Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

On the optimal design of pension systems

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Empirica Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The present paper aims to quantify efficiency properties of flat and earnings-related pay-as-you-go financed social security systems of various institutional designs in order to identify an optimal pension design. Starting from a benchmark economy without social security, we introduce alternative pension systems and compare the costs arising from liquidity constraints as well as distortions of labor supply versus the benefits from insurance provision against income and lifespan uncertainty. Our findings suggest an optimal replacement rate of about 50 % of average earnings. In our model a single-tier earnings-related pension system yields the highest efficiency gains dominating flat benefits as well as two-tier systems of any form. We also show that the negative correlation between pension progressivity and pension generosity of real-world social security systems can be justified on efficiency grounds. Finally, our results indicate a positive impact of means-testing flat benefits against earnings-related benefits within multi-pillar pension systems.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Note that for the special case \(\mu=\frac{1}{\gamma}\) Eq. (1) simplifies to the traditional expected utility specification; see Epstein and Zin (1991, p. 266).

  2. Note that in order to avoid LSRA transfers causing major liquidity effects at any age, transfers are given as an annuity to agents before or after they retire.

  3. We do not report the macroeconomic effects of simulations with compensation payments, but they are available on request.

  4. The exact efficiency change in Table 3 is 0.76 which is rounded to 0.8. Rounding also explains the seemingly differences between the efficiency values reported in the following tables and the respective values displayed in the figures.

  5. In each specification considered the model is calibrated so that the initial equilibrium features the same expected lifespan and the same fractions of liquidity constrained households as in the benchmark model.

  6. Nevertheless, skill classes are still affected differently by an earnings-related benefit system due to differences in intertemporal labor supply patterns and saving rates.

  7. Note that the other two starting points (i.e. when κ 1 = 0.0) in the left part of Fig. 4 can be found in Fig. 1 as well.

  8. Note that the top left position on all three efficiency curves again shows the earlier result of a single earnings-related tier with a replacement rate of 60 % generating an aggregate efficiency gain of 1.1 %—as was already highlighted in both Figs. 2 and 4.

References

  • Abío G, Mahieu G, Patxot C (2004) On the optimality of PAYG pension systems in an endogenous fertility setting. J Pension Econ Finance 3(1):35–62

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Auerbach AJ, Kotlikoff LJ (1987) Dynamic fiscal policy. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Bomsdorf E (2003) Sterbewahrscheinlichkeiten der Periodensterbetafeln für die Jahre 2000 bis 2100. Eul Verlag, Köln

    Google Scholar 

  • Cecchetti SG, Lam PS, Mark NC (2000) Asset pricing with distorted beliefs: Are equity returns too good to be true? Am Econ Rev 90:787–805

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Conde-Ruiz JI, Profeta P (2007) The redistributive design of social security systems. Econ J 117:686–712

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cremer H, Lozachmeur J-M, Pestieau P (2008) Social desirability of earnings tests. Ger Econ Rev 9(2):114–134

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cremer H, Pestieau P (2011) Myopia, redistribution and pensions. Eur Econ Rev 55:165–175

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Epstein LG, Zin SE (1991) Substitution, risk aversion, and the temporal behavior of consumption and asset returns: an empirical analysis. J Political Econ 99(2):263–286

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr H (2009) Computable stochastic equilibrium models and their use in pension- and ageing research. De Econ 157(4):359–416

    Google Scholar 

  • Fehr H, Habermann C (2008) Risk sharing and efficiency implications of progressive pension arrangements. Scand J Econ 110(2):419–443

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr H, Habermann C, Kindermann F (2008) Social security with rational and hyperbolic consumers. Rev Econ Dyn 11(4):884–903

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr H, Kallweit M, Kindermann F (2011) Should pensions be progressive? Yes, at least in Germany! CESifo working paper no. 3636, Munich

  • Huggett M, Ventura GJ (1999) On the distributional effects of social security reform. Rev Econ Dyn 2(3):498–531

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Koethenbuerger M, Poutvaara P, Profeta P (2008) Why are more redistributive social security systems smaller? A median voter approach. Oxford Econ Pap 60:275–292

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kudrna G, Woodland A (2011) An inter-temporal general equilibrium analysis of the Australian age pension means test. J Macroecon 33:61–79. Wales

    Google Scholar 

  • Matsen E, Thøgersen Ø (2004) Designing social security—a portfolio choice approach. Eur Econ Rev 48:883–904

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nishiyama S, Smetters K (2008) The optimal design of social security benefits, WP 2008-197, MRRC, University of Michigan

  • OECD (2011) Pensions at a glance 2011: retirement-income systems in OECD and G20 countries, OECD publishing. Econ J 118:556–590

    Google Scholar 

  • Press WH, Teukolsky SA, Vetterling WT, Flannery BP (2001) Numerical recipes in Fortran: the art of scientific computing. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Simonovits A (2003) Designing optimal linear rules for flexibel retirement. J Pension Econ Finance 2(3):273–293

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simonovits A (2006) Optimal design of pension rule with flexibel retirement: the two-type case. J Econ 89(3):197–222

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We would like to thank an anonymous referee for very helpful comments. A previous version of the paper was presented at NETSPAR Pension Workshops in The Hague and Amsterdam, the annual meeting of the Austrian Economic Association in Vienna, the annual congress of the International Institute of Public Finance in Dresden, the annual meeting of the Verein für Sozialpolitik in Göttingen and the Finanzwissenschaftliches Seminar in Munich. We thank participants and especially Lans Bovenberg, Lex Meijdam, Andras Simonovits and Ed Westerhout for detailed comments. Financial support from the NETSPAR project “Multi-pillar pension schemes and macroeconomic performance” is gratefully acknowledged.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Hans Fehr.

Appendix: Computation algorithm

Appendix: Computation algorithm

In the first step of our simulation analysis we compute the initial steady state of the model. The computation of an equilibrium follows the Gauss-Seidel method introduced by Auerbach and Kotlikoff (1987). Given our set of exogenous parameters and initial guesses for aggregate variables and the bequest distribution, we calculate factor prices, household’s decision rules and value functions.

In order to obtain the solution for the household’s optimization problem (1), the state space is discretized, i.e. we use the state vector \({z_j=(s,a_j,ep_j,\eta_j)\in {\mathcal{J}} \times {\mathcal{S}} \times {\mathcal{A}} \times {\mathcal{P}}\times {\mathcal{E}}}\) with discrete sets \({{\mathcal{J}}=\{1,\ldots, J\}, {\mathcal{S}}=\{1,\ldots,S\}, {\mathcal{A}}=\{a^1,\ldots, a^{n_A}\}, {\mathcal{P}}=\{ep^1,\ldots, ep^{n_P}\}}\) and \({{\mathcal{E}}=\{\eta^1,\ldots, \eta^{K}\}}\). For all possible states z j we compute the optimal decisions from (1) over an equidistant multidimensional grid.

As we model both uncertainty and means-testing, (1) is not differentiable in every (c j , ℓ j ). Furthermore, V(z j+1) is only known in a discrete set of points \({z_{j+1}\in \{j+1\}\times{\mathcal{S}} \times {\mathcal{A}} \times {\mathcal{P}} \times{\mathcal{E}},}\) resulting in our maximization problem not being analytically solvable. Hence, we use backward induction through the following maximization and interpolation algorithms to numerically find solutions for the household’s optimization problem:

First, we compute (1) in the maximum age of J for all possible states z J . The probability of surviving to period J + 1 is zero for all households, there is no bequest motive and agents are not allowed to work after the mandatory retirement age—hence, V(z J+1) = 0 and it is optimal for agents to consume all remaining assets.

Given all possible V(z J ), we compute (1) for all \(j=J-1,\ldots,1\). In some model specifications we’re modeling means-tested pensions, in which case V(z j ) is not globally smooth and concave as the value function shows a considerable amount of local optima. Therefore it is essential to use a computation algorithm which is able to accurately find the global maximum of V(z j ), i.e. which is robust against falsely selecting a local optimum. One method of dealing with this problem is a “brute force” approach, i.e. a discrete grid-search on a finely spaced grid with a large number of points. This method is robust against falsely selecting a local maximum as the global one, but is computationally very expensive.

To reduce computation time we consequently use Powell’s algorithm (Press et al. (2001), pp. 406ff.) to find optimal solutions for (1) while guarding against the selection of local optima by adopting a section-wise optimization routine over the grid: We split the multidimensional grid into p a  × p p sections, for each of which we find independent local optima of V(z j ) using Powell’s algorithm. The local optimum with the highest value of V(z j ) is identified as the global optimum of V(z j ). Furthermore, we undertake careful robustness checks by varying the number of optimization sections as well as changing the resolution of the multidimensional grid.

Since Powell’s algorithm requires a continuous function, we interpolate V(z j+1) using linear interpolation, i.e. we find a function sp j+1 that satisfies the interpolation conditions

$$ sp_{j+1}\left(j+1,a_{j+1}^l,ep_{j+1}^m\right)=E\left[V(z_{j+1})\right] $$

for all grid points \(l=1,\ldots,n_A\) and \(m=1,\ldots,n_P\).

Given the optimal decisions of households, we compute their distribution and update the initial guesses by computing aggregate assets, labor supply and consumption. We also obtain the social security contribution rate which balances the budgets of the public pension system. The procedure is repeated iteratively until convergence is reached.

After obtaining the initial equilibrium we change the exogenous policy parameters and solve for the transition path between the initial and the final steady state. Assuming in the first guess that variables would remain constant along the transition even with alternative exogenous policy parameters, we update all individual and aggregate variables for each transition period until convergence is reached.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Fehr, H., Uhde, J. On the optimal design of pension systems. Empirica 40, 457–482 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10663-013-9214-2

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10663-013-9214-2

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation