Skip to main content
Log in

Primaries: the unifying force

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We present a formal model of intra-party politics to explain candidate selection within political parties. We think of parties as heterogeneous groups of individuals who aim to implement a set of policies but who differ in their priorities. When party heterogeneity is too great, parties are in danger of splitting into smaller yet more homogeneous political groups. In this context we argue that primaries can have a unifying role if the party elite cannot commit to policy concessions. Our model shows how three factors interact to create incentives for the adoption of primary elections, namely (1) the alignment in the preferred policies of various factions within a party, (2) the relative weight of each of these factions and (3) the electoral system. We discuss the existing empirical literature and demonstrate how existing studies can be improved in light of our theoretical predictions to provide a new, structured perspective on the adoption of primary elections.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See, for example, Aldrich (1995), Besley (2005), Levy (2004), Roemer (2001).

  2. See Adams and Merrill (2008), Serra (2011, 2013) or Aragon (2009). Mierowitz (2005) sees primaries as a mechanism that allows screening voters’ preferences rather than candidates’ qualities.

  3. For an early discussion see, for example, North and Weingast (1989).

  4. Boix and Svolik (2013) argue that institutionalized power-sharing within dictatorships could follow a similar logic.

  5. Our model remains silent on other non-policy consequences of primaries, such as the electoral bonus of calling a primary (Carey and Polga-Hecimovich 2006) or the greater factionalization when calling a primary (Key 1949).

  6. Lee et al. (2004) argue that citizen candidate models account better for what actually happens in elections than Downsian models. Put differently, parties select candidates that implement their own preferred policy instead of selecting policies that are implemented by their candidates.

  7. The rationale behind this simplifying assumption is that, relative to other selection methods, primaries have the tendency to take power away from the party elite.

  8. In Sect. 5 we show the robustness of our results when considering a one-dimensional policy space.

  9. The probabilities of winning the election capture a large set of models we might have in mind. For example, it could be the case that when the party splits, its voters perfectly coordinate by voting for one of the factions in order to avoid a large gain by the opposing party.

  10. A possible example is the presence of a non-democratically elected elite that has been in power for many years while the policy preference of the party’s core supporters has shifted. The socialist party in Spain (PSOE) was, until the last leadership change in July 2014, an example of such a situation.

  11. In order to illustrate the proposition’s result, it is best to write the two conditions in terms of y. They read as follows: \(y\; < \;\frac{1 - \alpha x}{1 - x}\;and\;y\; < \;\frac{(\alpha - 1)x}{1 - x}.\)

  12. Their measure of this divergence is the difference between the Berry state citizen ideology score (a weighted average of the Democrat and Republican representatives’ scores) and the Berry-based Democratic elite ideology score.

  13. In their cross-country section, Kemahlioglu et al. (2009) code the thresholds for preventing runoff elections as zero, one and two respectively. A higher likelihood of a runoff can be interpreted as a lower α and our theory suggests a non-monotonic effect on the aggregate use of primaries. However, their empirical design treats the effect of this variable as monotonic and finds no significant impact on the use of primaries. Instead, they find a negative relationship when bunching the values of zero and one and comparing them with two. Our theory suggests that this finding should become stronger when comparing the values of one and two, and weaker or even opposite between zero and one.

  14. For instance, see Obler (2009) for a discussion of primary elections in Belgium.

  15. Empirically this seems to be the case; see Lee et al. (2004).

  16. A future avenue of research could analyze further the institutionalization of primaries as a more irreversible change than a policy concession. This establishes an interesting link to the work of Levy (2004), who models parties as commitment devices.

  17. See Acemoglu and Robinson (2005) for an analogous discussion.

  18. That this effect is not unrealistic is shown by Obler (2009) in his analysis of the introduction of primaries in Belgium. Obler argues that the Christian Social Party did not adopt primaries when the elite perceived the likely winner of the primaries to be more extreme.

  19. The fact that primaries are more likely when the dissenting faction is centrist is related to results in Gerber and Morton (1998) and Jackson et al. (2007) where we observe that more open selection induces more centrist policies.

  20. See Tufte (1973). For an excellent review of this literature, see Taagepera and Shugart (1989).

References

  • Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. (2005). Economic origins of dictatorship and democracy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

  • Adams, J., & Merrill, S. (2008). Candidate and party strategies in two-stage elections beginning with a primary. American Journal of Political Science, 52(2), 344–359.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aldrich, J. (1995). Why parties? the origin and transformation of political parties in America (p. 1995). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Ansolabehere, S., Hirano, S., & Snyder, J. (2006). What did the direct primary do to party loyalty in Congress? In D. Brady & M. D. McCubbins (Eds.), Process, party and policy making: Further new perspectives on the history of Congress. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aragon, F. (2009). Candidate nomination procedures and political selection: Evidence from Latin American parties, LSE STICERD Research Paper No. EOPP003.

  • Besley, T. (2005). Political selection. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 19(3), 43–60.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boix, C., & Svolik, M. (2013). The foundations of limited authoritarian government: Institutions, commitment, and power-sharing in dictatorships. Journal of Politics, 75, 300–316.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caillaud, B., & Tirole, J. (2002). Parties as political intermediaries. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(4), 1453–1489.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carey, J. (2003). Presidentialism and representative institutions in Latin America at the turn of the century. Baltimore, MD: The John Hopkins University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carey, J., & Polga-Hecimovich, J. (2006). Primary elections and candidate strength in Latin America. The Journal of Politics, 68(3), 530–543.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cox, G. (1997). Making Votes Count. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

  • Crutzen, B., Castanheira, M., & Sahuguet, N. (2009). Party organization and electoral competition. Journal of Law Economics and Organization, 26(2), 212–242.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Luca, M., Jones, P., & Tula, M. (2002). Back rooms or ballot boxes?: candidate nomination in Argentina. Comparative Political Studies, 35(4), 413–436.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Folke, O., Persson, T., & Rickne, J. (2014). Preferential voting, accountability and promotions into political power: Evidence from Sweden. Huntingdon: Mimeo.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gerber, E., & Morton, R. (1998). Primary election systems and representation. Journal of Law Economics and Organization, 14, 304–324.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hirano, S., & Snyder, J. M. (2008). The decline of third-party voting in the United States. The Journal of Politics, 69(01), 1–16.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jackson, M., Mathevet, L. & Mattes, K. (2007). Nomination processes and policy outcomes. Quarterly Journal of Political Science, 2, 67–94.

  • Kemahlioglu, O., Weitz-Shapiro, R., & Hirano, S. (2009). Why primaries in Latin American presidential elections? The Journal of Politics, 71(01), 339–352.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Key, V. O. (1949). Southern politics in state and nation. New York: Knopf.

    Google Scholar 

  • Laver, M., & Sergenti, E. (2010). Party competition: an agent-based model. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lee, D., Moretti, E., & Butler, M. (2004). Do voters affect or elect policies? evidence from the U. S. House. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119(3), 807–859.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levy, G. (2004). A model of political parties. Journal of Economic Theory, 115(2), 250–277.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meinke, S., Staton, J., & Wuhs, S. (2010). State delegate selection rules for presidential nominations, 1972–2000. The Journal of Politics, 68(1), 180–193.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mutlu-Eren, H. (2011). Keeping the party together. Mimeo.

  • North, D., & Weingast, B. (1989). Constitutions and commitment: the evolution of institutions governing public choice in seventeenth-century England. Journal of Economic History, 49, 803–832.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Obler, J. (2009). Intraparty democracy and the selection of parliamentary candidates: the Belgian case. British Journal of Political Science, 4(02), 163–185.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roemer, J. (2001). The democratic political economy of progressive income taxation. Econometrica, 67(1), 1–19.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Serra, G. (2011). Why primaries ? The party’s tradeoff between policy and valence. The Journal of Theoretical Politics, 23, 21–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Serra, G. (2013). when will incumbents avoid a primary challenge? Aggregation of partial information about candidates’ valence. In N. Schofield, G. Caballero, & D. Kselman (Eds.), Advances in Political Economy: Institutions, Modeling and Empirical Analysis (pp. 217–248). Heidelberg: Springer.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Snyder, J., & Ting, M. (2011). Electoral selection with parties and primaries. American Journal of Political Science, 55, 781–795.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taagepera, R., & Shugart, M. (1989). Seats and votes: The effects and determinants of electoral systems. Canadian Journal of Political Science, 22, 875–876.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tufte, E. (1973). The relationship between seats and votes in two-party systems. The American Political Science Review, 67(2), 540–544.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ware, A. (2002). The American direct primary: Party institutionalization and transformation in the North. New York: Cambridge University Press.

Download references

Acknowledgments

We thank Stephen Ansolabehere, Fernando Aragon, Torun Dewan, Simon Hix, Michael Laver, Massimo Morelli, Hande Mutlu-Eren, Gilles Serra, Kenneth Shepsle, participants of the APSA 2010 Annual Meetings and seminar participants at the London School of Economics and Universitat Autonoma of Barcelona for helpful comments and discussions. Hannes Mueller acknowledges financial support by the Juan de la Cierva programme.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Rafael Hortala-Vallve.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary material 1 (PDF 456 kb)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Hortala-Vallve, R., Mueller, H. Primaries: the unifying force. Public Choice 163, 289–305 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-015-0249-8

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-015-0249-8

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation