Skip to main content
Log in

The competent demand pull hypothesis: which sectors do play a role?

  • Published:
Economia Politica Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The paper investigates intersectoral linkages between manufacturing and services under the competent demand pull hypothesis. This hypothesis postulates that the demand pulls the innovative capacities of the suppliers only when and if they are accompanied by qualified knowledge interactions with creative customers. We empirically investigate this hypothesis based on the sector-level data of nineteen (manufacturing and service) sectors in fifteen EU countries over the period 1995–2007. We adopt the input–output framework to assess the strength of the inter-sectoral intermediate goods transactions. Our main findings confirm that demand actually pulls technological change only when it comes from competent customers able to implement effective user-producer knowledge interactions. The results stress the relevance of the transactions-cum-knowledge interactions between the knowledge intensive business service sectors and the manufacturing industries.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See the excellent review paper by Godin and Lane (2013) for a complete discussion on the origins, development and death of demand pull hypothesis within innovation studies. The suggestion to recognize this related strand of the literature is the merit of an anonymous referee to whom we are very grateful.

  2. For a full list of sectors taken under analysis, see “Appendix 1”.

  3. We follow the same method to calculate the supply-side variable described and used in Antonelli and Gehringer (2013a).

  4. We recognize the need to account for the effects of the sector’s internal R&D efforts. In our previous investigations, however, this variable was never significant, Antonelli and Gehringer (2012, 2013a). This was also the case in the present analysis, except for one case, namely for rubber and plastic products. There is another important limitation related to R&D data. Since data on sectoral R&D expenditures covering our sample are very incomplete, we would lose several observations by including it. Thus, in our main estimation procedure, we report the results from specification without R&D variable. Moreover, as explained below, the application of the DOLS procedure makes sure that there is no omitted variables problem.

  5. This effect refers to the supply-push hypothesis between the supplying sector i (on the left-hand side) and the receiving sector j (on the right-hand side). We do not exclude this dynamics from being actually effective, but we concentrate on the demand pulling dynamics and overcome the possible reversal causality by means of an appropriate econometric methodology.

  6. Under cointegration the error term is stationary; it becomes I(0). An I(0) variable which oscillates around a constant mean is statistically not able to systematically influence the non-stationary dependent variable. Consequently, it can be concluded that omitted variables do not affect and bias our results. Omitted variables could refer to different factors, such as institutional variables (for instance, industrial policies applied in certain countries and in certain sectors) but also other variables (e.g. human capital, specific innovation inputs).

  7. Following the seminal contribution by Solow (1957), this alternative indicator has been often referred to in different fields of the applied work to measure innovative outcome.

  8. Detailed information regarding the data source for our investigation is provided in “Appendix 2”. It also contains the correlation matrix and descriptive statistics of the variables.

  9. We are thankful to the anonymous referee for the suggestion to complete the picture with the pooled estimation. It constitutes indeed an important preliminary check before proceeding to a more detailed sector-to-sector analysis. We limit the discussion of these results to a minimum and refer to a more extensive treatment of the issue in Antonelli and Gehringer (2012).

  10. In the last row, we report the standardized coefficients relative to sectoral aggregate demand (AD).

  11. Crucially, however, the results differ in the magnitude. This derives from the fact that in the pooled regressions the estimated coefficients measure a simple averaged impact of each sectors competent demand on the system-level TFP growth, whereas in the sectoral estimations this impact accounts for more precise features of sector-to-sector interactions.

References

  • Acs, Z. J., Anselin, L., & Varga, A. (2002). Patents and innovation counts as measures of regional production of new knowledge. Research Policy, 31, 1069–1085.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Antonelli, C. (2008). Localized technological change: Towards the economics of complexity. London: Routledge.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Antonelli, C. (Ed.). (2011). Handbook on the economic complexity of technological change. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Antonelli, C. (2013). Knowledge governance: Pecuniary knowledge externalities and total factor productivity growth. Economic Development Quarterly, 27(1), 62–70.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Antonelli, C., & Gehringer, A. (2012). Knowledge externalities and demand pull: The European evidence. LEI & BRICK Working Paper n. 14.

  • Antonelli, C., & Gehringer, A. (2013a). Demand pull and technological flows within innovation systems: The intra-European evidence. Department of Economics S. Cognetti de Martiis, Working Paper n. 01.

  • Antonelli, C., & Gehringer, A. (2013b). The cost of knowledge and productivity dynamics: An empirical investigation on a panel of OECD countries. University of Turin and University of Göttingen, Mimeo.

  • Arthur, W. B. (2007). The structure of invention. Research Policy, 36(2), 274–287.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boyd, J., & Prescott, E. (1986). Financial intermediary-coalitions. Journal of Economic Theory, 38(2), 211–232.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crespi, F., & Pianta, M. (2007). Innovation and demand in European industries. Economia Politica Journal of Institutional and Analytical Economics, 24, 79–112.

    Google Scholar 

  • Davidson, P. (2001). The principle of effective demand: Another view. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 23(3), 392–409.

