Skip to main content
  • Research Paper
  • Published:

Assessing the land expectation value of even-aged vs coppice-with-standards stand management and long-term effects of whole-tree harvesting on forest productivity and profitability

Abstract

Key message

Whole-tree harvesting makes forests more profitable than conventional harvest as long as the impact on tree growth remains under 2.3% for even-aged oak ( Quercus petraea (Matt.) Liebl.) and 3.4% for sweet chestnut ( Castanea sativa Mill.) coppice with oak standards. Coppice-with-standards may have potential to be more profitable than even-aged oak in case of 50% rise in fuelwood prices with 10% decrease in timber prices.

Context

Making the shift to renewable energy sources requires increasing biomass removal from the forest in a sustainable way. Today, the most common practice for forest biomass extraction is whole-tree harvesting rather than conventional harvest in which only stems are harvested or sometimes branches larger than 7 cm in diameter. However, intensive biomass harvesting can certainly increase economic profitability but it could affect long-term forest productivity because more nutrients are exported from sites.

Aims

We explored the land expectation value of even-aged oak (Quercus petraea (Matt.) Liebl.) and sweet chestnut (Castanea sativa Mill.) coppice with oak standards under different discount rates and wood prices scenarios, tree mortality triggered by climate variation as well as the effects of a decrease in forest productivity due to whole-tree harvesting on the land expectation value (LEV).

Methods

We modeled two plausible harvesting scenarios for both stands and assessed their LEV. We first analyzed the sensitivity of the valuation results to discount rate, wood prices changes, and increased tree mortality rates. Second, we compared conventional harvest to whole-tree harvesting in which removing the fine wood implies a decrease in tree growth over the long term (between 1 and 10%).

Results

In the current economic situation, the LEV of even-aged oak is higher than coppice-with-standards but this situation could be reversed in case of rising energy prices and lower timber prices in the future. The variation of the discount rate has a significant impact on the LEV but 3% seems to be adequate for European forests. A gradual increase in annual tree mortality rate of 0.6 and 0.9% along even-aged and CWS rotation, respectively, reduced the LEV by half, while increased mortality with constant rates along the rotations had more negative effect on the LEV than gradual increases: 0.4–0.5% increases in mortality rates reduced both LEV’s by half.

Whole-tree harvesting is able to improve the LEV for both stands by 36 to 64% compared to conventional harvest; but this improvement of LEV only lasts as long as the impact on tree growth remains under 2.3 and 3.4%, respectively, for even-aged oak stand and coppice-with-standards.

Conclusion

Whole-tree harvesting system increases forest profitability as long as the sustainability guidelines for biomass harvesting are respected. With the increased demand for fuelwood, the coppice-with-standards regime may become financially attractive once again and fulfill a multitude of forest owner objectives with a wide range of additional options.

1 Introduction

In the context of climate change, national and international institutions have recommended the promotion of renewable energy to protect the global environment and reduce greenhouse gas emissions. The new bioeconomy roadmap for European countries (European Commission 2018) aims to accelerate the deployment of a sustainable bioeconomy by promoting bio-based products and wood consumption for different uses to reach sustainable development goals respecting the Paris Agreement (UN General Assembly 2015). The strategies of the bioeconomy and forest-based sector focus intensively on production processes, product substitution by bio-based alternatives, and resource efficiency (Pelli et al. 2017). France has launched its national bioeconomy strategy (Alim'agri 2017) and has set operational objectives for the forest-based sector, detailed in the National Forestry and Wood Programme (PNFB) and the National Biomass Mobilization Strategy (SNMB) (Alim'agri 2016; MTES 2018). This forest policy aims to satisfy biomass demand in both volume and quality and to optimize the co-benefits of this mobilization while preventing potentially negative impacts.

However, the development of forest bioeconomy is complex, because it builds on a fragmented policy framework and there is no common EU forest policy (Wolfslehner et al. 2016). The Nordic bioeconomy program is rapidly developing and aims to combine environmental, social, and economic ambitions for an even more sustainable development in the Nordic region (Points 2018). In Eastern Europe, there is a lack of national bioeconomy strategies and action plans for the sustainable and circular use of the bioresources (Paşnicu et al. 2019; Vasary 2019).

French forests contain an important wood resource and cover more than 16 million ha. They are mostly mixed deciduous broad-leaved forests and are mainly private, with more than three million forest landowners. Coppice-with-standards (CWS) is a traditional management system developed over past centuries in Western and Northern Europe to ensure a continuous flow of a wide range of forest products (Buckley 1992). However, since the beginning of the twentieth century, CWS stands have progressively been converted to high forests (Huffel 1909), though they still frequently occur throughout France (5 million hectares, about 30% of the total productive forest area (IGN 2015)).

Today, the desire to develop renewable energy sources and supply wood chips to collective biomass boilers and power plants has created an increasing interest in the extraction of all forms of forest biomass. Different methods of logging are used in Europe; their selection depends on site conditions, silvicultural treatments, species composition, tree sizes, stand density, and the economic condition of each country. According to Asikainen et al. (2009), the proportion of mechanization varies greatly among European countries: the percentage is close to 100% in the Nordic countries, UK and Ireland, and notably smaller in Eastern Europe. The mechanization and whole-tree harvesting (WTH) make harvesting poor-quality wood as bioenergy profitable for the landowner (Adebayo et al. 2007; Spinelli and Magagnotti 2010). However, additional harvesting, in particular the extraction of fine wood [diameter < 7 cm], has come under debate. Indeed, despite the relatively small proportion of biomass in fine wood, it contains large amounts of nutrients (Weetman and Webber 1972; Triska and Cromack 1980; Augusto et al. 2015) and its removal could compromise forest productivity. Several studies have shown that removing fine wood has negative effects on long-term forest yield by reducing stand productivity over time; tree growth can decrease by 3 to 20% (Kimmins 1976; Grigal 2000; Nord-Larsen 2002; Peng et al. 2002; Thiffault et al. 2011; Wall 2012; Kaarakka et al. 2014; Miettinen et al. 2014; Achat et al. 2015; Egnell 2017). In this regard, the French recommendations for sustainable biomass harvesting have continuously been updated thanks to several scientific studies and increasing technical expertise (Cacot et al. 2006; Landmann and Nivet 2014). The latest recommendations take into account local conditions, in particular soil sensitivity to mineral exports (Landmann et al. 2018). It is highly recommended to leave at least 10% of the fine wood on the ground for non-sensitive soils and to increase this value to 30% on moderately sensitive soils. In the case of highly sensitive or poor soils, harvesting fine wood is not recommended; all fine wood should be left on the forest floor.

Forest management is a complex process, which requires both patience and acceptance of risk, and which includes environmental, economic, and social criteria. Not only is knowledge of the effects of nutrient losses due to WTH essential to maintaining forest soil fertility, economic issues are also crucial to guarantee forest sustainability. The emergence of new industries and new wood-derived products implies changes in silvicultural practices and forest management; these changes undoubtedly involve environmental risks but also long-term economic uncertainties for the future. Additional harvests will undoubtedly increase the profitability of the stand but the effects of more harvesting on the forest have not been sufficiently analyzed from an economic point of view. Furthermore, the increases in tree mortality have been highlighted in different forests around the globe (Van Mantgem et al. 2009; Peng et al. 2011; Westerling et al. 2006; Williams et al. 2013). A number of studies (Sáenz-Romero et al. 2017; Taccoen et al. 2019; Brandl et al. 2020) suggest that mortality rates will keep on increasing, while species that have not been impacted to date might be impacted in the future.

Forest investment is staggered over time; the return may occur decades after the initial investment. It is therefore necessary to compare cash flows occurring at different times. Faustmann (1849) considers a forest as a financial asset managed over an infinite horizon; he proposed a simple deterministic model to evaluate the land expectation value (LEV) over an infinite sequence of rotations. Discounting to determine the present value of future cash flows is therefore fully justified in forest economics (Samuelson 1976; Peyron and Maheut 1999; Terreaux 2008; Hanewinkel 2009; Hyde 2012). On this issue, Price (2014) and Brazee (2018) demonstrated the implications of various discount rates on net present values and showed how much time is crucial in many aspects of forest economics. In addition, silvicultural costs have an important effect on the net present value since these “front-end costs” emerge at the beginning of a rotation (Sauter and Mußhoff 2018). Timber prices also depend on wood quality (Cavaignac et al. 2005), variation in supply and demand (Caurla et al. 2010), and climatic policies (Buongiorno et al. 2011; Hanewinkel et al. 2013). More generally, forest investments can be subject to natural hazards (growth fluctuations, storms, diseases, fires, etc.) and economic risks (variations in inflation, supply and demand, wood prices and silvicultural costs, etc.), not to mention other political and social risks (Kant and Alavalapati 2014; Terreaux and Chavet 2016).

The main objective of this study was to compare the land expectation value (LEV) for even-aged oak (Quercus petraea (Matt.) Liebl.) and chestnut coppice (Castanea sativa Mill.) with oak standards under different wood prices and discount rates scenarios. Using current prices and silvicultural costs, we generated a series of cash flows and transformed these into Faustmann’s LEV, assuming that future costs, prices, and stand growth were known. Nevertheless, tree survival is frequently hypothesized to be climate sensitive (Peng et al. 2011; Williams et al. 2013). With projections of increasing temperatures (O'Neill et al. 2017), drought frequencies, and intensities, a number of studies suggest that mortality rates will keep on increasing (e.g., Neumann et al. 2017; Sáenz-Romero et al. 2017).

The LEV was assessed according to two harvesting scenarios: (1) whole-tree harvesting and (2) conventional harvesting (all fine wood is left on site). Whole-tree harvesting scenario was then analyzed under the assumption of decline in long-term productivity due to intensive biomass removal and nutrient exports by fine wood. We therefore explored the economic consequences on LEV by simulating 10 scenarios of decrease in tree growth in both height and diameter from 1 to 10%. This study also aimed to find possible trade-offs between the short-term economic gain and the long-term decline in productivity.

2 Material and methods

2.1 Harvesting scenarios and working hypotheses

We simulated two plausible scenarios each for even-aged oak stand and CWS: (1) whole-tree harvesting (WTH), and (2) conventional harvesting (CH) without any export of fine wood. Three categories of potential wood uses were defined according to dimensional characteristics: (i) large wood [diameter > 22 cm] for timber, (ii) medium wood [7–22 cm] for industrial wood or fuelwood, and (iii) fine wood [diameter < 7 cm] only for fuelwood. In WTH scenario, all the fine wood was harvested at each silvicultural operation, with the assumption that 10% of the fine wood would systematically be left on the forest floor due to harvesting losses (Landmann et al. 2018). In this case, the decline in stand productivity was assumed to affect tree growth, in height and diameter, from 1 to 10% due to additional nutrient exports (Nord-Larsen 2002; Wall 2012; Achat et al. 2015). In CH scenario, large wood was sold as timber and only medium wood was harvested for energy and other industrial uses. All the fine wood was left on the ground. We assumed here that soil fertility and stand productivity would not be affected because the high nutrient content of fine wood would ensure the maintenance of soil fertility (Lattimore et al. 2009; Landmann and Nivet 2014).

Silvicultural operations in each scenario were triggered at the same reference basal area; this postponed thinning operations and coppice harvesting date from 1 to 5 years depending on the decrease in height and diameter as well as the stand type.

2.2 Growth models and volume equations

We modeled two plausible stands on medium-fertility sites (Jarret 2004; Bedeneau 1988): (i) pure even-aged sessile oak stand and (ii) chestnut coppice with oak standards stand (CWS). We then used the dendrometric outputs (Bessaad et al. 2020) to compute subsequent volumes through tree allometric equations, thereby ensuring consistency in our estimates by compartment (stem, crown, branches) and by cutting level. The harvested volume, at any given date of silvicultural operation, is one of the most important pieces of information for conducting economic analyses. This method allowed us to compute, for both stands, the profitability of each scenario (WTH and CH) using Microsoft Excel software.

2.2.1 Pure even-aged sessile oak

The “Fagacées” model developed by Le Moguédec and Dhôte (2012) allowed us to obtain the necessary dendrometric data (Table 1). We opted for the recommended silvicultural pathway of sessile oak on a medium-fertility site class (site fertility index: H100 = 27.5 m) from Jarret (2004) because of using average economic data afterwards. We then reproduced, as closely as possible, the silvicultural pathway on the basis of the relative density index (RDI) value (Reineke 1933), which is the ratio of the actual number of stems (N) in a stand and the theoretical number of stems (Nmax), this stand could support with the same diameter at breast height (DBH) (Eq. 1).

Table 1 Output parameters for even-aged sessile oak
$$ RDI=\frac{N}{N_{max}} $$
(1)

2.2.2 Coppice-with-standards

We assumed here that the coppice and the standards covered equal parts of the area (Bary-Lenger and Nebout 1993) and that tree growth for the coppice and the standards was unrelated. We separately simulated the part of chestnut coppice and oak standards using growth models and biomass equations. We modeled oak standards using “Fagacées” and used Bedeneau (1988) general logistic model for chestnut coppice, thus allowing us to plot the evolution curves in biomass (Eq. 2) and height (Eq. 3) according to age.

$$ Biomass\ \left(t.{ha}^{-1}\right)=124\times {\left(1-{e}^{\left(-0.078\times age\right)}\right)}^{1.4} $$
(2)
$$ Height\ (m)=17.9\times {\left(1-{e}^{\left(-0.049\times age\right)}\right)}^{0.67} $$
(3)

We then estimated tree circumference at breast height (C130) for chestnut coppice from real observations (n =504) and measurements of tree total height from 2 to 24 m and tree circumference from 2 to 102 cm on four sites in the Centre-Val de Loire region (Appendix Fig. 7). C130 depends on the total height (Htot) and varies according to the following simple linear regression model (R2 =99.05; P <0.05) (Eq. 4).

$$ {\mathrm{C}}_{130}={\left(0.836321+0.350799\times {\mathrm{H}}_{\mathrm{tot}}\ \right)}^2 $$
(4)

All dendrometric parameters for CWS stand are presented in Table 2.

Table 2 Output parameters for chestnut coppice and oak standards

2.2.3 Volume equations

We used tree allometric equations resulting from the EMERGE project (Deleuze et al. 2014b; Deleuze et al. 2014a) to compute woody biomass production by cutting level (Eqs. 5 to 9). We used cutoff height (Hcut) as the main parameter to distribute volumes between the stem and the crown. This parameter is defined by the French National Forest Inventory (IFN, now IGN) as the height of the stem measured approximately at the first major fork in the trunk, or, where appropriate, the height at which a more than 10% decrease in diameter is reached. Indeed, this parameter is very informative of the shape of the tree and has been systematically integrated into inventories since 2006. We deduced a relationship between Htot and Hcut from dendrometric surveys carried out at the nine sites. The average value of \( \frac{{\mathrm{H}}_{cut}}{{\mathrm{H}}_{\mathrm{tot}}} \) for each species was 0.41 ± 0.1; CV = 25% (n = 41) for sessile oak and 0.50 ± 0.07; CV= 13.38% (n = 504) for chestnut.

Volumes were calculated in three steps, where “a, b, c, d, e, f, g, α, and β” are the parameters specific to each species but without units (Appendix Table 5).

First, we calculated total tree volume (Vtot) as follows (Eq. 5).

$$ {V}_{tot}\ \left({m}^3\right)=\frac{H_{tot}.{C}_{130}^{\kern1.75em 2}}{4\pi\ {\left(1-\frac{1.30}{H_{tot}}\right)}^2}\times \left(a+b\ \frac{\sqrt{C_{130}}}{H_{tot}}+c\ \frac{H_{tot}}{C_{130}}\right) $$
(5)

Second, the total volume was distributed by compartment (stem (Vstem) and crown (Vcrown)) according to the following Eqs. (6) and (7):

$$ {V}_{stem}\ \left({m}^3\right)={V}_{tot}\left(d+e.\mathit{\ln}\ \left(\frac{H_{cut}}{H_{tot}-{H}_{cut}}\right)+f\ \frac{\sqrt{C_{130}}}{H_{tot}}+\frac{g}{C_{130}}\right) $$
(6)
$$ {V}_{Crown}\left({m}^3\right)={V}_{tot}-{V}_{stem} $$
(7)

Third, we used Eqs. (8) and (9) to obtain stem volume up to the cutting level (Vstem_cut) and crown volume (Vcrown_cut), respectively:

$$ {V}_{stem\_ cut}\ \left({m}^3\right)={V}_{stem}\times \left(1-\frac{C_{cut}^3}{C_{130}^3}\ {\left(1-\frac{1.30}{H_{tot}}\right)}^3\right) $$
(8)
$$ {V}_{Crown\_ cut}\left({m}^3\right)={V}_{Crown}\times \left(1-{\left(\frac{C_{cut}}{C_{130}}\ \left(1-\frac{1.30}{H_{tot}}\right)\ {\left(\frac{3-\beta }{3\alpha }\ crown\ part\right)}^{-\frac{1}{3}}\right)}^{3-\beta}\right) $$
(9)

2.2.4 Potential effects of climate change on tree mortality

Tree mortality is becoming increasingly important in the discussion of how to adapt forests to climate change, to preserve their ecosystem services, and to mitigate the risk of induced economic losses. The Fagacées model used in our study for oak has not been calibrated on very young stands (Le Moguédec and Dhôte 2012). The trees growth, involving self-thinning, was the only cause of mortality. For CWS, chestnut mortality is given in the (Appendix Fig. 8). The current mean annual mortality rate is 0.50% per year in Europe’s forests, ranging from 0.31 per year in central-western Europe to 1.39% per year in south-western Europe.

For our analysis, we defined two scenarios of a potential increase in annual tree mortality due to drought and temperature increment in forest. First, we assumed a gradual increase in tree mortality from 0.1 to 1.3% over the stand rotation. Second, we modeled tree growth under constant mortality rates over time from 0.1 to 1%.

2.3 Economic parameters

We calculated the LEV (Eq. 10) under different harvesting scenarios while respecting Faustmann’s (1849) main assumptions, an environment in which prices, costs, and technology are constant.

$$ LEV\ \left(\text{\EUR} \right)={\sum}_{i=0}^t\frac{R_i-{C}_i}{{\left(1+r\right)}^i}\times \frac{{\left(1+r\right)}^t}{{\left(1+r\right)}^t-1} $$
(10)

Ri is the revenue received at time i; Ci is the cost incurred at time i; and r is the discounting rate over time i.

We transformed the silvicultural pathway schedule (Appendix Tables 6 and 7) into costs and revenue over the entire rotation of each stand. Occasional costs were estimated based on averages for each type of silvicultural operation (Table 3) (Saint-André et al. 2019; Bessaad et al. 2020). Occasional revenue is only related to the timber and fuelwood sales that follow the cutting schedule for each stand. We then calculated the fixed annual revenue and charges (management fees at 15 € ha-1, insurance costs and taxation at 15 € ha-1, other annual income such as hunting at 30 € ha-1), based on expert evaluation. We did not take into account possible financial aid for afforestation, improvement of existing stands, equipment, or management because the application of these schemes remains marginal.

Table 3 Average silvicultural costs for sessile oak in north-central France (Saint-André et al. 2019)

Concerning wood product prices, we first drew the price curve for sessile oak timber, based on regional sales data for private forests in 2017. The average timber price for standard quality followed the relation: P = 48.66 (Vol) + 61.67 and depended on mean tree volume (Vol). The average price for fuelwood was 12.6 € m-3, and ranged from 5 to 20 € m-3 depending on species, tree size, forest location, and skidding distance. We examined the LEV for both types of stands assuming a decrease in tree growth both in height and diameter caused by fine wood removal.

To better understand the effects of our main variables, we conducted a sensitivity analysis based on price variations observed over the last few decades. Timber prices varied from −50 to +50%, whereas fuelwood prices showed a wider range, from −50% to +150%, compared to the average value of 12.6 € m-3 obtained for 2017. Choosing the discount rate is crucial to our research because of the long-term nature of the impacts of WTH on soil fertility. We used a rate r of 3% to discount both costs and profits of various natures at different times. We then conducted a sensitivity analysis for the discount rate covered a range of 2–4%, which seems to be adequate for European forestry (Lebègue et al. 2005; Benítez et al. 2007; Terreaux 2008; Terreaux 2018).

3 Results

3.1 Comparison of CWS and even-aged oak LEV

We first estimated the global profitability for even-aged oak and CWS according to the same scenario (WTH) by maximizing the LEV (r = 3%) using as command variable the rotation age. The graphs in (Fig. 1) show that bare land value ranged from 957 for CWS to 1292 € ha-1 for even-aged oak. The mathematically optimum rotation age for both silvicultural systems was 177 years, but the curve for CWS tends to reach the optimum earlier than does the curve for even-aged oak. In the case of an early harvest, for example, at the age of 120 years, the loss in LEV was less pronounced in CWS (10%) than in even-aged oak stand (25%). Therefore, the CWS system provides the owners or managers forest with more flexibility, making it possible to cut before the calculated optimal date to take advantage of good market conditions, for example. The LEV of even-aged oak was higher because this type of stand produces more large wood (Fig. 2), in particular at the final cutting: 437 m3 ha-1 compared to 187 m3 ha-1 for CWS. The larger the diameter of oak timber, the higher its value. Fine and medium wood yield from the CWS was 1079 m3 ha-1 (including 590 m3 ha-1 produced by the chestnut coppice), and it was much higher than in even-aged oak stand (722 m3 ha-1) during the same rotation.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Changes in LEV (€ ha-1) in the whole-tree harvesting scenario for even-aged oak and coppice-with-standards with an optimal rotation age for both stands

Fig. 2
figure 2

Wood volumes. a Final large wood production, peaks, and troughs indicate thinnings. (b) Fine and medium wood production along the rotation

3.2 Harvesting fine wood under the assumption of a decrease in tree growth during subsequent rotations

Our results (Fig. 3) showed that WTH improved global profitability compared to CH scenario by 36% for even-aged stand and 64% for CWS. This gain was higher for the CWS regime due to the high ratio of fine wood (20%) in the total fuelwood production (only 13% in even-aged stand). More specifically, the chestnut coppice contains a high proportion of fine wood (27% of its production). Moreover, leaving 30% of the fine wood on the ground improved profitability by 28% for even-aged oak and by 50% for CWS, which represents only slight losses in expected gain for WTH (8%) and even-aged oak (14%).

Fig. 3
figure 3

Effects of a 1 to 9% decrease in tree growth on the LEV (€ ha-1) in the whole-tree harvesting scenario compared to conventional harvest without any export of fine wood, for even-aged oak (a) and coppice-with-standards (b)

The simulations of WTH, under the assumption of a decrease in tree growth, allowed us to quantify the associated impact on profitability due to harvesting the fine wood. Our results showed that a decrease of 2.3% in tree growth for even-aged oak and 3.4% for CWS, based on the basal reference area, postponed thinning operations and consequently delayed revenue for up to 3 years for even-aged oak and 5 years for CWS. This decrease in tree growth led us to the same LEV as CH for both stands (Fig. 3). In even-aged stand, the total volume including fuelwood was reduced by 2.7% whereas timber production was reduced by 3.7%. For CWS, the loss in total production was more pronounced at 7.3%, while timber volume was reduced by 4.8%.

We also found an almost linear relation between the LEV and the tree growth (Fig. 3). The LEV was very close to zero for both stands if tree growth had been reduced by 9%. In this case, total production was reduced by 12.5% for even-aged oak stand and by 18.5% for CWS, while timber production was reduced by 15.3 and 12%, respectively.

3.3 Price sensitivity analysis

Fluctuating wood prices had a significant effect on LEV (Fig. 4). First, a near doubling (+93%) of the fuelwood price (24.32 € m-3) allowed an equal LEV for both types of stands; beyond this price, CWS became the most profitable investment. Second, raising oak timber prices by 50% increased the difference between stand LEVs from 26 to 37% in favor of even-aged stand. Conversely, a drop of 25% in timber prices made CWS more profitable than even-aged stand, whereas a drop of 40% and below led to negative values. With a slight fall (10%) in timber prices and a simultaneous 50% rise in energy prices, the LEVs of both stands became equal. CWS became more advantageous when energy prices exceeded 20 € m-3. It should be noted that the LEV was more sensitive to timber price fluctuations than to fuelwood prices in even-aged stand because of the high economic value of timber and its large part in the total discounted wood revenue (Fig. 5). At rotation end, the proportion of timber in the discounted wood revenue for even-aged oak was 71%, with only 29% for fuelwood including 8% for fine wood. For CWS, fuelwood provided about half (49%) of the discounted wood revenue including 5 and 7% of oak and chestnut fine wood, respectively.

Fig. 4
figure 4

Prices sensitivity analysis, effect of fuelwood and timber price variations on the LEV (€ ha-1) of even-aged oak and coppice-with-standards: a fluctuating fuelwood prices (average = 12.6 € m-3), from −50 to +150%, b fluctuating oak timber prices, from −50 to +50%, c rising fuelwood prices, up to +80% with a slight decrease in oak timber prices

Fig. 5
figure 5

Changes in the proportion of discounted wood revenue by species, diameter class, and wood use for even-aged oak (a) and CWS (b). The filled area represents sessile oak and the hatched area represents chestnut coppice

3.4 Impact of discount rate r on the LEV

For both stands, forest investment was generally more profitable under low discount rates (Fig. 6). However, for the very low discount rate of r = 2%, the optimal rotation age was not reached. The LEV was 10,500 € for even-aged oak and 6600 € for CWS at 220 years, our maximum simulation period. At medium discount rates, 2.5 and 3%, the LEV ranged from 4300 to 1290 € for even-aged oak and from 2777 to 957 € for CWS. The optimal rotation age was reached for both stands at 205 years (r = 2.5%) and 177 years (r = 3%). For r > 3%, the LEV was negative for both stands.

Fig. 6
figure 6

Sensibility analysis of the consequences of using different discount rates (r = 2; 2.5; 3; 3.5; and 4) on the LEV

3.5 Consequences of increased tree mortality triggered by climate change

For both scenarios, the decrease in the LEV of even-aged oak was more significant than CWS (Table 4). First, the gradual increases in annual tree mortality over time reduced the LEV in even-aged oak by 90 ± 1 € ha-1 for every 0.1% and 47 ± 4 € ha-1 for CWS. A gradual increase in tree mortality of 0.6% along even-aged oak rotation reduced the LEV of even-aged oak by almost 50%, while at 0.9%, the LEV was reduced by 70%. For CWS, the LEV was reduced by half at 0.9% and by 70% at 1.2%.

Table 4 Consequences of gradual and constant increase in annual mortality rate (%) on the LEV (€ ha-1)

Second, constant mortality rates had more negative effect on the LEV than gradual increases. Both LEVs were reduced by half at 0.4–0.5%. When increases in annual mortality rates passed 0.6%, the LEVs were reduced by more than 70%.

4 Discussion

4.1 Potential trends in forest productivity and economic value

A forest’s economic value depends mostly on the volume, dimensions, and quality of the wood that it can produce, thus on its soil fertility, and not only on wood prices and silvicultural costs. The volumes we obtained were very close to other previous studies: large wood volume including thinning operations was 922 m3 ha-1 in even-aged oak stand and 415 m3 ha-1 for CWS stand at the age of 177 years. For the same age and site fertility index, Jarret (2004) estimated total volume in an even-aged oak stand at 859 m3 ha-1. For CWS stand, Bary-Lenger and Nebout (1993) revealed that oak timber yield ranged from 1.81 to 3.05 m3 ha-1 per year for standards, which provides between 380 and 540 m3 of timber at the end of the rotation.

Our chestnut coppice on medium-fertility soil produced 108 m3 ha-1 at every cutting. This is consistent with Venanzi et al. (2016), who estimated 175.3 m3 ha-1 through a study carried out on a chestnut CWS in the mountains of central Italy on high fertility sites with a very high yield. Their estimates are very high, closer to the production of a simple coppice regime (Bedeneau 1988; Bourgeois et al. 2004). In addition, the number of standards in CWS system has an effect of the LEV because they provide more timber. Poor stand in standards has less economic value than our simulated stand with equal proportions of coppice and standards. However, the LEV remains the highest in even-aged oak whatever the proportions of coppice and standards in CWS system because oak trees cover 100% of the area and produce more high timber value than in CWS.

It should also be noted that the results obtained from this study concern average fertility sites. Other soil fertility indexes were not investigated because of the lack of data on CWS management as well as specific silvicultural costs to each fertility class. We therefore focused on comparison between the two harvesting scenarios for both management systems on sites with medium fertility.

For WTH scenarios, our results showed that bare land value ranged from 957 to 1292 € ha-1 under a discount rate of 3%. The LEV was very sensitive to changes in discount rates; the lower rates lead to extend the final harvest age and increase standing volume but this will lead to greater environmental degradation in future (Pukkala 2016).

The even-aged management system has been the reference silvicultural treatment since the beginning of the twentieth century owing to its high production of timber and high prices, and it has been opposed to CWS forests (see, in particular, Lorentz and Huffel (1929) and Lanier et al. (1986)). Indeed, in the current context of low fuelwood prices, the even-aged system remains more profitable than CWS because of the high timber prices compared to fuelwood. Nonetheless, in light of the EU’s renewable energy targets, biomass will become the most important source of renewable energy, and fuelwood prices could increase in the future geopolitical context. We showed that an increase of 50% in fuelwood prices associated to 10% decrease in timber prices aligned the profitability of the two types of stands. CWS could therefore once again become an attractive regime, producing both timber and fuelwood, and may be one of the most efficient systems for the future.

4.2 Is whole-tree harvesting profitable over the long term?

The environmental effects of increasing harvesting pressure on forests are still not fully understood. Moreover, not only the ecological aspects and potential losses in productivity but also the related economic concerns in order to find more possible trade-offs should be taken into account. Fine wood represents a non-negligible part of global forest profitability regardless of the type of stand. WTH improved the profitability of even-aged stand by 36% of CWS by 64% due to the additional harvest of fine wood, which amounts to 13 and 20% of the total fuelwood volume, respectively. Furthermore, leaving 30% of the fine wood behind after each harvesting operation, as recommended by Landmann et al. (2018), did not much affect the expected gain: losses were relatively slight in even-aged oak (8%) and in CWS (14%). We would therefore fully endorse this recommendation, if leaving 30% of the fine wood meant there would be no detrimental effect on tree growth and forest productivity.

A decrease in annual tree growth of only 2.3% for even-aged oak and 3.4% for CWS had a large impact on forest profitability and was enough to bring the LEV back to the same level as the CH scenario. It is therefore inadvisable to harvest fine wood beyond these growth decrease percentages. Moreover, a 9% decrease in tree growth led to near-zero LEVs for both stands, due to total wood production reduced by 12.5% in even-aged oak stand and 18.5% in CWS. More specifically, the decline in profitability for even-aged stand was primarily due to reduced timber production (−15.3%), compared to −9% for fuelwood. Conversely, the decline in profitability for CWS was mostly due to reduced fuelwood production (−21%), compared to −11.8% for timber. For lower fertility sites with a very low LEV, the silvicultural pathway should be adapted in order to maintain the economic value of the forest.

Our economic analysis is in line with previous research on the environmental impacts of WTH, which showed that harvesting fine wood reduced tree growth in subsequent rotations by 3 to 20% (Kimmins 1976; Grigal 2000; Nord-Larsen 2002; Peng et al. 2002; Thiffault et al. 2011; Wall 2012; Kaarakka et al. 2014; Achat et al. 2015; Egnell 2017). The current guidelines for sustainable biomass harvesting (Landmann et al. 2018) recommend leaving 10 to 30% of the total fine wood volume on the ground and not exporting any fine wood in case of poor or sensitive soils. Our study supports these recommendations: a small proportion, though not all, of the fine wood should be left in the forest. Leaving all of the fine wood on the forest floor does indeed affect forest profitability. We showed that the proportion of fine wood in total wood revenue was higher at the beginning than at the end of the rotation; it declined gradually to reach 8% of the discounted wood revenue at 120 years for even-aged stand and 12 at 140 years for CWS. Therefore, harvesting fine wood does not add the same value at all cutting cycles; the discounted profits depend on time preference and changes in the proportion of fine wood in the total harvest.

4.3 How do increases in tree mortality due to climate change affect the forest profitability?

Extreme events such as abnormal droughts or heatwaves are important drivers of tree mortality, and they are expected to increase in frequency and intensity with climate change (Peng et al. 2011; Taccoen et al. 2019). However, disentangling the effects of climate change on the temporal increase in tree mortality from those of management and forest dynamics remains a challenge. Besides climate variability, tree mortality is further influenced by tree size as well as other biotic factors (van Mantgem et al. 2009; Peng et al. 2011). Age is an important driver of tree mortality, with individual mortality probability decreasing with age over the first century of a tree life (Neumann et al. 2017). In addition, Sáenz-Romero et al. (2017) indicated a significant but moderate response of tree height to climate variation on oak population at a reference age of 10 years.

Our analysis is limited due to the multitude of factors controlling tree mortality, but the use of early warning could highlight some economic concerns of the future. Our results show, for both mortality scenarios, that economic losses due to the potential increases in tree mortality triggered by climate change might be very significant. Consequences of widespread tree mortality would seriously affect the forest profitability and compromise long-term economic returns, especially wood revenues. Changes in silvicultural and harvesting practices should therefore be further explored in order to adapt forests to future climatic variations. Moreover, a combined effect of increased tree mortality and decrease in tree growth due to intensive harvesting may have a large impact on all ecosystem services, including wood and non-wood products, carbon sequestration, and air and water quality.

5 Conclusion

Our study demonstrates that WTH makes the forest more profitable as long as the impact on tree growth remains under 2.3% for even-aged oak stand and 3.4% for coppice-with-standards. This duality between environmental risk and economic gain requires trade-offs to guarantee forest sustainability. Indeed, our findings support the current guidelines for sustainable biomass harvesting, which advocate for leaving a small proportion of fine wood on the forest floor. Decision makers need to agree on this trade-off and should remain sensitive to environmental and social dimensions while including economic analyses in their decisions. For a better understanding of economic vulnerability of forests, tree mortality derived by climate variation should also receive major attention in order to maintain all ecosystem services.

Our work contributes to the question of forest economic sustainability, though certain aspects, such as risks and uncertainties, need to be further addressed.

Data availability

The datasets generated during and analyzed during the current study are available on OpenAIRE Zenedo: https://doi.org/10.5281/zenodo.4050092.

References

Download references

Acknowledgments

The authors gratefully thank the staff of French National Forestry Office (ONF), Christine Deleuze and Jean-Pierre Renaud, for providing the volumes equations resulting from the project EMERGE, and Hanitra Rakotoarison for her assistance acquiring economic data. We also thank Isabelle Bilger for her support during the realization of this work and Vicki Moore for proofreading the English manuscript.

Funding

This research was funded by the DEFIFORBOIS project “Development and sustainability of the forest-wood sector in the Centre region,” PSDR 4 project Centre-Val de Loire Region, France. This study has also been carried out with financial support from the French National Research Agency (ANR) in the frame of the Investments for the future Programme, within the Cluster of Excellence COTE (ANR-10-LABX-45) through the Project LUCAS.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Abdelwahab Bessaad.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

The authors declare no competing interests.

Additional information

Handling Editor: Rasoul Yousefpour

Publisher’s note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Contributions of the co-authors

Conceptualization: Jean-Philippe Terreaux, Nathalie Korboulewsky; Methodology: Abdelwahab Bessaad, JeanPhilippe Terreaux, Nathalie Korboulewsky; Software: Abdelwahab Bessaad; Validation: Abdelwahab Bessaad, Jean-Philippe Terreaux, Nathalie Korboulewsky; Formal analysis: Jean-Philippe Terreaux; Investigation: Abdelwahab Bessaad; Resources: Abdelwahab Bessaad, Jean-Philippe Terreaux, Nathalie Korboulewsky; Data curation: Abdelwahab Bessaad; Writing (original draft): Abdelwahab Bessaad; Writing (review and editing): Abdelwahab Bessaad, Jean-Philippe Terreaux, Nathalie Korboulewsky; Visualization: Abdelwahab Bessaad; Supervision: Jean-Philippe Terreaux; Project administration: Nathalie Korboulewsky; Funding acquisition: Nathalie Korboulewsky.

Appendix

Appendix

Fig. 7
figure 7

Linear regression model for chestnut circumference C130 estimation

Fig. 8
figure 8

Tree mortality along chestnut coppice rotation

Table 5 Specific parameters of volume equations from Deleuze et al. (2014b) and Deleuze et al. (2014a)
Table 6 Silvicultural pathway for even-aged sessile oak Jarret (2004)
Table 7 Silvicultural pathway for coppice-with-standards Bary-Lenger and Nebout (1993) and Jarret (2004)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Bessaad, A., Terreaux, JP. & Korboulewsky, N. Assessing the land expectation value of even-aged vs coppice-with-standards stand management and long-term effects of whole-tree harvesting on forest productivity and profitability. Annals of Forest Science 78, 57 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s13595-021-01071-2

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s13595-021-01071-2

Keywords