Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Modeling technical change in climate analysis: evidence from agricultural crop damages

  • Research Article
  • Published:
Environmental Science and Pollution Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This study accounts for the Hicks neutral technical change in a calibrated model of climate analysis, to identify the optimum level of technical change for addressing climate changes. It demonstrates the reduction to crop damages, the costs to technical change, and the net gains for the adoption of technical change for a climate-sensitive Pakistan economy. The calibrated model assesses the net gains of technical change for the overall economy and at the agriculture-specific level. The study finds that the gains of technical change are overwhelmingly higher than the costs across the agriculture subsectors. The gains and costs following technical change differ substantially for different crops. More importantly, the study finds a cost-effective optimal level of technical change that potentially reduces crop damages to a minimum possible level. The study therefore contends that the climate policy for Pakistan should consider the role of technical change in addressing climate impacts on the agriculture sector.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9
Fig. 10

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Contributes 21% to gross domestic product (GDP) and 44% to employment in 2013–2014.

  2. Climate change mitigation refers to efforts to reduce or prevent emission of greenhouse gases. Mitigation can mean using new technologies and renewable energies, making older equipment more energy efficient, or changing management practices or consumer behavior.

  3. Adaptation is the principal way to deal with the impacts of a changing climate. It involves taking practical actions to manage risks from climate impacts, protect communities and strengthen the resilience of the economy.

  4. The simple nature of the model is retained because it provides transparent unification of growth theory and climate science with few equations that can be easily understood and manipulated.

  5. Climate change is a typical example of a public good that entails the global common good, and climate damage in one country will also bring calamities to other countries.

  6. The fluctuating parameters are (i) initial concentration in atmosphere, (ii) initial concentration in upper and lower strata, (iii) equilibrium concentration atmosphere, (iv) equilibrium concentration in lower and upper strata, (v) equilibrium temperature impact (0 °C per doubling of CO2), (vi) initial lower stratum temperature change (0 °C from 1900), (vii) initial atmospheric temperature change (0 °C from 1900), and (viii) climatic damage intercepts.

  7. Appendix 3 shows the sector-specific output of all downstream agricultural sectors. All the sectors are grouped into three categories. Categories A, B, and C refer to major crops, minor crops, and meat and milk, respectively.

  8. These are the damages calculated with zero level of additional technical change in the PCE model, and represented as P in Table 1.

References

  • Adger WN (2010) Social capital, collective action, and adaptation to climate change. In: Voss M (ed) Der Klimawandel. VS Verlag für Sozialwissenschaften, pp 327–345. doi:10.1007/978-3-531-92258-4_19

    Google Scholar 

  • Asseng S, Ewert F, Rosenzweig C et al. (2013) Uncertainty in simulating wheat yields under climate change. Nat Clim Chang 3(9):827–832

  • Baker E, Clarke L, Shittu E (2008) Technical change and the marginal cost of abatement. Energ Econ 30:2799–2816

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barker T, Pan H, Köhler J, Warren R, Winne S (2006) Decarbonizing the global economy with induced technological change: scenarios to 2100 using E3MG. Energy J 27:241–258

    Google Scholar 

  • Bosetti V, Tavoni M (2009) Uncertain R&D, backstop technology and GHGs stabilization. Energ Econ 31:S18–S26

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bruinsma J (2003) World agriculture: towards 2015/2030: an FAO perspective

  • Buonanno P, Carraro C, Galeotti M (2003) Endogenous induced technical change and the costs of Kyoto. Resour Energy Econ 25:11–34

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clarke L, Weyant J, Edmonds J (2008) On the sources of technological change: what do the models assume? Energy Econ 30:409–424

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dell M, Jones BF, Olken BA (2012) Temperature shocks and economic growth: evidence from the last half century. Am Econ J Macroecon 4(3):66–95

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dietz S, Asheim GB (2012) Climate policy under sustainable discounted utilitarianism. J Environ Econ Manag 63(3):321–335

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dietz S, Stern N (2015) Endogenous growth, convexity of damage and climate risk: how Nordhaus’ framework supports deep cuts in carbon emissions. Econ J 125(583):574–620

    Google Scholar 

  • Dufresne JL, Foujols MA, Denvil S et al. (2013) Climate change projections using the IPSL-CM5 earth system model: from CMIP3 to CMIP5. Clim Dyn 40:2123–2165

  • Easterling WE et al. (2007) Food, fibre and forest products Climate change: 273–313

  • Edenhofer O, Lessmann K, Kemfert C, Grubb M, Köhler J (2006) Induced technological change: exploring its implications for the economics of atmospheric stabilization: synthesis report from the innovation modeling comparison project. Energy J 27:57–107

    Google Scholar 

  • Gerlagh R, Van der Zwaan B (2006) Options and instruments for a deep cut in CO2 emissions: carbon dioxide capture or renewables, taxes or subsidies? Energy J 27:25–48

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gillingham K, Newell RG, Pizer WA (2008) Modeling endogenous technological change for climate policy analysis. Energy Econ 30:2734–2753

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Golding N, Betts R (2008) Fire risk in Amazonia due to climate change in the HadCM3 climate model: potential interactions with deforestation. Glob Biogeochem Cycle 22:1–10. doi:10.1029/2007GB003166

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • GoP (2012) Economic survey of Pakistan Ministry of Finance. Government of Pakistan, Islamabad

    Google Scholar 

  • Grübler A, Messner S (1998) Technological change and the timing of mitigation measures. Energy Econ 20:495–512

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hicks JR (1939) The foundations of welfare economics. Econ J 49:696–712

    Google Scholar 

  • Jacobsen HK (2001) Technological progress and long-term energy demand—a survey of recent approaches and a Danish case. Energy Policy 29:147–157

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Köhler J, Grubb M, Popp D, Edenhofer O (2006) The transition to endogenous technical change in climate-economy models: a technical overview to the innovation modeling comparison project. Energy J 27:17–55

    Google Scholar 

  • Lee DS et al. (2009) Aviation and global climate change in the 21st century. Atmos Environ 43:3520–3537

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Lempert RJ, Collins MT (2007) Managing the risk of uncertain threshold responses: comparison of robust, optimum, and precautionary approaches. Risk Anal 27(4):1009–1026

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lobell DB (2012) Gourdji SM. The influence of climate change on global crop productivity Plant Physiol 160:1686–1697

    CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Lofgren H, Harris RL, Robinson S (2002) A standard computable general equilibrium (CGE) model in GAMS vol 5. Intl Food Policy Res Inst

  • Löschel A (2002) Technological change in economic models of environmental policy: a survey. Ecol Econ 43:105–126

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mustafa Z (2011) Climate change and its impact with special focus in Pakistan. vol 33

  • Nordhaus WD (1991) To slow or not to slow: the economics of the greenhouse effect. Econ J 101(407):920

  • Nordhaus WD (1994) Expert opinion on climatic change. Am Scientist 82:45–51

    Google Scholar 

  • Nordhaus WD (2008) A question of balance: weighing the options on global warming policies. Yale University Press, New Haven

  • Nordhaus WD, Boyer J (2000) Warming the world: economic models of global warming. MIT Press, Cambridge

  • Parry ML, Rosenzweig C, Iglesias A, Livermore M, Fischer G (2004) Effects of climate change on global food production under SRES emissions and socio-economic scenarios. Global Environ Chang 14:53–67

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rogelj J, McCollum DL, Reisinger A, Meinshausen M, Riahi K (2013) Probabilistic cost estimates for climate change mitigation. Nature 493:79–83

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scarf HE, Shoven JB (2008) Applied general equilibrium analysis. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Singh BK, Bardgett RD, Smith P, Reay DS (2010) Microorganisms and climate change: terrestrial feedbacks and mitigation options. Nat Rev Microbiol 8:779–790

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Smit B, Pilifosova O (2003) Adaptation to climate change in the context of sustainable development and equity. Sustain Dev 8:9

    Google Scholar 

  • Statistics PBo (1991) Input output tables. Statistics House, 21-Mauve Area, G-9/1, Islamabad

    Google Scholar 

  • Stern N (2013) The structure of economic modeling of the potential impacts of climate change: grafting gross underestimation of risk onto already narrow science models. J Econ Lit 51 (3):838–859

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stern NH, Treasury HMs (2006) Stern review: the economics of climate change vol 30. HM treasury, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Stocker TD, Qin GK, Plattner M et al. (2014) Climate change 2013: the physical science basis. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

  • Sultana H, Ali N, Iqbal MM, Khan AM (2009) Vulnerability and adaptability of wheat production in different climatic zones of Pakistan under climate change scenarios. Clim Chang 94:123–142

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Warren R et al. (2013) Quantifying the benefit of early climate change mitigation in avoiding biodiversity loss. Nat Clim Chang 3:678–682

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weitzman ML (2009a) On modeling and interpreting the economics of catastrophic climate change. Rev Econ Stat 91:1–19

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weitzman ML (2009b) On modeling and interpreting the economics of catastrophic climate change. Rev Econ Stat 91:1–19

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weitzman ML (2012) GHG targets as insurance against catastrophic climate damages. Journal of Public Economic Theory 14(2):221–244

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wing IS (2008) Explaining the declining energy intensity of the US economy. Resour Energy Econ 30:21–49

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yohe G, Strzepek K (2007) Adaptation and mitigation as complementary tools for reducing the risk of climate impacts. Mitig Adapt Strateg Glob Chang 12(5):727–739

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Adeel Ahmed.

Additional information

Responsible editor: Philippe Garrigues

Electronic supplementary material

ESM 1

(DOCX 488 kb).

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Ahmed, A., Devadason, E.S. & Al-Amin, A.Q. Modeling technical change in climate analysis: evidence from agricultural crop damages. Environ Sci Pollut Res 24, 12347–12359 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11356-017-8747-5

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11356-017-8747-5

Keywords

Navigation