A non-possibility theorem for joint stability in interindustry models

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.amc.2012.10.042Get rights and content

Abstract

Joint-stability in interindustry modeling relates to the mutual simultaneous consistency of the demand-driven and supply-driven models of Leontief and Ghosh, respectively. Previous work has claimed joint-stability to be an acceptable assumption from the empirical viewpoint, provided only small changes in exogenous variables are considered. We show in this note, however, that the issue has deeper theoretical roots, offering a mathematical demonstration that shows the impossibility of mutual consistency between demand-driven and supply-driven models. Mutual consistency would entail that coefficient matrices under both model versions would remain constant when the economic equilibrium changes following an external shock.

Introduction

Interindustry models are essentially of two types. The demand-driven model of Leontief [1] takes final demand as external with gross outputs and primary factors use responding to accommodate demand while keeping the demand-supply balance in check. In contrast, Ghosh [2] takes primary factors as external whereas gross inputs and final demand adjust to the availability of primary factors in production. Clearly, these two models emphasize different driving forces while attempting to determine total activity levels in both cases. In the Leontief version, activity levels refer to total or gross outputs, as seen from the use perspective. In Ghosh, they refer to total inputs, or the resource perspective. We know from basic National Accounting rules that gross outputs and gross inputs will necessarily coincide in equilibrium. It is therefore from this accounting connection that the two competing models naturally arise. It is also known that the behavioral information of both models is not independent. Equilibrium changes in the demand-driven model will modify the underlying coefficient matrix in the supply-driven version, and vice versa. Thus, mutually compatible coefficient matrices, in the sense that they would both remain unaltered when facing external shocks, would guarantee quantitative applications with a sound theoretical basis and a common accounting platform. This constancy of the technical and allocation coefficients is the property known as joint stability in the literature.

Previous research by Chen and Rose [3], [4], Bon [5], and Rose and Allison [6], among others, has correctly identified a version of the joint-stability condition but has not taken it to its theoretical limit. In fact, it has been argued the condition to be sufficiently acceptable for empirical quantitative work as long as only small changes in external parameters are considered. We consider this conclusion to be faulty and prove so by formally showing its theoretical unsuitability, that is to say, any external change, however small, would never keep joint-stability. In Section 2 we introduce the elements of the discussion and redefine the joint-stability condition. Section 3 explores the implications of the condition and presents the main theoretical result showing the condition to be contradictory with basic axioms. Section 4 summarizes.

An n-sector interindustry economy E(n) is characterized by a n × n matrix of bilateral aggregate flows Z, a (column) n vector of final demands f and a (row) n vector of primary factors use v, or value-added. In compact expression we may represent this economy by E(n)=(Z,f,v). Matrix Z = (zij) contains interindustry exchanges between sectors i and j. The balance in the national accounting identities ensures the following relationship holds true for all i:j=1nzij+fi=j=1nzji+vi=xi,where xi stand for benchmark gross output (left-hand side) and gross input (rigth-hand side) level for sector i. We introduce now behavioral assumptions. From the perspective of production (i.e. inputs) we define a n × n technical coefficient matrix aij = [A]ij by setting aij=zij/xj. Similarly, from the perspective of distribution (i.e. outputs), we introduce a n × n allocation matrix bji = [B]ji by taking bji=zji/xj. Introducing these two definitions in expression (1) we transform it into two behavioral equations:j=1naij·xj+fi=xi,j=1nbji·xj+vi=xi.In compact matrix notation we can write (and solve) them as:x=A·x+f=(I-A)-1·f,x=x·B+v=v·(I-B)-1.The first of these two expressions is the basic Leontief quantity model and the second one corresponds to the quantity model of Ghosh.1 In Leontief’s model total production is determined as a result of demand-driven (i.e. f) inputs adjustments whereas in Ghosh is a consequence of supply-driven (i.e. v) allocation adjustments in output. If we use X as the diagonalized matrix version of the gross output vector x, we can easily check from the definitions of A and B that A=Z·X-1 and B=X-1·Z. It is therefore immediate that A and B are similar matrices through change of basis matrices X and X-1:B=X-1·A·X.It can quickly be seen that for the same bases, similarity of matrices B and A implies similarity of (I-A) and (I-B) and, provided B and A are invertible, similarity of B-1and A-1 as well. As a combined result, similarity on the Leontief and Ghosh inverses, if they exist, also follows for the same bases:(I-B)-1=X-1·(I-A)-1·X.

Take now expression (5) and substitute into Eq. (3a):x=v·(I-B)-1=v·(X-1·(I-A)-1·X).For simplicity, let α denote now the coefficients of the Leontief inverse α=(I-A)-1 so that (6a) becomes:x=v·(X-1·α·X).Similarly, let β=(I-B)-1 stand for the Ghosh inverse matrix. If we now expand (6b) and write the equivalent algebraic relationship, we obtainxj=i=1nvi·xj·αij·1xi=i=1nvi·αij·xjxi=i=1nvi·αij·γij,where γij represents the output ratio between sectors j and i , i.e. γij=xj/xi. Take the partial derivatives first in expression (3a) and then in (7) to obtain:xjvi=βij=αij·γij.Both interindustry models will appear to be simultaneously equivalent in their partial effects, or jointly stable, provided the output ratios γij=xj/xi remain unaltered after a change in sector i’s value-added. Should these ratios change following an external shock in value-added, (8) would imply that constancy of coefficients does not follow. Notice that this would be possible only if in the new equilibrium output quantities do not change or changes are proportional everywhere, i.e. a balanced growth situation. This is the same type of conclusion reached in [3], [4], [5], [6] but we have used the coefficients of the inverse matrices, α and β, instead of the direct input and allocation coefficients of matrices A and B. This novel presentation will allow us now to further explore the implications of the constancy of the output ratios.

Section snippets

Main result

We now state and prove the following:

Joint stability non-possibility theorem. Let A and B be respectively the Leontief and Ghosh non-negative coefficient matrices of an interindustry economy E(n). Assume matrix A is productive (maximal eigenvalue smaller than 1). Then (a) matrix B is productive as well, (b) matrix (I-A) is non-singular and in addition its inverse (I-A)-1is non-negative, (c) constant output ratios, however, are incompatible with productivity of A.

Proof. (a) follows from matrix

Summary remarks

The joint stability property requires that matrices A and B are constant and unaltered by the effects of external changes in output. We offer a proof that this is not possible since joint stability implies non-productivity of the input-output matrix. Evidence in the form of simple numerical examples has been known in the literature: when production adjusts to new final demand schedules, the derived Ghosh matrix B will change. Similarly, in the Ghosh model, when output adjusts to new value-added

Acknowledgements

Support from research Grants MICINN-ECO2009-11857 and SGR2009-578 is gratefully acknowledged. We wish to thank two anonymous reviewers for their useful comments on the earlier draft. Remarks by J. Oosterhaven on a previous paper have been helpful in shaping the present one. This paper was concluded while the first author was visiting the Edward J. Bloustein School of Planning and Public Policy, at Rutgers University. The support of staff, colleagues and especially Professor Michael Lahr is also

References (16)

  • R. Bon

    Comparative stability analysis of demand-side and supply-side input–output models

    International Journal of Forecasting

    (1986)
  • W. Leontief

    Quantitative input and output relations in the economic system of the United States

    Review of Economic and Statistics

    (1936)
  • A. Ghosh

    Input–output approach in an allocation system

    Economica

    (1958)
  • C.L. Chen et al.

    The joint stability of input–output production and allocation coefficients

    Modeling and Simulation

    (1986)
  • C.L. Chen et al.

    The absolute and relative joint stability of input–output production and allocation coefficients

  • A. Rose et al.

    On the plausibility of the supply-driven input–output model: empirical evidence on joint stability

    Journal of Regional Science

    (1989)
  • T. Shores

    Applied Linear Algebra and Matrix Analysis

    (2007)
  • H. Nikaido

    Introduction to Sets and Mappings in Modern Economics

    (1972)
There are more references available in the full text version of this article.

Cited by (2)

  • Supply and demand biases in linear interindustry models

    2013, Economic Modelling
    Citation Excerpt :

    See for instance Guerra and Sancho (2011) for the L model, and most notably Oosterhaven (1988, 1989, 2012) and De Mesnard (2009), among others, for the G model. The joint stability issue between both models has been recently dealt with in Guerra and Sancho (2012) whereas a good elementary introduction can be found in Miller and Blair (2009, chapter 12). A way to overcome such unwanted property has been to extend the classical models to make the exogenous variable, or more precisely some part of it, into an endogenous one.

  • Demand-Driven and Supply-Sided Input–Output Models

    2021, Journal of Quantitative Economics
View full text