Skip to main content
Log in

The Dynamic Relationship Between Housing Prices and the Macroeconomy: Evidence from OECD Countries

  • Published:
The Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper studies the dynamic relationship among house prices, income and interest rates in 15 OECD countries. We find that any disequilibrium in the long-run cointegrating relationship among these variables is corrected by the subsequent movement in house prices in most of these countries. This error-correction property of house prices implies that most of the variations in house prices are transitory, as compared to the movements in income and interest rates that are permanent, suggesting that the short-run movements in house prices are independent of the movements in income and interest rates. The results suggest that only the permanent movement in house prices, income and interest rates are associated with each other. We also find that the correlation in house price cycles across different OECD countries has changed over time with the highest correlation during the boom period of 1998–2005.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For example, see Englund and Ioannides (1997) and Himmelberg et al. (2005) among others.

  2. Our sample includes Australia, Belgium, Canada, Denmark, Finland, France, Ireland, Italy, Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway, Spain, Sweden, the U.K. and the U.S..

  3. These countries are Belgium, Canada, Denmark, France, Ireland, Italy, Norway, Spain, the U.K. and the U.S..

  4. A separate but related strand of literature focuses on the interlinkages between housing wealth, financial wealth, and consumer spending. See, for example Lettau and Ludvigson (2001, 2004), Case et al. (2005), Kishor (2007), Campbell and Cocco (2007), and Simo-Kengne et al. (2015).

  5. In the context of the linkages between aggregate wealth and consumption several studies have shown the importance of this strategy (Pichette and Tremblay 2003; Lettau and Ludvigson 2004).

  6. Zimmer (2015) studies the correlation in housing prices between four major U.S. cities and confirms that housing prices do, indeed, exhibit correlations that change over time.

  7. A more detailed description of the data can be found in Mack and Martínez-García (2011) and we acknowledge the use of this data set.

  8. The OECD database describes the short-term interest rate as either the three month interbank offer rate or the rate associated with Treasury bills, Certificates of Deposit or comparable instruments, each of three month maturity. One can also possibly argue that the long-term interest rates are more appropriate in capturing the dynamic relationship with the house prices and income. Hence, as a robustness check, we also test our results using long-term interest rates. These results are reported in the Appendix B and we find that there is no qualitative change in the results.

  9. The “hats” represent estimated value in rest of the paper.

  10. The Johansen test suggests one cointegrating vector in this system of three variables for most of the countries. Consequently, while understanding the role of permanent and transitory components we would have 3−1=2 permanent innovation and one transitory innovation.

  11. No adjustment is necessary for the possibility that the explanatory variables and error terms could be correlated. The generated regressors do not pose a problem since the estimated β s are superconsistent i.e. the true parameter converges to the true values at rate T rather than \(\sqrt {T}\) as in OLS (Stock and Watson 1988).

  12. Among the group of OECD countries, in case of Germany and Switzerland we didn’t find evidence of cointegration and the sign of the coefficients were inconsistent with the economic theory. Hence, these two countries are dropped from the sample.

  13. In an issue “The Economist” wrote that, “by slashing interest rates (by more than the Taylor rule prescribed) the Fed encouraged a house-price boom”.

  14. Apart from the important role of government in the housing markets, the mortgage products are found to have varying degree of sophistication in its characteristics like interest rate determination, loan amortization, penalties clauses, final maturity options, et cetera (Lea 2010; Scanlon et al. 2004; Girouard et al. 2006).

  15. The results do not change qualitatively and to a large extent even quantitatively if alternative criteria like Schwartz information criterion or Hannan-Quinn criterion are adopted instead.

  16. The half-life is computed as l n(0.5)/l n(1−|α h|) where |α h| represents the estimated coefficient on the lagged cointegrating residual \(\hat {\beta }^{\prime } Y_{t-1}\).

  17. Not imposing the cointegrating restrictions can lead to identification problem with the permanent and the transitory components of the model (Gonzalo and Granger 1995).

  18. Different methods have been proposed in the literature for performing trend and cycle decomposition. Beveridge and Nelson (1981) decomposition is a natural choice to perform trend and cycle decomposition in the present example since it utilizes the long-run cointegrating relationship in performing the decomposition. Moreover, as shown by Morley et al. (2003), the restrictions imposed by Beveridge-Nelson decomposition tend to be supported more by the data than an alternative trend-cycle method like an unobserved component model.

  19. The actual and trend for every variable as well as cycle of non-significant variables in the error correction process are not presented to maintain brevity. These results are available upon request.

  20. Some merit to this argument of slower adjusted of housing supply can also be found in Andrews et al. (2011).

  21. Also see Holly and Jones (1997).

  22. Scanlon et al. (2008) study the mortgage product innovation in advanced economies and report that these changes are prominent particularly in Denmark, Netherlands, and the U.K..

  23. In the context of the U.S. Zimmer (2015) finds that the correlation in house price across four major U.S. cites has changed over time with correlation strengthening during the recent financial turmoil.

  24. Splitting the whole sample into these periods may rather seem arbitrary. However, it has been chosen to reveal the changes in the housing market dynamics among these nations. Also, it better captures the nature of the recent episode of global boom-bust cycle in the housing markets.

  25. These results support the recent views expressed by the Fed Chair Janet L. Yellen. While presenting the semiannual monetary policy report to the congress before the Committee on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs on July 16, 2104 the Fed chair testified that “while prices of real estate, equities, and corporate bonds have risen appreciably and valuation metrics have increased, they remain generally in line with historical norms.”

References

  • Adams, Z., & Füss, R. (2010). Macroeconomic determinants of international housing markets. Journal of Housing Economics, 19(1), 38–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andrews, D., Sánchez, A.C., & Johansson, Å. (2011). Housing markets and structural policies in OECD countries.

  • Annett, A. (2005). House prices and monetary policy in the euro area. Chapter III in Euro area policies: selected issues, IMF Country Report. (05/266).

  • Apergis, N. (2003). Housing prices and macroeconomic factors: prospects within the European Monetary Union. International Real Estate Review, 6(1), 63–74.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barker, K. (2004). Review of housing supply, delivering stability: securing our future housing needs. HM Treasury, London.

  • Beltratti, A., & Morana, C. (2010). International house prices and macroeconomic fluctuations. Journal of Banking & Finance, 34(3), 533–545.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernanke, B.S. (2010). Monetary policy and the housing bubble. In Speech at the annual meeting of the american economic association, Atlanta, Georgia vol. 3.

  • Beveridge, S., & Nelson, C.R. (1981). A new approach to decomposition of economic time series into permanent and transitory components with particular attention to measurement of the business cycle. Journal of Monetary economics, 7 (2), 151–174.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bracke, P. (2013). How long do housing cycles last? A duration analysis for 19 OECD countries. Journal of Housing Economics, 22(3), 213–230.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Campbell, J.Y., & Cocco, J.F. (2007). How do house prices affect consumption? Evidence from micro data. Journal of Monetary Economics, 54(3), 591–621.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Case, B., Goetzmann, W.N., & Geert Rouwenhorst, G. (2000). Global real estate markets-cycles and fundamentals. Technical Report, National bureau of economic research.

  • Case, K.E., Quigley, J.M., & Shiller, R.J. (2005). Comparing wealth effects: the stock market versus the housing market. Advances in Macroeconomics, 5(1).

  • Catte, P., Girouard, N., Price, R., & André, C. (2005). The contribution of housing markets to cyclical resilience. OECD economic studies, 2004(1), 125–156.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Claessens, S., Ayhan Kose, M., & Terrones, M.E. (2009). What happens during recessions, crunches and busts? Economic Policy, 24(60), 653–700.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Costello, G., Fraser, P., & Groenewold, N. (2011). House prices, non-fundamental components and interstate spillovers: the Australian experience. Journal of Banking & Finance, 35(3), 653–669.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Del Negro, M., & Otrok, C. (2007). 99 Luftballons: monetary policy and the house price boom across US states. Journal of Monetary Economics, 54(7), 1962–1985.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Demyanyk, Y., & Hemert, O.V. (2011). Understanding the subprime mortgage crisis. Review of Financial Studies, 24(6), 1848–1880.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DiPasquale, D., & Wheaton, W.C. (1994). Housing market dynamics and the future of housing prices. Journal of Urban Economics, 35(1), 1–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DiPasquale, D., & Wheaton, W.C. (1996). Urban economics and real estate markets Vol. 23. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Doms, M., Furlong, F., & Krainer, J. (2007). Subprime mortgage delinquency rates. Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Working Paper, 33, 1–29.

    Google Scholar 

  • Drake, L. (1993). Modelling UK house prices using cointegration: an application of the Johansen technique. Applied Economics, 25(9), 1225–1228.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Egebo, T., Richardson, P., & Lienert, I. (1990). A model of housing investment for the major OECD economies. OECD Economic Studies, 14, 151–188.

    Google Scholar 

  • Égert, B., & Mihaljek, D. (2007). Determinants of house prices in Central and Eastern Europe. Comparative economic studies, 49(3), 367–388.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Englund, P., & Ioannides, Y.M. (1997). House price dynamics: an international empirical perspective. Journal of Housing Economics, 6(2), 119–136.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Girouard, N., Kennedy, M., Van Den Noord, P., & André, C. (2006). Recent house price developments: the role of fundamentals. Technical Report, OECD Publishing.

  • Glaeser, E.L., & Gyourko, J. (2002). The impact of zoning on housing affordability. Technical Report, National Bureau of Economic Research.

  • Gonzalo, J., & Granger, C. (1995). Estimation of common long-memory components in cointegrated systems. Journal of Business & Economic Statistics, 13(1), 27–35.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gonzalo, J., & Ng, S. (2001). A systematic framework for analyzing the dynamic effects of permanent and transitory shocks. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 25(10), 1527–1546.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gupta, R., & Das, S. (2010). Predicting downturns in the US housing market: a Bayesian approach. The Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 41(3), 294–319.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Himmelberg, C., Mayer, C., & Sinai, T. (2005). Assessing high house prices: bubbles, fundamentals and misperceptions. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 19(4), 67–92.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hirata, H., Ayhan Kose, M., Otrok, C., & Terrones, M.E. (2013). Global house price fluctuations: synchronization and determinants. NBER International Seminar on Macroeconomics, 9(1), 119–166.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holly, S., & Jones, N. (1997). House prices since the 1940s: cointegration, demography and asymmetries. Economic Modelling, 14(4), 549–565.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hort, K. (1998). The determinants of urban house price fluctuations in Sweden 1968–1994. Journal of Housing Economics, 7(2), 93–120.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Igan, D., Kabundi, A., De Simone, F.N., Pinheiro, M., & Tamirisa, N. (2011). Housing, credit, and real activity cycles: characteristics and comovement. Journal of Housing Economics, 20(3), 210–231.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jarociński, M., & Smets, F.R. (2008). House prices and the stance of monetary policy. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, 90 (July/August 2008).

  • Kishor, N.K. (2007). Does consumption respond more to housing wealth than to financial market wealth? If so, why? The Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 35(4), 427–448.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lea, M. (2010). International comparison of mortgage product offerings. Research Institute for Housing America Research.

  • Lettau, M., & Ludvigson, S.C. (2004). Understanding trend and cycle in asset values: reevaluating the wealth effect on consumption. American Economic Review, 94(1), 276–299.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lettau, M., & Ludvigson, S. (2001). Consumption, aggregate wealth, and expected stock returns. The Journal of Finance, 56(3), 815–849.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mack, A., & Martínez-García, E. (2011). A cross-country quarterly database of real house prices: a methodological note. Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas Globalization and Monetary Policy Institute Working Paper, (99).

  • McCarthy, J., & Peach, R.W. (2004). Are home prices the next bubble? FRBNY Economic Policy Review, 10(3), 1–17.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meen, G. (2002). The time-series behavior of house prices: a transatlantic divide? Journal of Housing Economics, 11(1), 1–23.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morley, J.C. (2002). A state–space approach to calculating the Beveridge–Nelson decomposition. Economics Letters, 75(1), 123–127.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morley, J.C., Nelson, C.R., & Zivot, E. (2003). Why are the Beveridge-Nelson and unobserved-components decompositions of GDP so different? Review of Economics and Statistics, 85(2), 235–243.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • OECD (2003). OECD economic surveys: Spain.

