Skip to main content
Log in

Electoral misgovernance cycles: evidence from wildfires and tax evasion in Greece

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We present detailed empirical evidence from Greece that around elections, misgovernance results in significant increases in wildfires and tax evasion and has important economic implications: these effects have led to the destruction of property or loss of government revenue estimated at 8 % of GDP. There are two plausible reasons why misgovernance might intensify around elections: (i) attention and effort of elected officials is directed to campaigning instead of governing; and (ii) the misgovernance may benefit special interests and serve as a pork barrel transfer that is hard to monitor or control. Empirically, we find that redistributive politics are likely a dominant cause of electoral misgovernance. In the case of wildfires we also find evidence that political competition tends to increase electoral misgovernance; furthermore, electoral misgovernance helps incumbents get reelected. While misgovernance may manifest differently among countries, our analysis suggests that electoral cycles everywhere may be much more multifaceted and harmful than previous literature suggests.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. We are not the first to suggest that wildfires increase around elections (see among others Kailidis et al. 2004), though to the best of our knowledge no one has previously used even elementary statistical analysis to measure this effect. We hope that early versions of this paper have contributed to a broader appreciation of these regularities through the attention they have generated in both Greek and international media (e.g. Walker 2010; Wells 2011).

  2. A former Minister of Finance has openly acknowledged that “The first thing a government does in an election year is to pull the tax collectors off the streets” (Lewis 2011: 49).

  3. See http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/2007_Greek_forest_fires and http://earthtrends.wri.org/text/forests-grasslands-drylands/country-profile-73.html. Our empirical analysis in the next section is robust to the exclusion of the 2007 wildfires and we report regression results for two separate subsamples.

  4. According to United Nations Economic Commission for Europe Forest Fire Statistics Timber Bulletin, Vol. LV (2002), no. 4, Table 8, in 2001 just 23 % of area burnt in Greece had a known cause. Comparing to some countries with similar risk factors, the respective figure for Spain was 50 % and for Turkey 76 %.

  5. There is considerable political pressure from land owners to delay such registries, as for many of them it would reveal that their property was locked in a legal status in which it has little value.

  6. According to the president of the Panhellenic Union of Researchers and Geotechnicians as quoted by Kathimerini newspaper, 26 September 2010, p. 4.

  7. A relevant case in point: when the devastating 2007 wildfires broke out, co-ordinating the fire-fighting effort was delayed by several critical hours due to the absence of a key Minister who was campaigning at his constituency.

  8. This may be especially important considering that the strongest electoral manipulations of fiscal policies have been observed in developing countries where tax evasion is likely to be rampant; see, for example, Brender and Drazen (2005).

  9. The minimum permissible time between the announcement of elections and the election date is three weeks in Greece but surprise elections of this type are extremely rare.

  10. Data for 2010 (which was not an election year) are available on a provisional basis only so we have not included them, though it is clear that fires in 2010 were much less damaging than in any recent election year.

  11. We repeated the regression analysis with a dummy variable for that period and found that it was insignificant, suggesting a relative paucity of fires during the dictatorship may be purely due to the lack of an election in this period. There is no evidence that the data were manipulated in this period and, to the best of our knowledge, experts have not questioned the accuracy of figures collected during the dictatorship.

  12. Three major wildfire seasons were also observed in 1965, 1988, and 1998 during which no election took place. Remarkably, all three cases coincide with events that led to relaxations in law enforcement similar to and probably more severe than those produced by electoral misgovernance. In the summer of 1965, there was a major political upheaval throughout Greece caused by the ousting of the elected Prime Minister and repeated attempts to impose a government of defectors. The country was paralyzed from massive political demonstrations, while the functioning of the state was critically affected by the extreme frequency of changes in the executive. For instance, the post of the minister responsible for forests (Agriculture minister) was manned by four different persons between July and September of that year. In October 1987, the Government passed Law 1734, according to which areas used for livestock grazing (“voskotopia”) could be eligible for obtaining construction permits. This created incentives for diminishing the forest density of land and, according to Kailidis et al. (2004), explains the intensity of wildfires that took place the following summer of 1988. In a separate analysis of fires due solely to agrarian activities, Dimitrakopoulos and Mitsopoulos (2006) show that they peaked in 1988 leaving 26,009 hectares of forest burnt, more than three times the average area of 8,600 hectares burnt for similar reasons over the 1980–1997 period. Wildfires in 1998 are perhaps the clearest case of the effects of a low quality of governance unrelated to elections: in an attempt to re-organize the wildfire management agency, the Government assigned fire-fighting responsibility to the Fire Brigades Commission, replacing a previously decentralized structure headed by the forest guard—for an account see Xanthopoulos (2006). Lack of cooperation between the various groups resulted in a new peak in forest fires, and the new agency established credibility only after a substantial reduction in wildfires in subsequent years.

  13. See, for example, Flannigan and Harrington (1988), Swetnam (1993) and Larsen (1996) for evidence that weather conditions are related to wildfires.

  14. Before the 1967 dictatorship the two main parties were the National Radical Union (conservatives) and the Center Union (democrats). After the restoration of democracy in 1974, the conservative party was renamed and the center party was largely absorbed by the newly founded socialist party, hence the common treatment. We also tried a number of alternative specifications that took into account whether the party leader was the incumbent Prime Minister at the time of the elections, the duration of each incumbency and other similar factors, but were unable to detect any partisan effect.

  15. We considered including multiple instruments associated with weather conditions in our regressions, but found that this significantly reduced the strength of our instruments. We could not find an appealing instrument in the case of tax evasion. Lags of changes in monthly tax revenue were the only instrument worth considering, but this has low correlation with current changes in revenue and may not be independent of anticipated election outcomes. Using it as an instrument we were unable to find a significant effect of tax evasion on election outcomes.

References

  • Akhmedov, A., & Zhravskaya, E. (2004). Opportunistic political cycles: test in a young democracy setting. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119(4).

  • Alesina, A. (1987). Macroeconomic policy in a two-party system as a repeated game. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 102, 651–678.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A., Roubini, N., & Cohen, G. D. (1997). Political cycles and the macroeconomy. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bickers, K. N., & Stein, R. M. (1996). The electoral dynamics of the federal pork barrel. American Journal of Political Science, 40(4).

  • Brender, A., & Drazen, A. (2005). Political budget cycles in new versus established democracies. Journal of Monetary Economics, 52, 1271–1295.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chang, E. (2005). Electoral incentives for political corruption under open-list proportional representation. Journal of Politics, 67, 716–730.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Christodoulakis, N. (1994). Tax collection lags and the revenue-maximizing inflation. Empirical Economics, 19(3), 329–342.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Couch, J. F., & Shughart, W. F. (1998). The political economy of the new deal. Cheltenham Glos: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Deutsche Press-Agentur (2007). Greece counts cost as victory near. in wildfire battle (Roundup).

  • Dimitrakopoulos, A., & Mitsopoulos, I. (2006). Time and spatial distribution of forest fires caused by agrarian activities in Greece. In Proceedings of the 12th pan-Hellenic forestry conference (pp. 149–155).

    Google Scholar 

  • Dyke, A. (2007). Electoral cycles in the administration of criminal justice. Public Choice, 133, 417–437.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Efthyvoulou, G. (forthcoming). Political budget cycles in the European Union and the impact of political pressures. Public Choice. doi:10.1007/s11127-011-9795-x.

  • Escaleras, M., Andbarci, N., & Register, C. A. (2007). Public sector corruption and major earthquakes: a potentially deadly interaction. Public Choice, 132, 209–230.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fair, R. (1978). The effect of economic events on votes for President. Review of Economics and Statistics, 64, 322–335.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fearon, J. D. (1999). Electoral accountability and the control of politicians: selecting good types versus sanctioning poor performance. In A. Przeworski, S. C. Stokes, & B. Manin (Eds.), Democracy, accountability and representation. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Flannigan, M. D., & Harrington, J. B. (1988). A study of the relation of meteorological variables to monthly provincial area burned by wildfire in Canada (1953–1980). Journal of Applied Meteorology, 27(4), 441–452.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galbraith, J. K. (1954). The great crash 1929. Mariner.

  • Garret, T. A., & Sobel, R. S. (2003). The political economy of FEMA disaster payments. Economic Inquiry, 41(3), 496–509.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gaubatz, K. T. (1991). Election cycles and war. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 35(2), 212–244.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hibbs, D. A. (1977). Political parties and macroeconomic policy. American Political Science Review, 7, 1467–1487.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huang, A. L. (2010). Does environmental policy matter for elections? Evidence from the US Senate. UC Santa Barbara Working Paper.

  • Kailidis, D., Karanikola, P., & Tampakis, S. (2004). Forest fires in Greece in the previous century (1900–2000). In Proceedings first Hellenic environmental congress (pp. 249–257) (in Greek).

    Google Scholar 

  • Kalabokidis, K., Koutsias, N., Konstantinidis, P., & Vasilakos, C. (2007). Multivariate analysis of landscape wildfire dynamics in a Mediterranean ecosystem of Greece. Area, 39(3), 392–402.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaufmann, D. (2010). Can corruption adversely affect public finances in industrialized countries. Brookings Institution Working Paper.

  • Klomp, J., & de Haan, J. (forthcoming). Political budget cycles and election outcomes. Public Choice.

  • Kubik, J. D., & Moran, J. R. (2003). Lethal elections: gubernatorial politics and the timing of executions. Journal of Law and Economics, XLVI. doi:10.1007/s11127-012-9943-y.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kuklinski, J. J. (1978). Representativeness and elections: a policy analysis. American Political Science Review, 72, 165–177.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Larsen, C. P. S. (1996). Fire and climate dynamics in the boreal forest of northern Alberta, Canada, from AD 1850 to 1989. The Holocene, 6(4), 449–456.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leeson, P. T., & Sobel, R. S. (2008). Weathering corruption. Journal of Law and Economics, 51(4), 667–681.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levitt, S. D. (1997). Using electoral cycles in police hiring to estimate the effect of police on crime. American Economic Review, 87(3), 270–290.

    Google Scholar 

  • Levitt, S. D., & Snyder, J. M. (1997). The impact of federal spending on house election outcomes. Journal of Political Economy, 105(1).

  • Lewis, M. (2011). Boomerang: the meltdown tour. Allen Lane.

  • Mechtel, M., & Potrafke, N. (forthcoming). Electoral cycles in active labor market policies, Public Choice. doi:10.1007/s11127-011-9890-s.

  • Munger, C. T. (2003). Academic economics: strengths and faults after considering interdisciplinary needs. University of California Santa Barbara. Herb Kay lecture.

  • Nordhaus, W. (1975). The political business cycle. Review of Economic Studies, 42, 169–190.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (2003). The economic effects of constitutions. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Poterba, J. M. (1994). State responses to fiscal crises: the effects of budgetary institutions and politics. Journal of Political Economy, 102(4).

  • Rogoff, K. (1990). Equilibrium political budget cycles. American Economic Review, 80, 21–36.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ronconi, L. (2009). Enforcement and compliance with labor regulations. Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 63(4).

  • Shughart, W. F. II (2006). Katrinomics: the politics and economics of disaster relief. Public Choice, 127, 31–53.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sobel, R. S., & Leeson, P. T. (2006). Government’s response to Hurricane Katrina: a public choice analysis. Public Choice, 127, 55–73.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sobel, R. S., Coyne, C. J., & Leeson, P. T. (2007). The political economy of FEMA: did reorganization matter. Journal of Public Finance and Public Choice, 17(2–3), 49–65.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stock, J. W., Wright, J. H., & Yogo, M. (2002). A survey of weak instruments and weak identification in generalized methods of moments. Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, 20(4), 518–529.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Swetnam, T. W. (1993). Fire history and climate change in giant sequoia groves. Science, 262(5135), 885–889.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Walker, M. (2010). Tragic flaw: graft feeds Greek crisis. Wall Street Journal, April 15, 2010.

  • Wells, K. (2011). Wildfires, cops and keggers: a new marketplace podcast on election-time mischief. Freakonomics Blog, November 2, 2011.

  • Xanthopoulos, G. (2006). Who should be responsible for forest fires? Lessons from the Greek experience. USDA Technical Report, PSW-GTR.

  • Young, M., Reksulak, M., & Shughart, W. F. II (2001). The political economy of the IRS. Economics and Politics, 13(2).

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors are grateful to Mr. D. Varakis for collecting the fiscal data series, to Mr. Lalas for providing the precipitation and temperature data and to Dr. G. Xanthopoulos for the data on forest fires in Greece and helpful discussions. We thank Costas Roumanias for several very useful discussions and Christos Antoniadis for excellent research assistance. We gratefully acknowledge helpful comments from Sarantis Kalyvitis and seminar participants at the Santa Fe Institute, Harvard and Yale and conference participants at the CRETE 2009 Conference.

Disclaimer  All views expressed in the paper are solely those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the position of any other person or institution. The second author was Minister of Finance in Greece during 2001–2004, a term which led to several insights on the causes and manifestation of electoral misgovernance.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Spyros Skouras.

Appendices

Appendix A: List of Greek parliamentary/legislative/national election dates 1955–2009

  • 19 February 1956, 11 May 1958,

  • 29 October 1961, 3 November 1963, 16 February 1964,

  • 17 November 1974, 20 November 1977,

  • 19 October 1981, 3 June 1985, 18 June 1989, 5 November 1989,

  • 8 April 1990, 10 October 1993, 22 September 1996,

  • 8 April 2000, 7 March 2004, 16 September 2007, 4 October 2009.

Appendix B: International evidence for effect of elections on wildfires and tax evasion

Combining several data sources we were able to amass a limited data set with which to offer a preliminary investigation into the relationship between elections, tax evasion and wildfires in other countries (Tables 6 and 7).

Table 6 International effect of elections on tax evasion and the role of corruption
Table 7 International effect of elections on wildfires and the role of corruption

In sum, there is no effect of elections on wildfires and only a weak effect on tax evasion when pooling across all countries. However, there is some evidence that countries that are more corrupt tend to have more wildfires and more tax evasion in election years. Given the short samples we have to work with in each country and the fact that institutional conditions may preclude these specific manifestations of electoral misgovernance in many countries, we consider this evidence as highly suggestive of an international dimension to the misgovernance effect we describe.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Skouras, S., Christodoulakis, N. Electoral misgovernance cycles: evidence from wildfires and tax evasion in Greece. Public Choice 159, 533–559 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-013-0071-0

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-013-0071-0

Keywords

Navigation