Skip to main content
Log in

Gray Marketing: Does It Hurt the Manufacturers?

  • Published:
Atlantic Economic Journal Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

It is generally believed that the existence of gray channels hurts authorized retailers because gray marketers often free-ride on the marketing activities performed by authorized retailers. However, the effect on manufacturers’ profits is still rather vague. This paper sets up a two-stage sub-game perfect equilibrium model to examine the effects of gray goods on authorized retailers and manufacturers. It is found that manufacturers who are against parallel importation are likely to be those whose product has a low gray good penetration ratio, low price elasticity of demand, high cross-price elasticity of demand, or a high demand convexity.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The mathematical details are available upon request from the author.

  2. The marginal benefit of service is measured by p S x as shown in Eq. 6. Its value declines as the sales of the authorized product decrease.

  3. The two axes in Fig. 1 represent the sale and service levels of the authorized retailer respectively. The slope of π x  = 0 is defined by \({\raise0.7ex\hbox{${{\text{d}}S}$} \!\mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{{\text{d}}S} {{\text{d}}x}}}\right.\kern-\nulldelimiterspace}\!\lower0.7ex\hbox{${{\text{d}}x}$}}\left| {_{\pi _x = 0} } \right. = - {\raise0.7ex\hbox{${\pi _{xx} }$} \!\mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{\pi _{xx} } {\pi _{xS} }}}\right.\kern-\nulldelimiterspace}\!\lower0.7ex\hbox{${\pi _{xS} }$}}\) which is positive as π xx  < 0 and π xS  > 0. Its intercept is \(x = {\raise0.7ex\hbox{${\omega - p}$} \!\mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{\omega - p} {p_x }}}\right.\kern-\nulldelimiterspace}\!\lower0.7ex\hbox{${p_x }$}} >0\) which can be derived by substituting S = 0 into the π x  = 0 function to yields \(\pi _x \left| {_{S = 0} } \right. = p_x \left( {x;g,0} \right)x + p\left( {x;g,0} \right) - \omega = 0\). Similarly, the slope of π s  = 0 is \({\raise0.7ex\hbox{${{\text{d}}S}$} \!\mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{{\text{d}}S} {{\text{d}}x}}}\right.\kern-\nulldelimiterspace}\!\lower0.7ex\hbox{${{\text{d}}x}$}}\left| {_{\pi _s = 0} } \right. = - {\raise0.7ex\hbox{${\pi _{Sx} }$} \!\mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{\pi _{Sx} } {\pi _{SS} }}}\right.\kern-\nulldelimiterspace}\!\lower0.7ex\hbox{${\pi _{SS} }$}} >0\), and its intercept on the x axis is \(x = {\raise0.7ex\hbox{${f_S }$} \!\mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{f_S } {p_S }}}\right.\kern-\nulldelimiterspace}\!\lower0.7ex\hbox{${p_S }$}} >0\). Compare the two intercepts, we obtain: \({\raise0.7ex\hbox{${{\text{d}}S}$} \!\mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{{\text{d}}S} {{\text{d}}x}}}\right.\kern-\nulldelimiterspace}\!\lower0.7ex\hbox{${{\text{d}}x}$}}\left| {_{\pi _x = 0} } \right. - {\raise0.7ex\hbox{${{\text{d}}S}$} \!\mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{{\text{d}}S} {{\text{d}}x}}}\right.\kern-\nulldelimiterspace}\!\lower0.7ex\hbox{${{\text{d}}x}$}}\left| {_{\pi \; = 0} } \right. = {\raise0.7ex\hbox{${ - \pi _{xx} \pi _{SS} + \pi _{Sx}^2 }$} \!\mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{ - \pi _{xx} \pi _{SS} + \pi _{Sx}^2 } {\pi _{xx} \pi _{xS} }}}\right.\kern-\nulldelimiterspace}\!\lower0.7ex\hbox{${\pi _{xx} \pi _{xS} }$}} = {\raise0.7ex\hbox{${ - D}$} \!\mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{ - D} {\pi _{xx} \pi _{xS} }}}\right.\kern-\nulldelimiterspace}\!\lower0.7ex\hbox{${\pi _{xx} \pi _{xS} }$}} >0\). It indicates that the slope of π x  = 0 is greater than that of π S  = 0. Consequently, we have π x  = 0 and π S  = 0 curves as shown in Fig. 1.

  4. As \({\raise0.7ex\hbox{${{\text{d}}x}$} \!\mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{{\text{d}}x} {{\text{d}}x}}}\right.\kern-\nulldelimiterspace}\!\lower0.7ex\hbox{${{\text{d}}x}$}}\left| {_S = {\raise0.7ex\hbox{${ - p{}_x\left( {\bar S} \right)}$} \!\mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{ - p{}_x\left( {\bar S} \right)} {\pi _{xx} }}}\right.\kern-\nulldelimiterspace}\!\lower0.7ex\hbox{${\pi _{xx} }$}}} \right. <0\), an increase in the volume of the gray goods shifts the π x  = 0 curve to the left.

  5. The mathematical details are available upon request from the author.

  6. The derivation of Eq. 12 is as follows: \(\frac{{{\text{d}}\Pi }}{{{\text{d}}g}} = \frac{{\partial \Pi }}{{\partial x}}\left[ {\frac{{\partial x}}{{\partial \omega }}\frac{{\partial \omega }}{{\partial g}} + \frac{{\partial x}}{{\partial g}}} \right] + \frac{{\partial \Pi }}{{\partial \omega }}\frac{{\partial \omega }}{{\partial g}} + \frac{{\partial \Pi }}{{\partial g}} = \left( {\omega - c} \right)\left( {x_\omega \omega _g + x_g } \right) + \left( {\omega - c} \right)\) (since \(\frac{{\partial \Pi }}{{\partial \omega }} = 0\))\( = \left( {\omega - c} \right)\left[ {x_\omega \frac{{ - \left( {x_g + 1} \right)}}{{\Pi _{\omega \omega } }} + \left( {x_g + 1} \right)} \right] = \left( {\omega - c} \right)\left( {x_g + 1} \right)\left( {\frac{{\Pi _{\omega \omega } - x_\omega }}{{\Pi _{\omega \omega } }}} \right) = \frac{1}{2}\left( {\omega - c} \right)\left( {x_g + 1} \right)\) (since \(\Pi _{\omega \omega } = 2x_\omega \)).

  7. Given S, the profit function of the authorized retailer becomes of x only: π = π(x). Its first-order condition for profit maximization consists of Eq. 4 only. Totally differentiate this equation with respect to x, S and g yields the following comparative static effects: \(\frac{{{\text{d}}x}}{{{\text{d}}g}}\left| {_S } \right. = \frac{{ - \pi _{xg} }}{{\pi _{xx} }} = \frac{{ - \left( {1 + \alpha } \right)\left( {p_{xg} x + p_g } \right)}}{{p_{xx} x + 2p_x }} = \frac{{ - \left( {1 + \alpha } \right)^2 \left( {p_{xx} x + p_x } \right)}}{{p_{xx} x + 2p_x }}\) and \(\frac{{{\text{d}}x}}{{{\text{d}}S}} = - \frac{{\pi _{xS} }}{{\pi _{xx} }} = - \frac{{p_S }}{{\pi _{xx} }}\) .

  8. The second-order condition for profit maximization requires.\(\pi _{xx} = p_{xx} x + 2p_x <0\) It is satisfied if \(\delta >- 2\).

  9. This result can be explained by the following example. Imports of Benz Mercedes through a gray market would do more damages to the local price of the car than the same amount of imports through the authorized channel. Moreover, an increase in pirate goods would cause the price of the legitimate goods to plunge.

References

  • Anderson, S. P., & Ginsburg, V. A. (1999). International pricing with costly consumer arbitrage. Review of International Economics, 7(1), 126–139.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bolton, P., & Bonanno, G. (1988). Vertical restraints in a model of vertical differentiation. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 103(3), 555–570.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen, Y., & Maskus, L. E. (2005). Vertical pricing and parallel imports. Journal of International Trade & Economic Development, 14(1), 1–18.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Choi, J. C., & Shin, H. S. (1992). A comment on a model of vertical product differentiation. The Journal of Industrial Economics, 40(2), 229–231.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Creamer, H., & Thisse, J. F. (1994). Commodity taxation in a differentiated oligopoly. International Economic Review, 35(3), 613–633.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eagle, L., Kitchen, P. J., Rose, L., & Moyle, B. (2003). Brand equity and brand vulnerability: the impact of gray marketing/parallel importing on brand equity and values. European Journal of Marketing, 37(10), 1332–1349.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gabszewicz, J., & Thisse, J. (1979). Price competition, quality and income disparities. Journal of Economic Theory, 20(3), 340–359.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gabszewicz, J., & Thisse, J. (1982). Product differentiation with income disparities: an illustrative model. Journal of Industrial Economics, 31(1/2), 115–129.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gallini, N. T., & Hollis, A. (1999). A contractual approach to the gray market. International Review of Law and Economics, 19(1), 1–21.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Inman, J. E. (1993). Gray marketing of imported trademarked goods: tariffs and trademark issues. American Business Law Journal, 31(1), 59–116.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Landes, W. M., & Posner, A. R. (1987). Trademark law: an economic perspective. Journal of Law and Economics, 30(2), 265–309.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malueg, D. A., & Schwartz, M. (1994). Parallel imports, demand dispersion, and international price discrimination. Journal of International Economics, 37(3/4), 167–195.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mathewson, F., & Winter, R. (1984). An economic theory of vertical restraints. Rand Journal of Economics, 15(1), 27–38.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mathur, L. K. (1995). The impact of international gray marketing on consumers and firms. Journal of European Marketing, 4(2), 39–59.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mitchell, A. (1998). Customer rights a grey area in distribution ban. Marketing Week, 21(21), 30–31.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mussa, M., & Rosen, S. (1978). Monopoly and product quality. Journal of Economic Theory, 18(2), 301–317.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • National Economic Research Associates. (1999). The economic consequences of the choice of regime in the area of trademarks. London: NERA.

    Google Scholar 

  • Palmeter, N. D., & Remington, M. (1988). Gray market imports: no black and white answer; comments on K mart v. Cartier: gray market trade and EEC law. Journal of World Trade, 22(5), 89–103.

    Google Scholar 

  • Richardson, M. (2002). An elementary proposition concerning parallel imports. Journal of International Economics, 56(1), 233–245.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shepherd, W. G. (1997). The economic industrial organization (4th ed.). Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Telser, L. (1990). Why should manufacturers want fair trade II? Journal of Law and Economics, 33(2), 409–418.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • The Economist. (1998). When grey is good. 348(8082), 17.

  • Voyle S. (2003). Levi’s leaps into mass market: it fought the stores that sold its jeans cheap. Now the US group has bowed to the inevitable with a cut-price rates. Financial Times, May 1, 12.

  • Wauthy, X. (1996). Quality choice in model of vertical differentiation. The Journal of Industrial Economics, 44(3), 345–354.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Hsiu-Li Chen.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Chen, HL. Gray Marketing: Does It Hurt the Manufacturers?. Atl Econ J 37, 23–35 (2009). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11293-008-9154-6

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11293-008-9154-6

Keywords

JEL

Navigation