    Google Scholar 

  • Diamond, D. (1984). Financial intermediation and delegated monitoring. Review of Economic Studies, 51(3), 393–414.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Doloreaux, D., & Shearmur, R. (2012). How much does KIBS contribute to R&D activities of manufacturing firms? Economia Politica Journal of Institutional and Analytical Economics, 3, 319–342.

    Google Scholar 

  • Edquist, C., & Zabala-Iturriagagoiti, J. N. (2012). Public Procurement for innovation as mission oriented innovation policy. Research Policy, 41(10), 1757–1769.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gehringer, A. (2011). Pecuniary knowledge externalities across European countries—are there leading sectors? Industry and Innovation, 18(4), 415–436.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Godin, B., & Lane, J. P. (2013). Pushes and pulls: Hi(S)tory of the demand pull model of innovation. Science Technology and Human Values, 38(5), 621–654.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greenwood, J., & Jovanovic, B. (1990). Financial development, growth, and the distribution of income. Journal of Political Economy, 98(5), 1076–1107.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Griliches, Z. (1979). Issues in assessing the contribution of research and development to productivity growth. Bell Journal of Economics, 10(1), 92–116.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Griliches, Z. (1992). The search for R&D spillovers. Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 94, 29–47.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jorgenson, D. W., Gollop, F. M., & Fraumeni, B. M. (1987). Productivity and U.S. economic growth. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jorgenson, D. W., & Griliches, Z. (1967). The explanation of productivity change. Review of Economic Studies, 34(3), 249–283.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaldor, N. (1966). Causes of the slow rate of growth in the United Kingdom. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • King, R. G., & Levine, R. (1993). Finance, entrepreneurship, and growth: Theory and evidence. Journal of Monetary Economics, 32(3), 513–542.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kline, S. J. (1985). Innovation is not a linear process. Research Management, 28, 36–45.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mowery, D., & Rosenberg, N. (1979). The influence of market demand upon innovation: A critical review of some recent empirical studies. Research Policy, 8(2), 102–153.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, R. R. (2013). Demand supply and their interaction on markets as seen from the perspective of evolutionary economic theory. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 23(1), 17–38.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, R. R., & Consoli, D. (2010). An evolutionary theory of household consumption behavior. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 20(5), 665–687.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pakes, A., & Griliches, Z. (1980). Patents and R&D at the firm level: A first report. Economics Letters, 5, 377–381.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Saviotti, P. P., & Pyka, A. (2013a). From necessities to imaginary world: Structural change, product quality and economic development. Technological Forecasting and Social Change, 80(8), 1499–1512.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Saviotti, P. P., & Pyka, A. (2013b). The co-evolution of innovation demand and growth. Economics of Innovation and New Technology, 22(5), 461–482.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schmookler, J. (1966). Invention and economic growth. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. A. (1947). The creative response in economic history. Journal of Economic History, 7(2), 149–159.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Solow, R. M. (1957). Technical change and the aggregate production function. Review of Economics and Statistics, 39, 312–320.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stock, J. H., & Watson, M. W. (1993). A simple estimator of cointegrating vectors in higher order integrated systems. Econometrica, 61(4), 783–820.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Von Hippel, E. (1993). The sources of innovation. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Von Hippel, E. (1994). Sticky information and the locus of problem-solving: Implications for innovation. Management Science, 40(4), 429–439.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Von Hippel, E. (1998). Economics of product development by users: The impact of sticky local information. Management Science, 44(5), 629–644.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weitzman, M. L. (1996). Hybridizing growth theory. American Economic Review, 86(2), 207–212.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weitzman, M. L. (1998). Recombinant growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113(2), 331–360.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wooldridge, J. M. (2009). Introductory econometrics: A modern approach. Mason, OH: South-Western Cengage Learning.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

The authors acknowledge the institutional support of the research project ‘Incentive Policies for European Research’ (IPER) and the funding of the European Union D.G. Research with the Grant number 266959 to the research project ‘Policy Incentives for the Creation of Knowledge: Methods and Evidence’ (PICK-ME), within the context of the Cooperation Program/Theme 8/Socio-economic Sciences and Humanities (SSH), both in progress at the Collegio Carlo Alberto and the University of Torino.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Agnieszka Gehringer.

Appendices

Appendix 1

Countries included in the analysis are: Austria, Belgium, Czech Republic, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Hungary, Italy, the Netherlands, Portugal, Slovakia, Spain, Sweden and the UK.

See Appendix Table 4.

Table 4 Full names and acronyms of analysed manufacturing and service sectors

Appendix 2

Table 5 summarizes information concerning the definition of variables and their statistical sources.

Table 5 Description of variables and their data sources

See Appendix (Tables 5, 6, 7).

Table 6 Correlation matrix
Table 7 Summary statistics

Appendix 3

Below we show the details of the unit root test, of cointegration test (Table 8) and of the DOLS estimations (Table 9).

Table 8 Results of the unit root test and cointegration test
Table 9 Sector-by-sector estimation results based on the fixed effects model

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Antonelli, C., Gehringer, A. The competent demand pull hypothesis: which sectors do play a role?. Econ Polit 32, 97–134 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s40888-015-0003-1

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s40888-015-0003-1

Keywords

JEL Classfication

Navigation