Skip to main content
Log in

The political economy of legal titling

  • Published:
The Review of Austrian Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The libertarian case for legal titling is that formalization of the economic (de facto) rights of those who own land and buildings improves prospects for capitalism and, ultimately, development. Although all rich countries have private property rights, we argue that the success of legal titling depends on a certain kind of state—what we call a property-protecting state—that is often missing in developing countries. We use insights from Austrian economics, public choice, and institutional economics to clarify the political basis for legal titling to improve land tenure security. Evidence from Afghanistan shows that legal titling has not worked because the country does not have a property-protecting state. We suggest focusing on improving political institutions before investing in legal titling. In the meantime, it makes more sense to register land ownership at the community level, without the state.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See, for example, Umbeck’s (1977) classic study on the gold rush in California that commenced in 1848–1849. However, Umbeck’s libertarian argument about the emergence of rights is not without critics. First, rather than a legal vacuum, the US federal government was actively adjudicating land claims during the gold rush (Clay 1999). Second, it is not clear that the miners had private property rights. According to Clay and Wright (2005), the miners had almost no ability to exclude others from their claims, and lost their rights if they were not continually guarding their claims. Hadfield (2016) explains further that it makes little sense to refer to the miners as establishing “law” because their rules were not enforceable by third parties, which is a defining feature of and legal order.

  2. It is important to recognize that private property is not inherently superior to communal property. For example, Kopsidis et al. (2015) show using administrative data on land ownership from Russia in the late nineteenth and early twentieth century that communal property was in some instances more productive than privately owned land.

  3. McCloskey (2010) argues that dignity afforded to entrepreneurs is what contributed to capitalism in England. De Soto’s argument is similar, although it is not based so much in analysis of culture, but of legal recognition. It is possible that in the US, there was also a cultural transformation that contributed to legal recognition.

  4. Another issue is that Native American governments on reservations are more predatory than surrounding governments, which further contributes to underdevelopment (Anderson and Parker 2008).

  5. It is important to acknowledge that the presence of such monitoring does not mean they will necessarily succeed. Experts failure is a perpetual challenge, including when projects are monitored by organizations staffed with economists (Koppl 2018). Nonetheless, the presence of such monitoring by independent expert organizations is likely to provide at least some useful information about the performance of land reform projects.

  6. We make no claim that the state is the only source of public goods. In many instances, public goods, including roads, can be privately provided (Clark and Powell 2017). However, it is still the case that the state’s ability to provide public goods, such as roads, is likely to improve prospects for successful legal titling.

  7. Boettke and Candela (2019) argue that political constraints are an explanation for state capacity. We agree, but also view the state’s administrative capacity as influencing ability to record ownership, while political constraints influence individual beliefs about whether the government will respect those rights in the future.

  8. Pashtuns are the largest tribal confederation in Afghanistan, constituting around 40 % of the population. Most Taliban and most nomads are Pashtuns.

  9. The United States Agency for International Development (USAID) was active in land reform in Afghanistan the 1960s and 1970s, but the government capacity to implement policies was limited and civil war eliminated chances for more meaningful reform.

  10. From 1992 to 1996, several groups competed for control. The situation was anarchic, but by 1996, the Taliban controlled much of the country.

  11. Decentralization can still be monocentric, while polycentric governance requires that local governance is autonomous, which provides the basis for self-governance (Wagner 2005; V. Ostrom 1994).

  12. Zahir Shah was Afghanistan’s king for over three decades. While Zahir Shah held elections, it was mainly for show, as the Afghan parliament had no real authority to challenge his rule (Dupree 1973).

References

  • Acemoglu, D., & Johnson, S. (2005). Unbundling Institutions. Journal of Political Economy, 113(5), 949–995.

    Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., & Robinson, J. A. (2003). An African success story: Botswana. In In Analytic Narratives on Economic Growth, edited by Dani Rodrik. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu, D., Reed, T., & Robinson, J. A. (2014). Chiefs: Economic development and elite control of civil Society in Sierra Leone. Journal of Political Economy, 122(2), 319–368.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alden Wily, L. (2009). Looking for peace on the pastures: Rural land relations in Afghanistan. Kabul, Afghanistan: Afghanistan Research and Evaluation Unit.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alden Wily, L. 2013. “Land, People, and the State in Afghanistan.” Kabul, Afghanistan: Afghanistan Research and Evaluation Unit (AREU).

  • Aligica, P. D. (2018). Public entrepreneurship, citizenship, and self-governance. Cambridge University Press.

  • Allen, D. W. (1991). Homesteading and property rights; or, how the west was really won. Journal of Law and Economics, 34(1), 1–23.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alston, L. J., Libecap, G. D., & Mueller, B. (1999). Titles, conflict, and land use: The development of property rights and land reform on the Brazilian Amazon frontier. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, T. L., & Parker, D. P. (2008). Sovereignty, credible commitments, and economic prosperity on American Indian reservations. The Journal of Law and Economics, 51(4), 641–666.

    Google Scholar 

  • Andrews, Matt. 2013. The limits of institutional reform in development: Changing rules for realistic solutions. Cambridge University Press.

  • Andrews, M., Pritchett, L., & Woolcock, M. (2013). Escaping capability traps through problem driven iterative adaptation (PDIA). World Development, 51, 234–244.

    Google Scholar 

  • AREU. (2017). Land governance assessment framework (LGAF) – Afghanistan. Kabul, Afghanistan: Afghanistan Research and Evaluation Unit.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arruñada, B. (2012). Institutional foundations of impersonal exchange: Theory and policy of contractual registries. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arruñada, B. (2014). Registries. Man and the Economy, 1(2), 209–230.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baczko, A. (2016). Legal rule and tribal politics: The US Army and the Taliban in Afghanistan (2001–13). Development and Change, 47(6), 1412–1433.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baldwin, K. (2013). Why vote with the chief? Political connections and public goods provision in Zambia. American Journal of Political Science, 57(4), 794–809.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barfield, T. J. (2010). Afghanistan: A cultural and political history. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barfield, T. J. (2011). Afghanistan’s ethnic puzzle: Decentralizing power before the US withdrawal. Foreign Affairs, 90, 54.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barnard, C. (1938). The functions of the executive. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

  • Barzel, Y. (2002). A theory of the state: Economic rights, legal rights, and the scope of the state. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bates, R. H. (1981). Markets and states in tropical Africa: The political basis of agricultural policies: With a new preface. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Batson, Douglas E. 2013. “Snow Leopards and Cadastres: Rare Sightings in Post-Conflict Afghanistan.” In Land and Post-Conflict Peacebuilding, edited by Jon Unruh and Rhodri Williams, 245–65.

  • Benjaminsen, T. A., Holden, S., Lund, C., & Sjaastad, E. (2009). Formalisation of land rights: Some empirical evidence from Mali, Niger and South Africa. Land Use Policy, 26(1), 28–35.

    Google Scholar 

  • Berkowitz, D., Pistor, K., & Richard, J.-F. (2001). Economic development, legality, and the transplant effect. European Economic Review, 47(1), 165–195.

    Google Scholar 

  • Berry, S. (2002). Debating the land question in Africa. Comparative Studies in Society and History, 44(4), 638–668.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blattman, C., Hartman, A., & Blair, R. (2014). How to promote order and property rights under weak rule of law? An experiment in changing dispute resolution behavior through community education. American Political Science Review, 108(1), 100–120.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boettke, Peter J., and Rosolino Candela. 2019. “Productive specialization, peaceful cooperation, and the problem of the predatory state: Lessons from comparative historical political economy.” GMU Department of Economics Working Paper No. 19-05.

  • Boettke, P. J., & Coyne, C. J. (2005). Methodological individualism, spontaneous order and the research program of the workshop in political theory and policy analysis. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 57(2), 145–158.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boettke, P. J., Coyne, C. J., & Leeson, P. T. (2008). Institutional stickiness and the new development economics. American Journal of Economics and Sociology, 67(2), 331–358.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boettke, P. J., Coyne, C. J., & Leeson, P. T. (2011). Quasimarket Failure. Public Choice, 149(1–2), 209–224.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boone, C. (2009). Electoral populism where property rights are weak: Land politics in contemporary sub-Saharan Africa. Comparative Politics, 41, 183–201.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boone, C. (2012). Land conflict and distributive politics in Kenya. African Studies Review, 55(1), 75–103.

    Google Scholar 

  • Borras Jr, S. M., Franco, J. C., Gómez, S., Kay, C., & Spoor, M. (2012). Land grabbing in Latin America and the Caribbean. Journal of Peasant Studies, 39(3–4), 845–872.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bromley, D. W. (2006). Sufficient reason: Volitional pragmatism and the meaning of economic institutions. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bromley, D. W. (2009). Formalising property relations in the developing world: The wrong prescription for the wrong malady. Land Use Policy, 26(1), 20–27.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bromley, D. W. (2019). Possessive individualism: A crisis of capitalism. Oxford University Press.

  • Bromley, D. W., & Anderson, G. (2012). Vulnerable people, vulnerable states: Redefining the development challenge. New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carpenter, D. (2001). The forging of bureaucratic autonomy: Reputations, networks, and policy innovation in executive agencies, 1862–1928. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Clark, J. R., & Powell, B. (2017). The ‘minimal’ state reconsidered: Governance on the margin. The Review of Austrian Economics, 1–12.

  • Clay, K. (1999). Property rights and institutions: Congress and the California land act 1851. The Journal of Economic History, 59(01), 122–142.

    Google Scholar 

  • Clay, K., & Wright, G. (2005). Order without law? Property rights during the California gold rush. Explorations in Economic History, 42(2), 155–183.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coburn, N., & Larson, A. (2014). Derailing democracy in Afghanistan: Elections in an unstable political landscape. Columbia University Press.

  • Coyne, C. J. (2013). Doing bad by doing good: Why humanitarian action fails. Stanford University Press.

  • D’Arcy, M., & Nistotskaya, M. (2016). State first, then democracy: Using cadastral records to explain governmental performance in public goods provision. Governance, 30(2), 193–209.

  • De Soto, H. (2000). The mystery of capital: Why capitalism triumphs in the west and fails everywhere Else. New York: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • De Soto, H. (2002). The other path: The economic answer to terrorism. New York: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Deschamps, C., & Roe, A. (2009). Land conflict in Afghanistan: Building capacity to address vulnerability. Kabul, Afghanistan: AREU.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dupree, L. (1973). Afghanistan. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dupree, L. (1989). Post-withdrawal Afghanistan: Light at the end of the tunnel. In The Soviet (Ed.), Withdrawal from Afghanistan, edited by Amin Saikal and William Maley (pp. 29–51). London: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dutta, N., Leeson, P. T., & Williamson, C. R. (2013). The amplification effect: Foreign Aid’s impact on political institutions. Kyklos, 66(2), 208–228.

    Google Scholar 

  • Edwards, D. B. (2002). Before Taliban: Genealogies of the afghan Jihad. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ferguson, J. (1994). The anti-politics machine. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ferrell, P. (2019). Titles for me but not for thee: Transitional gains trap of property rights extension in Colombia. Public Choice, 178(1), 95–114.

    Google Scholar 

  • Foschini, Fabrizio. 2012. “Land grabs in Afghanistan: Nangrahar, the disputed rangeland.” Afghanistan Analysts Network, 2012.

  • Foschini, Fabrizio. 2013. “Land grabs in Afghanistan: Deh Sabz: The new and the old.” Afghanistan Analysts Network, 2013.

  • Fukuyama, F. (2013). What is governance? Governance, 26(3), 347–368.

    Google Scholar 

  • Galiani, S., & Schargrodsky, E. (2010). Property rights for the poor: Effects of land titling. Journal of Public Economics, 94(9), 700–729.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gaston, Erica, and Lillian Dang. 2015. “Addressing land conflict in Afghanistan.” United States Institute for Peace.

    Google Scholar 

  • Giustozzi, A., & Isaqzadeh, M. (2013). Policing Afghanistan: The politics of the lame leviathan. London: C. Hurst & Co..

    Google Scholar 

  • Hadfield, G. K. (2016). Rules for a flat world: Why humans invented law and how to reinvent it for a complex global economy. Oxford University Press.

  • Hayek, F. A. (1945). The use of knowledge in society. The American Economic Review, 519–530.

  • Hayek, F. A. (1948). Individualism and economic order. University of Chicago Press.

  • Ho, P. (2005). Institutions in transition: Land ownership, property rights and social conflict in China. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ho, P. (2017). Unmaking China’s development: The function and credibility of institutions. Cambridge University Press.

  • Hodgson, G. M. (2015). Much of the ‘economics of property rights’ devalues property and legal rights. Journal of Institutional Economics, 1–27.

  • Holcombe, R. G. (2014). The economic theory of rights. Journal of Institutional Economics, 10(3), 471–491.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holcombe, R. G. (2018). Political capitalism: How political influence is made and maintained. Cambridge University Press.

  • Holland, A. C. (2017). Forbearance as redistribution: The politics of informal welfare in Latin America. Cambridge University Press.

  • Johnson, N. D., & Koyama, M. (2017). States and economic growth: Capacity and constraints. Explorations in Economic History, 64, 1–20.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kerekes, C. B., & Williamson, C. R. (2010). Propertyless in Peru, even with a government land title. American Journal of Economics and Sociology, 69(3), 1011–1033.

    Google Scholar 

  • Koppl, R. (2018). Expert Failure. Cambridge University Press.

  • Kopsidis, M., Bruisch, K., & Bromley, D. W. (2015). Where is the backward Russian peasant? Evidence against the superiority of private farming, 1883–1913. Journal of Peasant Studies, 42(2), 425–447.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leeson, P. T. (2007). Better off stateless: Somalia before and after government collapse. Journal of Comparative Economics, 35(4), 689–710.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leeson, P. T., & Boettke, P. J. (2009). Two-tiered entrepreneurship and economic development. International Review of Law and Economics, 29(3), 252–259.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leeson, P. T., & Harris, C. (2018). Wealth-destroying private property rights. World Development., 107, 1–9.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leeson, P. T., & Skarbek, D. (2009). What can aid do? Cato Journal, 29(3), 391–397.

    Google Scholar 

  • Libecap, G. D. (1989). Contracting for property rights. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Libecap, G. D., & Hansen, Z. K. (2002). ‘ Rain follows the plow’ and Dryfarming doctrine: The climate information problem and homestead failure in the upper Great Plains, 1890-1925. Journal of Economic History, 62(1), 86–120.

    Google Scholar 

  • Libecap, G. D., & Lueck, D. (2011). The demarcation of land and the role of coordinating property institutions. Journal of Political Economy, 119(3), 426–467.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lund, C. (2008). Local politics and the dynamics of property in Africa. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Malkasian, C. (2013). War comes to Garmser: Thirty years of conflict on the afghan frontier. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • McChesney, F. S. (1990). Government as definer of property rights: Indian lands, ethnic externalities, and bureaucratic budgets. The Journal of Legal Studies, 19, 297–335.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCloskey, D. N. (2010). Bourgeois dignity: Why economics Can’t explain the modern world. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Miller, M. C. (2011). Land and racial wealth inequality. The American Economic Review: P & P, 101(3), 371–376.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mittal, S., Rakove, J. N., & Weingast, B. R. (2011). The constitutional choices of 1787 and their consequences. In Founding choices: American economic policy in the 1790s (pp. 25–56). Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mokyr, J. (1990). The lever of riches: Technological creativity and economic Progress. Oxford University Press.

  • Montinola, G., Qian, Y., & Weingast, B. R. (1995). Federalism, Chinese style: The political basis for economic success in China. World Politics, 48(1), 50–81.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mukhopadhyay, D. (2013). Warlords, strongman governors and state building in Afghanistan. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Murtazashvili, I. (2013). The political economy of the American frontier. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Murtazashvili, I., & Murtazashvili, J. (2015). Anarchy, self-governance, and legal titling. Public Choice, 162(3), 287–305.

    Google Scholar 

  • Murtazashvili, I., & Murtazashvili, J. (2016a). Can community-based land adjudication and registration improve household land tenure security? Evidence from Afghanistan. Land Use Policy, 55, 230–239.

    Google Scholar 

  • Murtazashvili, I., & Murtazashvili, J. (2016b). Does the sequence of land reform and political reform matter? Evidence from state-building in Afghanistan. Conflict, Security & Development, 16(2), 145–172.

    Google Scholar 

  • Murtazashvili, I., & Murtazashvili, J. (2016c). The origins of property rights: States or customary organizations? Journal of Institutional Economics, 12(1), 105–128.

    Google Scholar 

  • Murtazashvili, I., & Murtazashvili, J. (2016d). When does the emergence of a stationary bandit Lead to property insecurity? Rationality and Society, 28(3), 335–360.

    Google Scholar 

  • Murtazashvili, J. (2014). Informal federalism: Self-governance and power sharing in Afghanistan. Publius, 44(2), 324–343.

    Google Scholar 

  • Murtazashvili, J. 2015a. “Bad medicine: Diagnosing the failure of state building efforts in Afghanistan.” Central Asian Affairs.

  • Murtazashvili, J. (2015b). Gaming the state. Central Asian Survey, 34(1), 78–92.

    Google Scholar 

  • Murtazashvili, J. (2016). Informal order and the state in Afghanistan. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Myerson, R. (2004). Justice, institutions, and multiple equilibria. Chicago Journal of International Law, 5, 91.

    Google Scholar 

  • Myerson, R. (2014). Constitutional structures for a strong democracy: Considerations on the government of Pakistan. World Development, 53, 46–54.

    Google Scholar 

  • North, D. C. (1981). Structure and change in economic history. New York: W. W. Norton & Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • North, D. C., & Weingast, B. R. (1989). Constitutions and commitment: The evolution of institutions governing public choice in seventeenth-century England. The Journal of Economic History, 49(4), 803–832.

    Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M. (1993). Dictatorship, democracy, and development. American Political Science Review, 87(3), 567–576.

    Google Scholar 

  • Onoma, A. K. (2009). The politics of property rights institutions in Africa. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E. (2011). Background on the institutional analysis and development framework. Policy Studies Journal, 39(1), 7–27.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, V. (1994). The meaning of American federalism: Constituting a self-governing society. San Francisco: Institute for Contemporary Studies.

    Google Scholar 

  • Palagashvili, L., Piano, E., & Skarbek, D. (2017). The decline and rise of institutions a modern survey of the Austrian contribution to the economic analysis of institutions. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Piano, E. E. (2019). State capacity and public choice: A critical survey. Public Choice, 178(1), 89–309.

    Google Scholar 

  • Powell, B., Ford, R., & Nowrasteh, A. (2008). Somalia after state collapse: Chaos or improvement? Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 67(3–4), 657–670.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pritchett, Lant, Salimah Samji, and Jeffrey S. Hammer. 2013. “It’s all about MeE: Using structured experiential learning ('e’) to crawl the design space.” Center for Global Development Working Paper, no. 322.

  • Rashid, A. (2010). Taliban: Militant Islam, oil and fundamentalism in Central Asia. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Riker, W. H., & Weimer, D. L. (1993). The economic and political liberalization of socialism: The fundamental problem of property rights. Social Philosophy and Policy, 10(02), 79–102.

    Google Scholar 

  • Safar, M. Yasin and J. David Stanfield. 2007. “Cadastral Survey in Afghanistan.” Policy Report No. 4, Capacity Building for Land Policy and Administration Reform Project. Kabul, Afghanistan: Asian Development Bank.

  • Salter, Alexander W., and Abigail R. Hall. 2015. “Calculating Bandits: Quasi-Corporate Governance and Institutional Selection in Autocracies.” In New Thinking in Austrian Political Economy, edited by Christopher J. Coyne and Virgil Henry Storr, 193–213. Emerald Group Publishing Limited.

  • Scott, J. C. (1999). Seeing like a state: How certain schemes to improve the human condition have failed. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scott, J. C. (2017). Against the grain: A deep history of the earliest states. Yale University Press.

  • Sened, I. (1997). The political institution of private property. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sjaastad, E., & Bromley, D. W. (1997). Indigenous land rights in sub-Saharan Africa: Appropriation, security and investment demand. World Development, 25(4), 549–562.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sjaastad, E., & Bromley, D. W. (2000). The prejudices of property rights: On individualism, specificity, and security in property regimes. Development Policy Review, 18(4), 365–389.

    Google Scholar 

  • Skarbek, D. (2009). Alertness, local knowledge, and Johnny Appleseed. The Review of Austrian Economics, 22(4), 415–424.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stanfield, J. D., Murtazashvili, J. B., Safar, M. Y., & Salam, A. (2013). Community documentation of land tenure and its contribution to state-building in Afghanistan. In R. Williams & J. Unruh (Eds.), Land and post-conflict peacebuilding (pp. 265–285). New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stanfield, J. D., Safar, Y., Salam, A., & Brick, J. (2010). Rangeland administration in (post) conflict conditions: The case of Afghanistan. In In Innovations in Land Rights: Recognition, Administration and Governance, edited by Klaus Deininger, Clarissa Augustinus, Stig Enmark, and Paul Munro-Faure, 300–317. Washington, DC: World Bank.

  • Stringham, E. P. (2015). Private governance: Creating order in economic and social life. Oxford University Press.

  • Sun, L., & Ho, P. (2018). Formalizing informal homes, a bad idea: The credibility thesis applied to China’s ‘extra-legal’ housing. Land Use Policy, 79, 891–901.

    Google Scholar 

  • Toulmin, C. (2009). Securing land and property rights in sub-Saharan Africa: The role of local institutions. Land Use Policy, 26(1), 10–19.

    Google Scholar 

  • Umbeck, J. (1977). A theory of contract choice and the California gold rush. Journal of Law and Economics, 20, 421–437.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vahabi, M. (2004). The political economy of destructive power. Edward Elgar Publishing.

  • Vahabi, M. (2016). A positive theory of the predatory state. Public Choice, 168(3–4), 153–175.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wagner, R. E. (2005). Self-governance, polycentrism, and federalism: Recurring themes in Vincent Ostrom’s scholarly oeuvre. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 57(2), 173–188.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weidmann, N. B., & Callen, M. (2013). Violence and election fraud: Evidence from Afghanistan. British Journal of Political Science, 43(01), 53–75.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weingast, B. R. (1995). The economic role of political institutions: Market-preserving federalism and economic development. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 11(1), 1–31.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weingast, B. R. (1997). The political foundations of democracy and the rule of law. American Political Science Review, 91(2), 245–263.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, C. R. (2009). Informal institutions rule: Institutional arrangements and economic performance. Public Choice, 139(3–4), 371–387.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, C. R. (2017). Praise for property. Journal of Private Enterprise, 32(4), 83–94.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, C. R., & Kerekes, C. B. (2011). Securing private property: Formal versus informal institutions. Journal of Law and Economics, 54(3), 537–572.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yoo, D., & Steckel, R. H. (2016). Property rights and economic development: The legacy of Japanese colonial institutions. Journal of Institutional Economics, 12(3), 623–650.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Ilia Murtazashvili.

Additional information

Publisher’s note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Murtazashvili, I., Murtazashvili, J. The political economy of legal titling. Rev Austrian Econ 32, 251–268 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11138-019-00442-3

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11138-019-00442-3

Keywords

Navigation