Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Law and economics of training: a taxonomy of the main legal and institutional tools addressing suboptimal investments in human capital development

  • Published:
European Journal of Law and Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Economic literature has widely acknowledged the growing role of firm training in the knowledge economy. Training fosters labour productivity, boosts competitiveness, and strengthens firms’ capacity to innovate. This key role of training, however, raises relevant issues in terms of the optimal level of the corresponding investment. In fact firms that bear training costs may not be able to fully appropriate the relevant benefits. In addition training may facilitate structural changes and stimulate growth nationwide. Efficiency reasons thus justify the existence of legal and/or institutional tools, either voluntary or mandatory, aimed at addressing suboptimal investments in human capital development. The purpose of this study is to draw a systematic taxonomy of the main legal and institutional devices able to address the underlying inefficiencies of training investments. Training is on the top of the political agenda in many countries. The European Union is committed to increase adults’ participation in lifelong learning and to improve the quality of training programs and institutions. However, while training is of increasing political interest, a proper tool-box for policy makers is still missing.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The only application of a property rights solution is found in the labour market for professional football players before it was challenged by the European Court of Justice. In this market if a player's contract was still in force the transfer from a club to another one could only be carried out if the old club agreed to leave the player, no matter whether the player had actually complied with the legal period of notice or not. As a consequence a transfer fee was freely negotiated between the old club and a new one. After the contract had expired transfers could not be prevented by the old club, but National Football Associations set a transfer fee the club could demand. In the European Union however such a practice has been strongly limited further to a sentence of the European Court of Justice (European Court of Justice, 15th December 1995, case C-415/93, Union Royale Belge des Sociétés de Football Association ASBL and Others v Jean-Marc Bosman and Others). EU Commission appreciated this decision, arguing that before this trial football players market could be compared to a “system of slavery”, thus supporting the unlawfulness of assigning property rights to skills and abilities. On the other side the main football associations (FIFA and UEFA) claimed that transfer fees were a compensation for player's education costs plus the education costs for the talents which have not become professionals in accordance with a property right solution. Currently the legal regime of football players’ labour market allows transfer fees for valid contracts, but there are no transfer fees at all for expired contracts (Fees and Mulheuber 2002).

References

  • Abraham, K. G., & Houseman, S. N. (1993). Job Security in America: Lessons from Germany. Washington, D.C: The Brookings Institution.

    Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu, D. (1997). Training and innovation in an imperfect labour market. Review of Economic Studies, 64, 445–464.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu, D. (2002). Technical change, inequality, and the labor market. Journal of Economic Literature, 40, 7–72.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu, D., & Pischke, J. S. (1998). Why do firms train? Theory and evidence. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113, 79–119.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu, D., & Pischke, J. S. (1999). Beyond Baker: Training in imperfect labour markets. Economic Journal, 109, F112–F142.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu, D., & Pischke, J. S. (2003). Minimum wages and on-the-job training. Research in Labor Economics, 22, 159–202.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Almeida, R., & Carneiro, P. (2009). The return to firm investments in human capital. Labour Economics, 16, 97–106.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Antonelli, G., Antonietti, R., & Guidetti, G. (2010). Organizational change, skill formation, human capital measurement: evidence from Italian manufacturing firms. Journal of Economic Surveys, 24, 206–247.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aoki, M. (1990). Toward an economic model of the Japanese firm. Journal of Economic Literature, 28, 1–27.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arulampalam, W., Booth, A. L., & Bryan, M. L. (2004). Training and the minimum wage. The Economic Journal, 114, C87–C94.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Autor, D. H. (2001). Why do temporary help firms provide free general skills training? Quarterly Journal of Economics, 116, 1409–1448.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barrett, A., & O’Connell, P. J. (2001). Does training generally work? The return of in-company training. Industrial and Labour Relation Review, 54, 623–655.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barron, J. M., Black, D. A., & Loewenstein, M. A. (1989). Job matching and on-the-job training. Journal of Labor Economics, 7(1), 1–19.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bassanini, A., Booth, A., Brunello, G., De Paola, M., Leuven, E. (2005). Workplace training in Europe, IZA Discussion Paper No. 1640.

  • Bauman, F. (2010). On unobserved worker heterogeneity and employment protection. European Journal of Law and Economics, 29, 155–175.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S. (1964). Human capital. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • Besley, T., & Ghatak, M. (2007). Retailing public goods: the economics of corporate social responsibility. Journal of Public Economics, 91, 1645–1663.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bishop, J. (1991). On-the-job training of new hires. In D. Stem & J. Ritzen (Eds.), Market failure in training. New York: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bishop, J. (1994). The impact of previous training on productivity and wages. In L. Lynch (Ed.), Private sector and skill formation: International comparisons (pp. 161–199). Chicago: Univ. of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Booth, A. (1991). Job-related formal training: Who receives it and what is it worth? Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 53, 281–294.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Booth, A., & Chatterji, M. (1998). Unions and efficient training. The Economic Journal, 108, 328–343.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Booth, A., & Francesconi, M. (2003). Union coverage and non-standard work in Britain. Oxford Economic Papers, 55(3), 383–416.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Booth, A., Francesconi, M., Zoega, G. (1999). Training, rent-sharing and unions. CEPR Discussion Paper Series No. 2200.

  • Brekke, K. A., Nyborg, K. (2005). Moral hazard and moral motivation: Corporate social responsibility as labour market screening. Oslo University Department of Economics Memorandum 25/2004.

  • Bresnahan, T. F., Brynjolfsson, E., & Hitt, M. L. (2002). Information technology, workplace organization, and the demand for skilled labor: Firm-level evidence. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117, 339–374.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brunello, G., De Paola, M. (2004). Market failures and the under-provision of training. Cesifo Working Paper No. 1286.

  • Casas-Arce, P. (2004). Firm provision of general training and specific human capital acquisition. University of Oxford Department of Economics Discussion Paper Series No. 198.

  • Chang, C., & Whang, Y. (1996). Human capital investment under asymmetric information. The pigouvian conjecture revisited. Journal of Labor Economics, 14, 505–519.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Conti, G. (2005). Training, productivity and wages in Italy. Labour Economics, 12, 557–576.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dearden, L., Reed, H., & Van Reenen, J. (2006). The impact of training on productivity and wages: Evidence from British panel data. Oxford Bullettin of Economics and Statistics, 68(4), 397–421.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Den Hertog, J. (2003). Non-competition clauses: unreasonable or efficient? European Journal of Law and Economics, 15, 111–127.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dolado, J. J., Stucchi, R. M. (2008). Temporary workers and firms’ productivity: Evidence from the Spanish manufacturing sector.‖ CEPR Discussion Paper No. 7055.

  • Duncan, G. J., & Stafford, F. P. (1980). Do union members receive compensating differentials? American Economic Review, 70, 355–381.

    Google Scholar 

  • Edlin, A. S., & Hermalin, B. E. (2000). Contract renegotiation and options in agency problems. Journal of Law Economics and Organization, 16, 395–423.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eger, T. (2004). Opportunistic termination of employment contract and legal protection against dismissal in German and the USA. International Review of Law and Economics, 23, 381–403.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • European Commission (2002). Communication on Corporate Social Responsibility: A business contribution to sustainable development. Bruxelles.

  • European Commission (2006). Termination of employment relationship. Legal situation in the Member States of the European Union. Luxembourg.

  • Fees, E., & Mulheuber, G. (2002). Economic consequences of transfer fee regulations in European football. European Journal of Law and Economics, 13, 221–237.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fella, G. (2005). Termination restrictions and investment in general training. European Economic Review, 49(6), 1479–1499.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Finegold, D., & Soskice, D. (1988). The failure of training in Britain: analysis and prescription. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 4(3), 21–53.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Franz, W., & Soskice, D. (1995). The German apprenticeship system. In F. Buttler, W. Franz, & R. Schettkat (Eds.), Institutional frameworks and labor market performance: Comparative views on the US and German economies (pp. 208–234). London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frey, B., & Jegen, R. (2001). Motivation crowding theory. Journal of Economic Surveys, 15, 589–611.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, M. (1995). The social responsibility of business is to make profits, reprinted. In W. M. Hoffman & R. E. Frederick (Eds.), Business ethics. New York: Mc-Graw Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Görg, H., & Strobl, E. (2006). Do government subsidies stimulate training expenditure? Microeconometric evidence from plant-level data. Southern Economic Journal, 72(4), 860–876.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gorlitz, K. (2010). The effects of subsidizing continuous training investment. Evidence from Germany establishment data. Labour Economics, 17, 789–798.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Green, F. (1993). The impact of trade union membership on training in Britain. Applied Economics, 25(8), 1033–1043.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Griliches, Z., & Mairesse, J. (1998). Production functions: The search for identification. In S. Strøm (Ed.), Econometrics and economic theory in the 20th century (pp. 169–203). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Groot, W. (1999). Productivity effects of enterprise-related training. Applied Economic Letters, 6(6), 369–371.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guidetti, G., & Mazzanti, M. (2007). Firm training activities and complementarities in production: Conceptual insights and empirical evidence. Journal of Socio-Economics, 36(6), 875–894.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hermalin, B. (2002). Adverse selection, short-term contracting, and the underprovision of on-the-job training. Contributions to Economic Analysis & Policy, 1(1), 1–19.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hollenbeck, K. (2009). Does the Workforce Investment Act work?. Paper presented at the 31st Annual Research Conference of the Association for Public Policy Analysis and Management (APPAM), Washington DC 6 November.

  • Holzer, H. J., Block, R. N., Cheatham, M., & Knott, J. H. (1993). Are training subsidies for firms effective? The Michigan experience. Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 46(4), 625–636.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ippolito, R. A. (2003). The Impact of minimum wage if workers can adjust effort. Journal of Law and Economics, 46, 207–227.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahn, C., & Huberman, G. (1988). Two sided uncertainty and “up-or-out” contracts. Journal of Labour Economics, 6, 423–444.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Katz, E., & Ziderman, A. (1990). Investment in general training: The role of information and labour mobility. The Economic Journal, 100, 1147–1158.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kessler, A. S., & Lulfesmann, C. (2006). The theory of human capital revised: on the interaction of general and specific investments. The Economic Journal, 116, 903–923.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kitzmuller, M., & Shimshack, J. (2012). Economic perspectives on corporate social responsibility. Journal of Economic Literature, 50, 51–84.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kondo, D. K. (1990). Crafting selves: power, gender, and discourses of identity in a Japanese workplace. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Konings, J., Vanormelingen, S. (2010). The impact of training on productivity and wages: firm level evidence. IZA Discussion Papers, No. 4731.

  • Lechthaler, W. (2009). The interaction of firing costs and firm training. Empirica, 36, 331–350.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lechthaler, W., Snower, D. J. (2006). Minimum Wages and Firm Training. The Kiel Institute for the World Economy Working Paper No. 1298.

  • Leuven, E. (2005). The Economics of private sector training: A survey of the literature. Journal of Economic Surveys, 19, 91–111.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leuven, E., & Oosterbeek, H. (2004). Evaluating the effect of tax deductions on training. Journal of Labor Economics, 22(2), 461–488.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levine, D. J. (1991). Just-cause employment policies in the presence of worker adverse selection. Journal of Labour Economics, 9, 294–305.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Loewenstein, M. A., & Spletzer, J. R. (1999). General and specific training: Evidence and implications. The Journal of Human Resources, 34, 710–733.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malcomson, J., Maw, J., & McCormick, B. (2003). General training by firms, apprentice contracts, and public policy. European Economic Review, 47, 197–227.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Manning, A. (2003). Monopsony in motion: Imperfect competition in labor markets. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marshall, A. (1920). Principles of economics. An introductory volume. London: Macmillan and Co.

    Google Scholar 

  • Maximiano, S., Oosterbeek, H. (2007). On the determinants of workers’ and firms’ willingness to train. Paper presented at the XXV Conference of the European Association of Law and Economics, Oslo 20–22 September.

  • Messer, D., Wolter, S.C. (2009). Money matters: evidence from a large-scale randomized field experiment with vouchers for adult training. IZA Discussion Paper No. 4017.

  • Mincer, J. (1958). Investment in human capital and personal income distribution. Journal of Political Economy, 66, 281–302.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moen, E. R., & Rosén, A. (2004). Does poaching distort training? The Review of Economic Studies, 71(4), 1143–1162.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mohrenweiser, J., Backes-Gellner, U., Zwich, T. (2010). Poaching and firm sponsored training: first clean evidence. GEABA Discussion Papers 10–16.

  • Moretti, E. (2010). Local labor markets. IZA Discussion Papers No. 4905.

  • Muehlemann, S., & Wolter, C. S. (2011). Firm-sponsored training and poaching externalities in regional labor markets. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 41, 560–570.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Neumark, D., & Wascher, W. (2001). Minimum wages and training revisited. Journal of Labor Economics, 19, 563–595.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nickell, S. (1998). Unemployment: questions and some answers. Economic Journal, 108, 802–816.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Picchio, M., & Van Ours, J. C. (2011). Market imperfections and firm-sponsored training. Labour Economics, 18(5), 712–722.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Prendergast, C. (1993). The role of promotion in inducing specific human capital acquisition. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108, 523–534.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosen, S. (1976). A theory of life earnings. Journal of Political Economy, 84, S45–S67.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rubin, P. H., & Shedd, P. (1981). Human capital and covenants not to compete. Journal of Legal Studies, 10, 93–110.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sacconi, L. (1997). Economia, etica, organizzazione: Il contratto sociale dell’Impresa. Roma: Laterza.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sacconi, L. (2005). Guida critica alla responsabilità sociale d’impresa, problemi, teorie e applicazioni della CSR. Roma: Bancaria Editrice.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sarti, D., & Hulkko-Nyman, K. (2011). Politiche retributive e impegno sul lavoro. Evidenze empiriche dalle professioni del welfare. Economia dei servizi, 3, 321–340.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schiller, B. R. (1994). Moving up: The training and wage gains of minimum wage entrants. Social Science Quarterly, 75, 622–636.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schlicht, E. (1996). Endogenous on-the-job training with moral hazard. Labour Economics, 3, 81–92.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schwab, S. J. (1993). Life-cycle justice: Accomodating just cause and employment at will. Michigan Law Review, 95, 8–58.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sepulveda, F. (2010). Training and productivity: Evidence for US manufacturing industries. Oxford Economic Papers, 62, 504–528.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stevens, M. (1996). Transferable training and poaching externalities. In A. L. Booth & D. J. Snower (Eds.), Acquiring skills. Cambridge: Cambride University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stevens, M. (2001). Should firms be required to pay for vocational training? The Economic Journal, 111, 485–505.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Veum, J. (1995). Sources of training and their impact on wages. Industrial and Labour Relations Review, 48(4), 812–826.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Woessmann, L. (2009). Efficiency and equity of European education and training policies. CESifo Working paper No. 1779.

  • World Business Council for Sustainable Development (2000). Corporate Social Responsibility: Making Good Business Sense. Geneve.

  • Zwich, G. (2002). Continuous training and firm productivity in Germany, ZEW Discussion Papers 02–50.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Giulio Pedrini.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Pedrini, G. Law and economics of training: a taxonomy of the main legal and institutional tools addressing suboptimal investments in human capital development. Eur J Law Econ 43, 83–105 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10657-013-9384-1

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10657-013-9384-1

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation