Skip to main content
Log in

The nature of Coasean property

  • Published:
International Review of Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The Coase Theorem is widely regarded as pointing to the importance of positive transaction costs for the analysis of economic institutions. Various interpretations of the Coase Theorem regard transaction costs as some set of impediments to contracting, or more broadly, as the costs of providing institutional solutions to conflicts over resource use. The abstract nature of the Coasean hypothetical tends to promote an abstract notion of property as a thin entitlement: a right in a designated person to take certain actions or derive value from a set of resource attributes. On this view, property is like a collection of tiny contracts. The property rights furnished by actual property law are much more coarse grained than this, and property is correspondingly “incomplete” for transaction costs reasons. Property and contract are substitutes in some situations, but they often are not interchangeable—because of Coasean transaction costs.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The authors are of two minds about the plausibility of this common interpretation as an answer to the historical question of what Coase (1960) actually said. Smith considers it a viable possibility; Lee is skeptical. Both authors agree that some older readings, which suggest that Coase believed that transaction costs were zero and bargaining could efficiently resolve any conflict of uses, are incorrect.

  2. Although some transaction costs might vary relatively freely in proportion to the value of the entitlements, which are the subjects of those transactions, other transaction costs are relatively static. Thus, as entitlements become narrower and more fine grained, the gross amount of social utility that can be obtained by reallocating any individual entitlement grows smaller—there simply is less at stake in each individual instance—but the transaction costs of each reallocation remain relatively invariant. As this process of attenuation continues, there are more and more reallocations for which the ever-shrinking gross marginal utility of reallocation has fallen below the static marginal cost of reallocation—i.e. the net marginal utility of reallocation has become negative—and, as result, an increasing fraction of all entitlements cannot feasibly be reallocated. At the limit, all reallocation ceases, with an enormous potential loss in social welfare.

  3. Note that in a world of positive transaction costs individual holders of entitlements will not be able to do this packaging on their own unless the individuals already had a set of entitlements that naturally lend themselves to being combined. (The likelihood of finding a counterparty interested in trading for a cobbled-together hodge-podge of random entitlements is remote.) In other words, creating these packages through purely private ordering would require that the initial allocation has already been designed to provide individuals with entitlements that naturally belong together in packages. Individual packaging then would not be an alternative to the institution of property, but rather would itself depend upon that institution, so long as transaction costs are positive.

  4. When it comes to property, Coase was a hyper-realist, although for his purposes, i.e. to show the working of law on the economy, it was not necessary to settle on one view of property (Merrill and Smith 2001, forthcoming).

References

  • Allen DW (1991) What are transaction costs? Res Law Econ 14:1–18

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berle AA, Means GC (1932) The modern corporation and private property. Commerce Clearing House, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Chang Y, Smith HE (forthcoming) An economic analysis of civil versus common law property. Notre Dame L Rev 88 (available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2017816)

  • Cheung SNS (1998) The transaction costs paradigm. Econ Inq 36:514–521

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coase RH (1937) The nature of the firm. Economica (n.s.) 4:386–405

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coase RH (1960) The problem of social cost. J Law Econ 3:1–44

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coase RH (1988) The firm, the market, and the law. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Demsetz H (2011) The problem of social cost: what problem? A critique of the reasoning of A. C. Pigou and R. H. Coase. Rev Law Econ 7:1–13

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Farber DA (1997) Parody lost/pragmatism regained: the ironic history of the Coase Theorem. Va Law Rev 83:397–428

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grey TC (1980) The disintegration of property. In: Pennock JR, Chapman JW (eds) NOMOS XXII: property. New York University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Grossman SJ, Hart O (1996) The costs and benefits of ownership: a theory of vertical and lateral integration. J Pol Econ 94:691–719

    Google Scholar 

  • Hansmann H, Kraakman R (2000) The essential role of organizational law. Yale Law J 110:387–440

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hart O (1995) Firms, contracts, and financial structure. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Hart O, Moore J (1990) Property rights and the nature of the firm. J Pol Econ 98:1119–1158

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Iacobucci EM, Triantis GG (2007) Economic and legal boundaries of firms. Va L Rev 93:515–570

    Google Scholar 

  • McCloskey D (1998) The so-called Coase Theorem. East Econ J 24:367–371

    Google Scholar 

  • Merrill TW, Smith HE (2001) What happened to property in law and economics? Yale Law J 111:357–398

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Merrill TW, Smith HE (forthcoming) Making Coasean property more Coasean. J Law Econ

  • Pigou AC (1920) The economics of welfare. Macmillan, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Schwab S (1989) Coase defends Coase: why lawyers listen and economists do not. Mich Law Rev 87:1171–1198

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith HE (2002) Exclusion versus governance: two strategies for delineating property rights. J Leg Stud 31:S453–S487

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith HE (2009) Mind the gap: the indirect relation between ends and means in American property law. Cornell Law Rev 94:959–989

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith HE (forthcoming) On the economy of concepts in property. U Pa L Rev 160 (available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1989008)

  • Stigler GJ (1961) The economics of information. J Polit Econ 69:213–225

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

Brian Angelo Lee gratefully acknowledges the Brooklyn Law School Dean’s Summer Research Stipend’s financial support for this project. The authors would like to thank Doug Allen and the anonymous reviewers for their valuable comments on an earlier draft. All errors are ours alone.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Henry E. Smith.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Lee, B.A., Smith, H.E. The nature of Coasean property. Int Rev Econ 59, 145–155 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1007/s12232-012-0152-2

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s12232-012-0152-2

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation