Skip to main content
Log in

Using equity premium survey data to estimate future wealth

  • Original Research
  • Published:
Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We present the first systematic methods for combining different experts’ responses to equity premium surveys. These techniques are based on the observation that the survey data are approximately gamma distributed. This distribution has convenient analytical properties that enable us to address three important problems that investment managers must face. First, we construct probability density functions for the future values of equity index tracker funds. Second, we calculate unbiased and minimum least square error estimators of the future value of these funds. Third, we derive optimal asset allocation weights between equities and the risk-free asset for risk-averse investors. Our analysis allows for both herding and biasedness in expert responses. We show that, unless investors are highly uncertain about expert biases or forecasts are very highly correlated, many investment decisions can be based solely on the mean of the survey data minus any expected bias. We also make recommendations for the design of future equity premium surveys.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The equity premium is a parameter that also has a number of applications beyond investment management. In particular, it is a key input variable in the Capital Asset Pricing Model, which is commonly used in calculating the cost of equity capital for capital budgeting purposes. The techniques that we discuss below would also be relevant in these contexts, but we do not explicitly explore these issues in this paper.

  2. According to the Pension Protection Fund the net funding position of defined benefit pension plans in the UK swung from a surplus of £161.2bn (June 2007) to a deficit of £180.2bn (March 2009), back again to a surplus of £50.1bn (January 2011) before returning to a deficit of £317.0bn (May 2012). At the time of writing, the deficit stands at £27.6bn (December 2013).

  3. The raw data are available at at http://www.ivo-welch.info/academics/equpdate-results2009.htm. Our results are largely insensitive to the choice of survey question used.

  4. Of course, since \(E\) is finite, \(f\left( \lambda _{i}\right)\) must be a discrete distribution while \(\varGamma \left( \alpha,\beta \right)\) is continuous. Therefore, strictly, \(\lim _{E\rightarrow \infty }\lambda _{p}=\alpha /\beta\) . However, we assume that \(E\) is sufficiently large for this distinction to not be of relevance.

  5. The maximum likelihood estimators that we use for \(\widehat{\alpha }\) and \(\widehat{ \beta }\) given the sample of responses are reported in, inter alia, Grice and Bain (1980): \(\ln \left( \widehat{\alpha }\right) -\psi \left( \widehat{\alpha }\right) =\ln \left( \overline{\lambda }/\widetilde{\lambda } \right)\) and \(\widehat{\alpha }/\widehat{\beta }=\overline{\lambda }\). Here \(\psi \left( \cdot \right)\) is the digamma function and \(\overline{ \lambda },\widetilde{\lambda }\) respectively represent the arithmetic and geometric means of the survey data. We use these estimators throughout, even when we assume there is correlation between expert forecasts. In unreported results, available on request from the authors, we demonstrate that our results have low sensitivity to the estimated values of \(\widehat{ \alpha },\widehat{\beta }\).

  6. It is, in general, necessary to distinguish between the observed cross-sectional variance of the transformed sample data, \(\sigma _{Y}^{2}\), and the variance of \(u_{i},\,\sigma _{u}^{2}\), which reflects the accuarcy of an individual forecast. For example, if all experts make identical, but equally incorrect, forecasts then \(\sigma _{Y}^{2}=0\) (all forecasts are the same) but \(\sigma _{u}^{2}>0\) (all experts are in error). See Freeman and Groom (in press) and the “Appendix” to this paper for more detailed discussions of this point.

  7. The term \(\widehat{\sigma }_{u}^{2}=\,\widehat{\sigma }_{Y}^{2}/\kappa\) is the estimated variance of each transformed forecast error. However, it is \(\sigma _{Y}^{2}\) that is observed and not \(\sigma _{u}^{2}\), and this is reflected in this formula. When \(\rho =0\), \(\widehat{\sigma }_{Y}^{2}= \widehat{\sigma }_{u}^{2}\), but this is not true more generally. See also footnote 6 and the “Appendix”.

  8. See Freeman and Groom (in press) for a discussion on how \(N\) is calculated. This is based on the assumption that \({\varvec{\Sigma}}_{u}\) is known rather than estimated with error and we do not alter that analysis here. We make this simplification because \(N\) is an indicative number only and is not used in further calculations.

  9. When \(x\) and \(y\) are independent, \(\sigma _{\left( x+y\right) }^{2}\,= \sigma _{x}^{2}+\sigma _{y}^{2},\,skew\left( x+y\right) \,=\left( \sigma _{x}^{3}skew_{x}+\sigma _{y}^{3}skew_{y}\right) /\sigma _{x+y}^{3}\) and \(kurt\left( x+y\right) =\left( \sigma _{x}^{4}kurt_{x}+\sigma _{y}^{4}kurt_{y}\right) /\sigma _{x+y}^{4}\).

  10. Notice that, if the survey data were unbiased, uncorrelated and normally distributed, \(\lambda _{i}\sim N(\lambda _{H},\sigma _{\lambda }^{2}),\) then \(\overline{\lambda }\sim N\left( \lambda _{H},\sigma _{\lambda }^{2}/n\right)\). In this case, \(I_{1}=\exp \left( H\lambda _{H}+0.5H^{2}\sigma _{\lambda }^{2}/n\right)\) and \(I_{2}=\exp \left( 2H\lambda _{H}+2H^{2}\sigma _{\lambda }^{2}/n\right)\). Given this \(A_{1}=H\sigma _{\lambda }^{2}/2n\) and \(A_{2}=3H\sigma _{\lambda }^{2}/2n\). These results are reported in Jacquier et al. (2005).

  11. As this utility function has constant relative risk aversion, the proportion invested in the risky asset is invariant to the level of initial wealth.

  12. The result of Jacquier et al. (2005) emerges when \(N=\infty ,\,\mu _{\omega }=0\) and \(\sigma _{\omega }^{2}=\sigma _{e}^{2}/T\).

  13. Although Tsai and Wu (2014) find an inverted U-shaped weighting for equity with time to retirement in a model with non-constant income growth and time-varying investment opportunities.

  14. As discussed in early footnotes, it is necessary to distinguish between the cross-sectional variation of responses, \(\sigma _{Y}^{2},\) and the variance of individual forecast errors, \(\sigma _{u}^{2};\,\sigma _{u}^{2}=\sigma _{Y}^{2}/\kappa\) where \(\kappa =1\) when \(\rho =0\). To account for this distinction, the Inverse Gamma function is calibrated to \(\alpha ^{*}\) and \(\beta ^{*}\), where \(\alpha ^{*}=\alpha \kappa ^{-1}\) and \(\beta ^{*}=\beta \kappa ^{-1}.\) The formula for \(\kappa\) in the case of exponential correlation is given in Eq. 5. We discuss this distinction in more detail below.

  15. See, for example, Grice and Bain (1980).

References

  • Barberis N (2000) Investing for the long run when returns are predictable. J Financ 60:225–264

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blume M (1974) Unbiased estimators of long-run expected rates of returns. J Am Stat Assoc 69:634–663

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clemen RL, Winkler RL (1985) Limits for the precision and value of information from dependent sources. Oper Res 33:427–442

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cooper I (1996) Arithmetic versus geometric mean estimators: setting discount rates for capital budgeting. Eur Financ Manag 2:157–167

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fama EF, French KR (2002) The equity premium. J Financ 57:637–659

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fernandez P, del Campo J (2010a) Market risk premium used in 2010 by professors: a survey with 1,500 answers. Working paper; http://ssrn.com/abstract=1606563

  • Fernandez P, del Campo J (2010b) Market risk premium used in 2010 by analysts and companies: a survey with 2,400 answers. Working paper; http://ssrn.com/abstract=1609563

  • Ferstl R, Weissensteiner A (2011) Asset-liability management under time-varying investment opportunities. J Bank Financ 35:182–192

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Financial Services Authority (2012) Rates of return for FSA prescribed projections. London.

  • Freeman MC (2011) The time-varying equity premium and the S&P500 in the twentieth century. J Financ Res 34:179–215

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Freeman MC, Groom B (in press) Positively gamma discounting: combining the opinions of experts on the social discount rate. Econ J. doi:10.1111/ecoj.12129

  • Hawkins DM, Wixley RAJ (1986) A note on the transformation of Chi-squared variables to normality. Am Stat 40:296–298

    Google Scholar 

  • Hernandez F, Johnson RA (1980) The large-sample behavior of transformations to normality. J Am Stat Assoc 75:855–861

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gollier C (2004) Maximizing the expected net future value as an alternative strategy to gamma discounting. Financ Res Lett 1:85–89

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Graham JR (1996) Is a group of economists better than one? Than none? J Bus 69:193–232

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Graham JR, Harvey CR (2010) The equity risk premium in 2010. Working paper; http://ssrn.com/abstract=1654026

  • Grice JV, Bain LJ (1980) Inferences concerning the mean of the gamma distribution. J Am Stat Assoc 75:929–933

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ho L-C, Tsay J (2004) Analysts’ forecasts of Taiwanese firms’ earnings: some empirical evidence. Rev Pac Basin Financ Mark Polic 7:571–597

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hung M-W, Wang J-Y (2005) Asset prices under prospect theory and habit formation. Rev Pac Basin Financ Mark Polic 8:1–29

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Indro DC, Lee WY (1997) Biases in arithmetic and geometric averages as estimates of long-run expected returns and risk premia. Financ Manag 26(Winter):81–90

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jacquier E, Kane A, Marcus AJ (2003) Geometric or arithmetic mean: a reconsideration. Financ Anal J 59:46–53

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jacquier E, Kane A, Marcus AJ (2005) Optimal estimation of the risk premium for the long run and asset allocation: a case of compounded estimation risk. J Financ Econom 3:37–55

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jagannathan R, McGrattan ER, Scherbina A (2000) The declining U.S. equity premium. Federal Reserve Bank Minneap Q Rev 24(4):3–19

    Google Scholar 

  • Jegadeesh N, Kim W (2010) Do analysts herd? An analysis of recommendations and market reactions. Rev Financ Stud 23:901–937

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jensen JL, Kristensen LB (1991) Saddlepoint approximations to exact tests and improved likelihood ratio tests for the gamma distribution. Commun Stat Theor Methods 20:1515–1532

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jouini E, Marin J-M, Napp C (2010) Discounting and divergence of opinion. J Econ Theory 145:830–859

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kan R, Zhou G (2009) What will the likely range of my wealth be? Financ Anal J 65:68–77

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kotz S, Adams JW (1964) Distribution of sum of identically distributed exponentially correlated gamma-variables. Ann Math Stat 35:277–283

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kulkarni HV, Powar SK (2010) A new method for interval estimation of the mean of the gamma distribution. Lifetime Data Anal 16:431–447

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lettau M, Ludvigson SC, Wachter JA (2008) The declining equity premium: what role does macroeconomic risk play? Rev Financ Stud 21:1653–1687

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mehra R, Prescott EC (1985) The equity premium: a puzzle. J Monet Econ 15:145–161

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mehra R, Prescott EC (2003) The equity premium in retrospect. In: Constantinides GM, Harris M, Stulz R (eds) Handbook of the economics of finance, volume 1B: financial markets and asset pricing. North Holland

  • Merton R (1969) Lifetime portfolio selection under uncertainty: the continuous-time case. Rev Econ Stat 51:247–257

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Önkal D, Goodwin P, Thomson M, Gönül S, Pollock A (2009) The relative influence of advice from human experts and statistical methods on forecast adjustments. J Behav Decis Making 22:390–409

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ramnath S, Rock S, Shane P (2008) The financial analyst forecasting literature: a taxonomy with suggestions for further research. Int J Forecast 24:34–75

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rapach DE, Zhou G (2011) Forecasting stock returns. Working paper, Saint Louis University

  • Singh V (2013) Did institutions herd during the internet bubble? Rev Quant Financ Acc 41:513–534

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tsai H-J, Wu Y (2014) Optimal portfolio choice with asset return predictability and nontradable labor income. Rev Quant Financ Acc. doi:10.1007/s11156-014-0435-7

  • Weitzman ML (2001) Gamma discounting. Am Econ Rev 91:260–271

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weitzman ML (2010) Risk-adjusted gamma discounting. J Environ Econ Manag 60:1–13

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Welch I (2000) Views of financial economists on the equity premium and other issues. J Bus 73–4:501–537

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wilson EB, Hilferty MM (1931) The distribution of Chi-squares. P Natl Acad Sci USA 17:684–688

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Winkler RL (1981) Combining probability distributions from dependent information sources. Manag Sci 27:479–488

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wong A (1993) A note on inference for the mean parameter of the gamma distribution. Stat Probab Lett 17:61–66

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Mark C. Freeman.

Appendix

Appendix

In this appendix, we present further details of the Kulkarni and Powar (2010) OPNAM method for estimating the density function of the mean of a gamma distribution conditional on a finite sample, the Winkler (1981) method for combining correlated expert forecasts, and the application of these two methods to the problem at hand. We also, by simulation, demonstrate the accuracy of these two techniques.

1.1 Transforming the data

The OPNAM method relies on the fact that if the underlying data \(\lambda _{i}\sim \varGamma \left( \alpha ,\beta \right)\) then \(Y_{i}=\lambda _{i}^{p}\) will be approximately normally distributed for \(p=0.246\) provided that \(\alpha >1.5\). The first four moments of \(Y_{i}\) are known in closed form—we derive the first two here and note that the equivalent equations for skewness and kurtosis are given on page 437 of Kulkarni and Powar (2010). The pdf of a gamma distribution is given by:

$$\begin{aligned} f\left( \lambda _{i}\right) \sim \varGamma \left( \alpha,\beta \right) =\frac{\beta ^{\alpha }}{\varGamma \left( \alpha\right) }\lambda _{i}^{\alpha -1}e^{-\beta \lambda _{i}} \end{aligned}$$
(24)

So, the expectation of \(Y_{p}=E\left[ \lambda _{i}^{p}\right]\) is given by

$$\begin{aligned} Y_{p}&= \int _{0}^{\infty }\lambda _{i}^{p}\frac{\beta ^{\alpha }}{\varGamma \left( \alpha\right) }\lambda _{i}^{\alpha -1}e^{-\beta \lambda _{i}}d\lambda _{i}=\int _{0}^{\infty }\frac{\beta ^{\alpha }}{\varGamma \left(\alpha\right)} \lambda _{i}^{p+\alpha -1}e^{-\beta \lambda _{i}}d\lambda _{i} \\&= \frac{\varGamma \left( \alpha+p\right) }{\beta ^{p}\varGamma \left( \alpha\right) } \int _{0}^{\infty }\frac{\beta ^{p+\alpha }}{\varGamma \left( \alpha+p\right) } \lambda _{i}^{p+\alpha -1}e^{-\beta \lambda _{i}}d\lambda _{i} \nonumber \end{aligned}$$
(25)

The transformation in the last line is ‘trivial’ in the sense that it is just multiplying both the numerator and denominator by \(\beta ^{p}\varGamma \left( \alpha+p \right)\) and then rearranging. The purpose of this trivial transformation is to ensure that the term within the integral is identical to the probability density function of a gamma distribution with parameters \(\alpha +p\) and \(\beta\). Clearly as this is the integral over the whole support of well-defined pdf, it must equal one. Therefore:

$$\begin{aligned} Y_{p}=\frac{\varGamma \left( \alpha+p\right) }{\beta ^{p}\varGamma \left( \alpha\right) } =\left( \frac{\alpha }{\beta }\right) ^{p}\frac{\varGamma \left( \alpha+p\right) }{ \alpha^{p}\varGamma \left( \alpha\right) }=E\left[ \lambda _{i}\right] ^{p}\frac{\varGamma \left( \alpha+p\right) }{\alpha^{p}\varGamma \left( \alpha\right) } \end{aligned}$$
(26)

and this is Eq. 2 in the body of this paper.

The cross-sectional variance of the forecasts is given by \(\sigma _{Y}^{2}=E \left[ \lambda _{i}^{2p}\right] -E^{2}\left[ \lambda _{i}^{p}\right]\), which follows directly from the preceding argument:

$$\begin{aligned} \sigma _{Y}^{2}=\left( \frac{1}{\beta ^{p}\varGamma \left( \alpha \right) } \right) ^{2}\left[ \varGamma \left( \alpha +2p\right) \varGamma \left( \alpha\right) -\varGamma ^{2}\left( \alpha +p\right) \right] \end{aligned}$$
(27)

Similar expressions follow for the skewness and excess kurtosis and Kulkarni and Powar note that these depend on \(\alpha\) and \(p\) but not \(\beta\). Therefore the choice of \(p\) depends on \(\alpha\) only. For \(\alpha >1.5\), they select \(p=0.246\) so as to get the skewness and excess kurtosis jointly close to zero. Their method is an approximation, though, and therefore the \(Y_{i}s\) are only approximately normally distributed even if the \(\lambda _{i}s\) are perfectly gamma distributed.

A key feature to notice is that this transformation from gamma to normal does not depend on the generating process for the underlying \(\lambda _{i}s\). Therefore this applies equally well to correlated as uncorrelated forecasts. To explicitly demonstrate this, we simulated correlated gamma distributed random variables as follows. First, using a Cholesky decomposition approach, we generate 131 normally distributed \(N(0,1)\) and exponentially correlated random variables. We then convert these to correlated uniform random variables using the cumulative density function of the standard normal distribution. Finally, we take an Inverse Gamma function to convert again into correlated gamma distributed random variables, \(\lambda _{i}\).Footnote 14 We then construct the transformations \(Y_{i}=\lambda _{i}^{0.246}\) and calculate the first four moments of the transformed forecasts.

In Table 4, we report our results. In Panel A we present information on the initial correlation structure that is put into the Cholesky decomposition and the estimated correlations between \(\lambda _{i}\) and \(\lambda _{i+1}\) and \(Y_{i}\) and \(Y_{i+1}\) across the simulations (where \(i=50\) is chosen at random for illustrative purposes). This clearly demonstrates that the correlation structure remains almost entirely unaffected by the transformations that we undertake—we discuss this point further below. In Panel B we present the median values of the first four moments of the \(Y_{i}\)s across these simulations, along with lower 2.5 % and upper 97.5 % simulated values. These are compared against the theoretical values given above and in Kulkarni and Powar (2010).

Table 4 The first four moments of the transformed forecasts, \(Y_i\)

For all values of \(\rho\) considered, the theoretical predictions lie within the 95 % confidence interval and close to the observed median values. This shows the robustness of the power transformation to correlation in the experts’ forecasts.

1.2 Constructing confidence intervals for \(\alpha /\beta\)

The purpose of using the OPNAM method is to construct confidence intervals, \(L_{x}^{*}\), for the population mean (rather than survey mean), \(\lambda _{p}\), of expert responses. To do this, we first construct confidence intervals, \(L_{x}\) for the population mean, \(Y_{p}\) (as given in Eq. 26) of the transformed responses and then use Eq. 4 to construct \(L_{x}^{*}\). We do this using the “Unknown \(\Sigma\)” method described in Winkler (1981). While we assume that the correlation between experts, \(\rho ^{|i-j|}\), is known perfectly, the sample cross-sectional variance of transformed forecasts, \(\widehat{\sigma }_{Y}^{2},\) will differ from the population cross-sectional variance of transformed forecasts, \(\sigma _{Y}^{2}\). As \(\Sigma _{u|ij}=\sigma _{Y}^{2}\rho ^{|i-j|}\), this introduces sampling error into our estimate \(\widehat{\varvec{\Sigma }}_{u}\).

To overcome this problem, following Winkler (1981), we form a Bayesian prior that the “true” variance-covariance matrix is Inverse Wishart distributed with parameter value \(\delta\):

$$\begin{aligned} f\left( \varvec{\Sigma }|\widehat{\varvec{\Sigma }},\delta \right) \propto \left| \varvec{\Sigma }^{-1}\right| ^{\frac{\delta +2n}{2}}\exp \left( -\frac{\delta }{2}tr\left( \varvec{\Sigma }^{-1}\widehat{\mathbf { \Sigma }}\right) \right) \end{aligned}$$
(28)

where \(\left| \cdot \right|\) is a matrix determinant and \(tr\left( \cdot \right)\) is a matrix trace. In this case, as discussed in the body of the paper, \(Y_{p}\) is Student’s \(t\)-distributed conditional on the transformed sample data, with \(\delta +n-1\) degrees of freedom and mean \(m^{*}\) and variance \(s^{*^{2}},\) as given in Eq. 3. In the case of exponential correlation, \(\widehat{\varvec{\Sigma }} _{u}^{-1}\) is given in Eq. 5 and, from here, the expressions for \(m^{*}\) and \(s^{*^{2}}\)can be simplified by noting that:

$$\begin{aligned} {\mathbf {1}}^{\prime }\widehat{\varvec{\Sigma }}_{u}^{-1}{\mathbf {1}}&= \kappa \widehat{\sigma }_{Y}^{-2}\frac{n(1-\rho )+2\rho }{1+\rho },\quad {\mathbf {Y}} ^{\prime }\widehat{\varvec{\Sigma }}_{u}^{-1}{\mathbf {1}} = \kappa \widehat{ \sigma }_{Y}^{-2}\frac{n\overline{Y}-\rho \left( n-2\right) Y_{^{R}}}{1+\rho } \nonumber \\ {\mathbf {Y}}^{\prime }\widehat{\varvec{\Sigma }}{\mathbf {Y}}&= \kappa \widehat{ \sigma }_{Y}^{-2}\frac{nV+\rho ^{2}\left( n-2\right) V_{^{R}}-2\rho \left( n-1\right) Z}{1-\rho ^{2}} \\ V&= \frac{1}{n}\sum \limits _{i=1}^{n}Y_{i}^{2},\quad V_{R}=\frac{1}{ n-2}\sum \limits _{i=2}^{n-1}Y_{i}^{2},\quad Z=\frac{1}{n-1} \sum \limits _{i=1}^{n-1}Y_{i}Y_{i+1} \nonumber \end{aligned}$$
(29)

Therefore the only complexity that arises when operationalizing Eq. 3 is identifying the parameter \(\delta\).

1.3 Estimating \(\delta\)

To estimate \(\delta ,\) we draw upon the commonly observed parallel between the Inverse Wishart distribution and the Inverse Gamma distribution. We start with the standard assumption that the relationship between the cross-sectional sample variance and cross-sectional population variance is given by a Chi-squared distribution with \(v-1\) degrees of freedom; \(\left( v-1\right) \left( \widehat{\sigma }_{Y}^{2}/\sigma _{Y}^{2}\right) \sim \chi _{v-1}^{2}\). We explain below how \(v\) is estimated. This means that:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\widehat{\sigma }_{Y}^{2}}{\sigma _{Y}^{2}}\sim \frac{\chi _{v-1}^{2}}{ v-1}=\varGamma \left( \frac{v-1}{2},\frac{v-1}{2}\right) \end{aligned}$$
(30)

which is a gamma distribution with both shape and rate parameters equal to \(\left( v-1\right) /2\). It then follows that \(\sigma _{Y}^{2}\sim \varGamma ^{-1}\left( \frac{v-1}{2},\frac{v-1}{2}\widehat{\sigma }_{Y}^{2}\right)\), where \(\varGamma ^{-1}\left( \cdot ,\cdot \right)\) is an inverse gamma function and the second parameter is now the scale parameter. Then, by the properties of the Inverse Gamma distribution:

$$\begin{aligned} Var\left[ \sigma _{Y}^{2}\right] =\frac{2(v-1)\widehat{\sigma }_{Y}^{2}}{ \left( v-3\right) ^{2}\left( v-5\right) } \end{aligned}$$
(31)

To link this to the Inverse Wishart distribution that forms the basis for the “Unknown \(\varSigma\)” method of Winker, we note \(\sigma _{Y}^{2}=\varSigma _{u|ii}\), and therefore the variance of this variable is given by \(Var\left[ \varSigma _{u|ii}\right]\). For an Inverse Wishart distribution, the relationship between the precision of our estimate of \(\Sigma _{u|ii}\) and \(\widehat{\sigma }_{Y}^{2}\) is given by:

$$\begin{aligned} Var\left[ \varSigma _{u|ii}\right] =\frac{2\delta \widehat{\sigma }_{Y}^{2}}{ \left( \delta -2\right) ^{2}\left( \delta -4\right) } \end{aligned}$$
(32)

and by comparison of Eqs. 31 and 32 it is clear that \(\delta =v-1\).

To estimate \(v\) we take a numerical approach. We run 100,000 simulations for all \(\rho \in \{0,0.25,0.5,0.75,0.9\}\). In each case, we draw 131 exponentially correlated Normal random error terms \(u_{i}\sim N\left( 0,\sigma _{Y}^{2}\right)\), where for simulation purposes, \(\sigma _{Y}^{2}= \widehat{\sigma }_{Y}^{2}\). For each simulation, \(s\), we then calculate the cross-sectional variance of the error term, \(\widehat{\sigma }_{sY}^{2}\) . We then take the maximum likelihood estimator of \(\left( v-1\right) /2\), the shape parameter of the gamma distribution, across the 100,000 simulations.Footnote 15 The values that emerge for \(v\) for \(\rho \in \{0,\) \(0.25,\,0.5,\,0.75,0.9\}\) are, to the nearest integer, \(v=\left\{ 131\text {, }115\text {, }81\text {, }40,\text { }17\right\}\). These results are reported in more detail in Table 5. This table also compares the first four moments of \(\widehat{\sigma }_{Y}^{2}/\sigma _{Y}^{2}\) against those of a \(\varGamma \left( \left( v-1\right) /2,\left( v-1\right) /2\right)\) distribution.

Table 5 Estimates of the degrees of freedom of the Chi-squared distribution

1.4 Accuracy of the method

To demonstrate the accuracy of our joint use of the OPNAM method and Winkler’s “Unknown \(\Sigma\)” technique for combining correlated forecasts, we run a further set of simulations. Within each of 100,000 simulations, for each value of \(\rho \in \{0,0.25,0.5,0.75,0.9\}\) we draw 131 values of \(Y_{i}\) from an exponentially correlated normal distribution \(N\left( E[Y_{i}],Var\left[ Y_{i}\right] \right)\). As discussed above, both \(E\left[ Y_{i}\right]\) and \(Var\left[ Y_{i}\right]\) are known in closed form as functions of \(\alpha ,\beta\). For simulation purposes, we use the values of \(\alpha\) and \(\beta\) that are empirically estimated from Welch’s data. For each simulation, we use a combination of the Winkler (1981) “Unknown \(\Sigma\)” method described above with the Kulkarni and Powar method to derive one-sided upper and lower 0.5 %, 1 %, 1.5 %,\(\ldots\), 9.5 % and 10 % confidence intervals for \(\alpha /\beta\). We then count the proportion of simulations where the initial value of \(\alpha /\beta\) lies outside the estimated confidence interval. These results are reported in Table 6.

Table 6 Examining the confidence intervals of \(g_p(\lambda _p)\)

As can be see, in all cases there is very close agreement between the estimated confidence level and the proportion of simulations where \(\alpha /\beta\) lies outside the estimated confidence interval. This demonstrates the robustness of the method that we use to correlation in the forecasts.

1.5 The correlation structure

Finally, we turn to the correlation structure and demonstrate again that there is close agreement between the assumed correlation structure for the untransformed and transformed estimates (see also Panel A of Table 4 above). For the case of \(\rho =0.9\), we simulate 131 correlated \(Y_{i}s\) using the standard Cholesky decomposition approach and then construct values of \(\lambda _{i}=Y_{i}^{1/0.246}\). We repeat these simulations 10,000 times. In Fig. 3 we present the correlation between \(\lambda _{1}\) and \(\lambda _{j}\) for \(j\in [2,131]\) across the 10,000 simulations. This is compared against Corr\(\left( Y_{1},Y_{j}\right)\) and \(\rho ^{|1-j|}\), which is the theoretical value under exponential correlation.

Fig. 3
figure 3

The correlation between raw forecasts, \(Corr(\lambda _1,\lambda _j)\). From 131 exponentially correlated normally distributed random variables, \(Y_{i}\), we estimate the correlation of \(\lambda _{j}=Y_{j}^{1/0.246}\) against \(\lambda _{1}=Y_{1}^{1/0.246}\) for all \(j\in [2,131]\) across \(10,000\) simulations. These correlations are then compared against the theoretical value \(\rho ^{|1-j|}\) and the correlation of \(Y_{j}\) with \(Y_{1}\). This figure is constructed with \(\rho =0.9\)

It is clear that the correlation structure of the \(\lambda _{i}s\) is also very close to being exponentially correlated with \(\rho =0.9\) even though we are modelling errors on the transformed values \(Y_{i}.\)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Freeman, M.C., Groom, B. Using equity premium survey data to estimate future wealth. Rev Quant Finan Acc 45, 665–693 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11156-014-0451-7

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11156-014-0451-7

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation