are used to develop an objective function for individual utility of energy allocation. The objective function includes the physiologically based population dynamics models of the consumer and resource species in a food chain as constraints. The model applies to all trophic levels in a food chain including human harvesting of renewable resources (see also Regev et al. (Regev, U., Gutierrez, A.P., Schreiber, S., Zilberman, D., 1998. Biological and Economic Foundation of Renewable Resource Exploitation. Ecological Economics. 26 (3), 227-242.)).

Specifically, the analysis:

  • (1)

    Attempts to combine ecological and economic theory;

  • (2)

    Points out the importance of time frame in the two economies (evolutionary vs. market time);

  • (3)

    Examines the effects of expected uncertainty due to environmental hazards in defining energy acquisition and allocation strategies in two invasive aphid species at the extremes of so called r- and K-strategies and the well adapted Central American cotton–cotton bollweevil system;

  • (4)

    Evaluates the effects of changes in behavioral and physiological parameters and environmental degradation on the abundance of resource and consumer species.

Introduction

Unlike humans, species in nature solve sustainable renewable resource management problems through the process of natural selection. We examine how this is done showing how the economies of plants and animals differ from that of humankind. Analogies between the two economies are used to develop an objective function “maximizing” individual utility of energy allocation in organisms. The use of economic analogies in ecology and vice-versa is not new (Ghiselin, 1995), nor has it been free of controversy (Rapport, 1991).

The comparative approach outlined here to examine interactions in a food chain is based on standard economic and ecological theory, but our approach differs from prior studies on optimal allocation of resources reviewed by Perrin and Sibley (1993), optimal foraging theory reviewed and criticized by Rapport (1991), and studies based on the theory of ecologically stable strategies (ESS). Unlike prior models of renewable resource management, the objective function in our model includes the physiologically based population dynamics models of the consumer and resource species as constraints. The model applies to all trophic levels in a food chain including human harvesting of renewable resource species. Regev et al. (1998) explored this latter topic and that paper should be considered dual to this one1.

The underlying assumption of our model is that in adapted species, the observed phenotypes (including behavior and physiology) are the product of natural selection (Darwin, 1858), and hence, the strategies and the genes that code for them have survival value (sensu Dawkins, 1995). We note that selection has not been directed as the observed phenotypes carry the genetic burden of prior history of what worked (Gould, 1986). Furthermore, we cannot, except on rare occasions, see the survival value of a specific bit of DNA, rather we can only observe what phenotype organisms do, estimate the costs of the strategy they adopt and examine via models what would happen if they did something different. We make no argument that individual organisms choose optimal strategies despite the fact that we use optimization methods to understand the dynamics. Rather we assume at the start that the evolved strategy reflects an optimization strategy that is on average flexible enough to meet the expected variation in their biotic and abiotic environment (e.g., Gutierrez and Regev, 1983). Established invasive species may be viewed as being in transition toward adaptedness in their new environment, noting that most invasions fail.

All organisms, including plants and humans, are consumers (i.e., predators in a general sense), and all have the same problems of resource acquisition and allocation in priority order to egestion, conversion costs, respiration, reproduction and growth (including reserves). The economic analogies are respectively wastages, cost of doing business, costs of converting the raw material to a product, profit and firm growth (see Regev et al., 1998 for economic analogies). Energy fixed by plants during photo- (or chemosynthesis) passes up the trophic chain (web) to higher trophic levels as a more complete food. In our primal state, humans differed little from other animal species being both prey and predator. Over time there arose an innovative remnant (cf., Winters, 1971) that led to modern humans that enabled us to become the top predator in the food chain and to escape regulation of our numbers by natural enemies. As modern economies developed, harvests of renewable resources came to be valued by price, but despite this the acquisition and allocation of revenues have analogies to the acquisition and allocation of energy by organisms in nature (Fig. 1, cf., Gutierrez and Curry, 1989). Important analogies between ecology and economics were proposed by Winters (1971), Gutierrez and Regev (1983), Perrin and Sibley (1993), Regev et al. (1998), others and here, and hence the same economics model applies to both systems.

Section snippets

Analogies between the economies of nature and humans

The biosphere is comprised of all of the global ecosystems and is akin to the global economy with its many economies with some in each group interacting more than others. The link between the two occurs when humans harvest from or disrupt natural ecosystems. Viewed from this perspective, an ecosystem is analogous to a human economic system (capitalist, socialist, etc.), with the biophysical properties of the ecosystem defining the possible economies of species that comprise its biota. A species

Discussion

The influence of economic thinking on evolutionary and ecological theory has a long history, and ran through some of Darwin's writings (Ghiselin, 1995) and may have influenced his ideas on evolution—especially the notion of progress (i.e., change). Dawkins, 1976, Dawkins, 1995 argues that the genes that constitute the phenological representation of adapted individuals (and in the aggregate of the population and of the species) have solved the resource acquisition and allocation problem in a way

Acknowledgements

We wish to thank Sebastian Schrieber and David Zilberman for their help in formulating the economic portion of this problem.

References (48)

  • J.H. Brown et al.

    Evolution of body size: consequences of an energetic definition of fitness

    Am. Nat.

    (1995)
  • E.L. Charnov et al.

    A trade-off-invariant life-history rule for optimal offspring size

    Nature

    (1995)
  • C. Darwin

    Origin Of Species

    (1858)
  • Richard Dawkins

    The Selfish Gene

    (1976)
  • Richard Dawkins

    God's utility function

    Sci. Am.

    (1995)
  • L.A. Falcon et al.

    Investigation of the pest status of Lygus hesperus in cotton in Central California

    J. Econ. Entomol.

    (1971)
  • J.O. Farlow

    A consideration of the trophic dynamics of a late Cretaceous large-dinosaur community (Oldman Formation)

    Ecology

    (1976)
  • David Finnoff et al.

    Protecting an endangered species while harvesting its prey in a general equilibrium ecosystem model

    Land Econ.

    (2003)
  • R.A. Fisher

    The Genetical Theory of Natural Selection

    (1930)
  • M.T. Ghiselin

    Perspective: Darwin, progress, and economic principles

    Evolution

    (1995)
  • N.E. Gilbert et al.

    Ecological relationships

    (1976)
  • S.J. Gould

    Evolution and the triumph of homologies or why history matters

    Am. Sci.

    (1986)
  • A.P. Gutierrez

    The physiological basis of ratio dependent theory

    Ecology

    (1992)
  • A.P. Gutierrez

    Applied Population Ecology: A Supply–Demand Approach

    (1996)
  • Cited by (32)

    • A coffee agroecosystem model: III. Parasitoids of the coffee berry borer (Hypothenemus hampei)

      2017, Ecological Modelling
      Citation Excerpt :

      Whatever strategy a species evolves, it must assure its continuity in time, and hence its traits must assure “adaptedness” to the biotic and abiotic conditions to minimize the likelihood of extinction (sensu Ayala, 1969). Further, Gutierrez and Regev (1983, 2005) proposed that evolved strategies may have little to do with maximizing the commonness of the species in the environments. Rather, adapted individuals and the species they comprise must via their genetics, take a long-term view of their resource management problem, and that tradeoffs are based on sufficiency or constrained optimization behavior rather than maximization rules.

    • Economic drivers of biological invasions: A worldwide, bio-geographic analysis

      2014, Ecological Economics
      Citation Excerpt :

      If there is a long history of studies on biological invasions in the natural sciences, with classical works dating back to the 1950s (e.g. Elton, 1958), economics has begun devoting attention to the issue in the last decade, after international scientific and policy-oriented initiatives (such as the Global Invasive Species Programme, sponsored by the United Nations and major international environmental organizations) called for the inclusion of an economic perspective on the driving forces and on the policy options. The corpus of economic analyses is now relatively rich, comprising studies on the valuation of economic costs (e.g. Adams and Lee, 2007; Born et al., 2005; Horsch and Lewis, 2009; McIntosh et al., 2007; Pimentel et al., 2005; Sinden et al., 2011; Turpie and Heydenrych, 2000), on the economic determinants (Costello et al., 2007; Essl et al., 2011; Hlasny and Livingston, 2008; Pyšek et al., 2010a,b; Westphal et al., 2008), on decision-making and policy strategies (Batabyal, 2006; Costello et al., 2007; Eiswerth and Johnson, 2002; Finnoff et al., 2005; Horan and Lupi, 2005; Leung et al., 2005; Liu et al., 2011; Margolis and Shogren, 2012; Margolis et al., 2005; Mehta et al., 2007; Mérel and Carter, 2008; Olson and Roy, 2010; Perrings, 2005; Rout et al., 2011; Sanchirico et al., 2010; Shogren, 2000; Shuang et al., 2011, among others), and on bioeconomic models that examine the influence of specific traits of invading species on their chances of establishing and on the optimal prevention and management options (Finnoff and Tschirhart, 2005; Finnoff et al., 2010; Gutierrez and Regev, 2005; Haight and Polasky, 2010; Marten and Moore, 2011; Rauscher and Barbier, 2010). A complete survey of the economic literature on biological invasions — a hint on its dimensions being offered by the about 140 Econlit entries between 2000 and today — is beyond the scope of this paper.2

    • Managing excessive predation in a predator-endangered prey setting

      2013, Ecological Economics
      Citation Excerpt :

      These results highlight the importance of the set of available controls. Our management problem has analogies to the regulation of open access harvesting if one views predators as akin to human harvesters (e.g. Gutierrez and Regev, 2005; Regev et al., 1998). Indeed, predation occurs without consideration of the ecological and economic impacts on future prey levels.

    • Control and the management of a spreading invader

      2010, Resource and Energy Economics
    View all citing articles on Scopus
    View full text