  • OECD (2004). OECD economic surveys: United Kingdom 2004.

  • Pichette, L., & Tremblay, D. (2003). Are wealth effects important for Canada? Bank of Canada.

  • Podivinsky, J.M. (1992). Small sample properties of tests of linear restrictions on cointegrating vectors and their weights. Economic Letters, 39(1), 13–18.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reinhart, C.M., & Reinhart, V.R. (2010). After the fall. Technical Report, National Bureau of Economic Research.

  • Scanlon, K., Whitehead, C., Pichler-Milanović, N., & Cirman, A. (2004). International trends in housing tenure and mortgage finance. London School of Economics London.

  • Scanlon, K., Lunde, J., & Whitehead, C. (2008). Mortgage product innovation in advanced economies: more choice, more risk. European Journal of Housing Policy, 8(2), 109–131.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shi, S., Jou, J.-B., & Tripe, D. (2014). Can interest rates really control house prices? Effectiveness and implications for macroprudential policy. Journal of Banking & Finance, 47, 15–28.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simo-Kengne, B.D., Miller, S.M., Gupta, R., & Aye, G.C. (2015). Time-Varying effects of housing and stock prices on U.S. consumption. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 50(3), 339–354.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Steiner, E. (2010). Estimating a stock-flow model for the Swiss housing market. Swiss Journal of Economics and Statistics (SJES), 146(III), 601–627.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stock, J.H., & Watson, M.W. (1988). Testing for common trends. Journal of the American statistical Association, 83(404), 1097–1107.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taylor, J.B. (2009). The financial crisis and the policy responses: an empirical analysis of what went wrong. Technical Report, National Bureau of Economic Research.

  • Zimmer, D.M. (2015). Time-Varying correlation in housing prices. The Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 54(1), 86–100.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to N. Kundan Kishor.

Appendices

Appendix A: State-Space Representation of Multivariate Beveridge-Nelson Trend and Cycle

Based on Morley (2002) we present a state-space representation of the multivariate Beveridge-Nelson trend and cycle. We have the following VECM equations

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \Delta h_{t} &=& \gamma_{10} + \gamma^{h}_{11} \Delta h_{t-1} + \gamma^{y}_{12} \Delta y_{t-1} + \gamma^{r}_{13}\Delta r_{t-1} + \cdots + \gamma^{h}_{17} \Delta h_{t-3} + \gamma^{y}_{18} \Delta y_{t-3}\\[-2pt] &&\qquad + \gamma^{r}_{19} \Delta r_{t-3} + \alpha^{h} \hat{\beta}^{\prime} Y_{t-1} + e_{ht}\\[-2pt] \Delta y_{t} &=& \gamma_{20} + \gamma^{h}_{21} \Delta h_{t-1} + \gamma^{y}_{22} \Delta y_{t-1} + \gamma^{r}_{23}\Delta r_{t-1} + \cdots + \gamma^{h}_{27} \Delta h_{t-3} + \gamma^{y}_{28} \Delta y_{t-3} \\[-2pt] &&\qquad+ \gamma^{r}_{29} \Delta r_{t-3} + \alpha^{y} \hat{\beta}^{\prime} Y_{t-1} + e_{yt}\\[-2pt] \Delta r_{t} &=& \gamma_{30} + \gamma^{h}_{31} \Delta h_{t-1} + \gamma^{y}_{32} \Delta y_{t-1} + \gamma^{r}_{33}\Delta r_{t-1} + \cdots + \gamma^{h}_{37} \Delta h_{t-3} + \gamma^{y}_{38} \Delta y_{t-3}\\ &&\qquad + \gamma^{r}_{39} \Delta r_{t-3} + \alpha^{r} \hat{\beta}^{\prime} Y_{t-1} + e_{rt} \end{array} $$

The Beveridge-Nelson cycle is defined as

$${Y^{c}_{t}} = -[E({\Delta} Y_{t+1}|I_{t}) + E({\Delta} Y_{t+2}|I_{t}) + {\ldots} + E({\Delta} Y_{t+k}|I_{t}) + \ldots] $$

where I t is the information available at time t. The state space representation of the above model is as follows:

$$\left[ \begin{array}{c} \Delta h^{\ast}_{t} \\[-2pt] \Delta y^{\ast}_{t} \\[-2pt] \Delta r^{\ast}_{t} \\[-2pt] \Delta h^{\ast}_{t-1} \\[-2pt] \Delta y^{\ast}_{t-1} \\[-2pt] \Delta r^{\ast}_{t-1} \\[-2pt] \Delta h^{\ast}_{t-2} \\[-2pt] \Delta y^{\ast}_{t-2} \\[-2pt] \Delta r^{\ast}_{t-2} \\[-2pt] \beta^{\prime} z_{t} \end{array} \right] \!\!=\!\! \left[ \begin{array}{cccccccccc} \gamma^{h}_{11} & \gamma^{y}_{12} & \gamma^{r}_{13} & \gamma^{h}_{14} & \gamma^{y}_{15} & \gamma^{r}_{16} & \gamma^{h}_{17} & \gamma^{y}_{18} & \gamma^{r}_{19} & \alpha^{h} \\[-2pt] \gamma^{h}_{21} & \gamma^{y}_{22} & \gamma^{r}_{23} & \gamma^{h}_{24} & \gamma^{y}_{25} & \gamma^{r}_{26} & \gamma^{h}_{27} & \gamma^{y}_{28} & \gamma^{r}_{29} & \alpha^{y} \\[-2pt] \gamma^{h}_{31} & \gamma^{y}_{32} & \gamma^{r}_{33} & \gamma^{h}_{34} & \gamma^{y}_{35} & \gamma^{r}_{36} & \gamma^{h}_{37} & \gamma^{y}_{38} & \gamma^{r}_{39} & \alpha^{r} \\[-2pt] 1 & 0 & 0 & 0 & 0 & 0 & 0 & 0 & 0 & 0\\[-2pt] 0 & 1 & 0 & 0 & 0 & 0 & 0 & 0 & 0 & 0\\[-2pt] 0 & 0 & 1 & 0 & 0 & 0 & 0 & 0 & 0 & 0\\[-2pt] 0 & 0 & 0 & 1 & 0 & 0 & 0 & 0 & 0 & 0\\[-2pt] 0 & 0 & 0 & 0 & 1 & 0 & 0 & 0 & 0 & 0\\[-2pt] 0 & 0 & 0 & 0 & 0 & 1 & 0 & 0 & 0 & 0\\[-2pt] \gamma^{h}_{101} & \gamma^{y}_{102} & \gamma^{r}_{103} & \gamma^{h}_{104} & \gamma^{y}_{105} & \gamma^{r}_{106} & \gamma^{h}_{107} & \gamma^{y}_{108} & \gamma^{r}_{109}& \gamma^{\ast} \end{array} \right] \left[ \begin{array}{c} \Delta h^{\ast}_{t-1} \\[-2pt] \Delta y^{\ast}_{t-1} \\[-2pt] \Delta r^{\ast}_{t-1} \\[-2pt] \Delta h^{\ast}_{t-2} \\[-2pt] \Delta y^{\ast}_{t-2} \\[-2pt] \Delta r^{\ast}_{t-2} \\[-2pt] \Delta h^{\ast}_{t-3} \\[-2pt] \Delta y^{\ast}_{t-3} \\[-2pt] \Delta r^{\ast}_{t-3} \\[-2pt] \beta^{\prime} z_{t-1} \end{array} \right] \!\!+\!\! \left[ \begin{array}{c} e_{ht} \\ e_{yt} \\ e_{rt} \\[-2pt] 0 \\[-2pt] 0 \\[-2pt] 0 \\[-2pt] 0 \\[-2pt] 0 \\[-2pt] 0 \\ e_{zt} \end{array} \right] $$

where \( \gamma ^{h}_{10i} = \gamma ^{h}_{1i}-\beta _{1}\gamma ^{h}_{2i}-\beta _{2}\gamma ^{h}_{3i}, \gamma ^{\ast } = 1+\alpha ^{h}-\alpha ^{y}-\alpha ^{r},\) and e z t = e h t β 1 e x t β 2 e r t and the starred letters represent the mean adjusted variable. In matrix form the state space form can be written as

$${\Delta} Y^{\ast}_{t} = F {\Delta} Y^{\ast}_{t-1} + e^{\ast}_{t} $$

where eigenvalues of the matrix F are less than unity in modulus. Then the cycle of the i th component of vector \(Y^{\ast }_{t}\) can be written as (i,i)th element of the matrix \(-(F+F^{2}+F^{3}+ ---) \ast {\Delta } Y^{\ast }_{t}\) which is equivalent of (i,i)th element of matrix \(-F(I-F)^{-1} \ast {\Delta } Y^{\ast }_{t}\). The trend component is computed by subtracting the cyclical component from the corresponding variable.

Appendix B: Robustness Check - Long-Term Interest Rates

As a robustness check, we also test our results using long-term interest rates. The table below reports the cointegrating vector estimates and the t-value from DOLS (Panel A) and the adjustment coefficient from the VECM model (Panel B) in case of cointegrating relationship between real house prices, real personal income, and real long-term interest rates.

Country

Constant

t-value

RPDI

t-value

RINT

t-value

Panel A: DOLS: long-term interest rates

Australia

−5.627

−18.08

2.185

30.26

0.021

3.66

Belgium

−0.936

−0.84

1.238

5.17

−0.087

−6.73

Canada

−4.657

−14.30

2.015

28.31

−0.003

−0.66

Denmark

−7.872

−2.01

2.699

3.20

−0.003

−0.09

Finland

−5.816

−6.64

2.238

11.74

0.038

3.25

France

−3.409

−6.25

1.744

14.21

−0.040

−4.79

Ireland

−4.113

−13.06

1.877

24.37

−0.021

−4.53

Italy

−8.901

−4.93

2.927

7.44

0.010

1.43

Netherlands

−7.089

−5.65

2.534

9.39

−0.047

−2.82

New Zealand

−6.217

−13.95

2.317

23.25

0.001

0.20

Norway

−0.716

−0.37

1.198

2.93

−0.016

−0.41

Spain

−7.928

−22.13

2.682

33.63

0.013

1.07

Sweden

−1.141

−0.94

1.268

4.95

−0.064

−4.41

U.K.

−2.035

−6.05

1.426

18.41

−0.027

−2.71

U.S.

1.124

4.21

0.730

11.34

−0.015

−2.58

Panel B: VECM: Long-Term Interest Rates

Australia

−0.009

−0.44

0.033

1.99

0.782

1.02

Belgium

−0.042

−3.68

−0.006

−1.19

−0.535

−1.26

Canada

−0.082

−3.07

−0.021

−1.26

0.989

1.08

Denmark

−0.033

−2.32

0.002

0.20

−0.097

−0.14

Finland

−0.048

−1.62

0.029

2.17

3.918

3.71

France

−0.021

−2.72

−0.002

−0.45

−0.204

−0.53

Ireland

−0.042

−3.45

−0.008

−0.76

1.158

1.12

Italy

−0.020

−1.81

−0.001

−0.12

2.191

2.54

Netherlands

−0.016

−2.23

0.000

0.04

−0.186

−0.31

New Zealand

−0.019

−1.31

0.033

3.58

0.730

0.69

Norway

−0.066

−4.81

−0.015

−1.74

−0.853

−1.28

Spain

−0.048

−3.11

−0.003

−0.44

0.656

0.86

Sweden

−0.035

−2.38

−0.018

−2.04

−3.510

−3.12

U.K.

−0.024

−2.03

−0.006

−0.76

−0.926

−1.92

U.S.

−0.031

−3.06

−0.003

−0.34

0.559

0.84

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Kishor, N.K., Marfatia, H.A. The Dynamic Relationship Between Housing Prices and the Macroeconomy: Evidence from OECD Countries. J Real Estate Finan Econ 54, 237–268 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11146-015-9546-8

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11146-015-9546-8

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation