Skip to main content
Log in

A comment on the locations of firms in Cournot spatial discrimination models

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Letters in Spatial and Resource Sciences Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Hamilton et al. (Regional Science and Urban Economics 19:87–102, 1989) claim that under certain conditions Cournot spatial discrimination always yields agglomeration of firms. However, I provide a counter-example that shows that this claim is not correct.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See for instance Anderson and Neven (1991), Mayer (2000) and Biscaia and Mota 2013.

  2. See Puu (2008) for the derivation of the hyperbolic demand function from standard utility functions. The hyperbolic demand has been adopted for example in “rent-seeking” games [Szidarovsky and Okuguchi (1997); Chiarella and Szidarovsky (2002)], equilibrium (in)stability models [Puu (1991, 2008)] and differential oligopoly models [Lambertini (2010); Lamantia (2011)]. Colombo (2014) considers equilibrium locations under the hyperbolic demand function in the case of linear transportation costs. He considers both the case of Bertrand and Cournot competition. The present note is related to Hamilton et al. (1989) generalization for the case of quadratic transportation costs. While under linear transportation costs agglomeration of firms never emerges in equilibrium [Colombo (2014)], under quadratic transportation costs both dispersion and agglomeration of firms may emerge in equilibrium (see later).

  3. This assumption guarantees that in equilibrium each consumer has a non-negative utility even when the hyperbolic demand function is derived from a log-linear utility function as: \(U(Q)=\ln [Q]+y\), where \(y\) is the numeraire good. Indeed, under the above parameter assumption, the quantity served at each location is never less than one.

  4. By running \(\frac{\partial \Pi _A }{\partial x_A }\), then substituting \(x_B =1-x_A \), and finally equating to zero, we get the first-order conditions in the case of symmetric locations of firms, that is:

    \(\frac{\sqrt{t\Gamma } }{2}\left[ {\frac{\sqrt{t} [16c^2+tc(11-28x_A +28x_A ^2)+t^2\Gamma (2-3x_A +3x_A ^2)]}{(4c+t\Gamma )[2c+t-2tx_A (1-x_A )]^2}-\frac{[8c+t\Gamma \arctan \sqrt{t /{(4c+t\Gamma )}} ]}{\sqrt{(4c+t\Gamma )^3} }} \right] =0\), where \(\Gamma \equiv (1-2x_A )^2\). As the first-order-conditions involve transcendental equations, an analytical solution is impossible to derive. Therefore, we need to adopt numerical simulations.

  5. The second-order condition and the global-stability condition [Sydsaeter and Hammond (1995); Liang et al. (2012)] are also verified numerically. Due to symmetry, I plot only Firm \(A\)’s location. In Fig. 1 it is also reported the maximum admissible level of parameter \(c\), given the value of \(t\) and the restriction \(c<{(1-t)} / 2\).

  6. Along these lines, it can be argued that the incentive to locate closer to each other in the space is stronger under concave demand functions than under linear or convex demand functions.

  7. The non-monotonic impact of the marginal costs is subtle. When \(c\) increases, the quantity served by Firm \(A\) to closer (farther) consumers diminishes (increases), as \(\frac{\partial q_{I,x} *}{\partial c}=\frac{-2c+T_I (x)-3T_{-I} (x)}{(2c+T_I (x)+T_{-I} (x))^3}\), which is positive (negative) when \(T_I (x)\ge (\le )2c+3T_{-I} (x)\). Therefore, Firm \(A\) has a lower incentive to move to the right to increase the quantity at locations \(x\ge x_A \), but at the same time the locations \(x\ge x_A \) are now more relevant in terms of overall transportation costs. For low levels of \(c\), the former effect prevails and greater dispersion emerges, whereas for high levels of \(c\), the latter effect prevails and lower dispersion emerges.

  8. In traditional articles of Cournot spatial discrimination as Hamilton et al. (1989) and Anderson and Neven (1991), the equilibrium locations of the firms are mainly explained by using the transportation cost argument. For example, [Hamilton et al. (1989), p. 92] claim that “...each firm is located so as to minimize transportation costs associated with its sales patters. No benefits from differentiated locations are therefore obtained” [a similar explanation is provided by Anderson and Neven (1991), p. 800]. However, this argument may be not sufficient under convex demand functions, as under convex demand the strategic effect at the locations near to the left endpoint of the segment becomes stronger, and this may determine a dispersed equilibrium.

References

  • Anderson, S., Neven, D.: Cournot competition yields spatial agglomeration. Int. Econ. Rev. 32, 793–807 (1991)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Biscaia, R., Mota, I.: Models of spatial competition: a critical review. Pap. Reg. Sci. 92, 851–871 (2013)

    Google Scholar 

  • Colombo, S.: Location choices with a non-linear demand function. Pap. Reg. Sci. (2014). doi:10.1111/pirs.12122

  • Chiarella, C., Szidarovsky, F.: The asymptotic behaviour of dynamic rent-seeking games. Comput. Math. Appl. 43, 169–178 (2002)

  • Hamilton, J.H., Thisse, J.F., Weskamp, A.: Spatial discrimination: Bertrand vs Cournot in a model of location choice. Reg. Sci. Urban Econ. 19, 87–102 (1989)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lamantia, F.: A nonlinear duopoly with efficient production-capacity levels. Comput. Econ. 38, 295–309 (2011)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lambertini, L.: Oligopoly with hyperbolic demand: a differential game approach. J. Optim. Theory Appl. 145, 108–119 (2010)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Liang, W.J., Lin, Y.J., Hwang, H.: Heterogeneous duopoly, spatially discriminatory pricing, and optimal location. Ann. Reg. Sci. 49, 845–860 (2012)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mayer, T.: Spatial Cournot competition and heterogeneous production costs across locations. Reg. Sci. Urban Econ. 30, 325–352 (2000)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Puu, T.: Chaos in duopoly pricing. Chaos Solitons Fractals 1, 573–581 (1991)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Puu, T.: On the stability of Cournot equilibrium with the number of competitors increases. J. Econ. Behav. Organ. 66, 445–456 (2008)

  • Sydsaeter, K., Hammond, P.J.: Mathematics for economic analysis. Prentice-Hall International, London (1995)

    Google Scholar 

  • Szidarovsky, F., Okuguchi, K.: On the existence and uniqueness of pure Nash equilibrium in rent-seeking game. Games Econ. Behav. 18, 135–140 (1997)

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Stefano Colombo.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Colombo, S. A comment on the locations of firms in Cournot spatial discrimination models. Lett Spat Resour Sci 8, 119–124 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s12076-014-0117-z

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s12076-014-0117-z

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation