Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

When Climate Change Determines International Agreements: Evidence from Water Treaties

  • Published:
Environmental and Resource Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Is climate change pushing governments to implement international treaties for the management of common resources? Yes, at least with respect to the Water Treaties (WTs) on common basins and rivers studied in this article. We found that climatic conditions, such as higher temperatures and lower precipitation, directly lead to a higher likelihood of signing WTs in the short, and even more so in the long run. By analyzing the impact of changes in climatic conditions observed between 1961–1975 and 1993–2007, we found that a one-degree Celsius increase in temperature has resulted in a 16.6% increase in the likelihood of signing WTs. These results are obtained for treaties related to environmental protection and economic development, and they also hold for “strong” treaties.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The literature on water scarcity indicators (also called indicators of “water pressure”, “water stress”, “water capability”) is vast, however often limited to recent years (see for instance Gain et al. 2016, Rosa et al. 2020, Vallino et al. 2020) due to the lack of historical data. Indeed water scarcity, which can be defined simply as a situation where freshwater demand exceeds its availability, turns out to be very difficult to compute once we consider the multidimensional factors that affects both the demand, the access and the availability of freshwater. Candau et al. (2022) provides a sophisticated indicator of water scarcity at a very disaggregated geographical scale, but it is unfortunately only available for the year 2000 due to a lack of data.

  2. By approximating climate change by the fluctuation in temperatures and precipitation we follow a longstanding literature in economics and in political sciences. See for instance Burke et al. (2015) on the link between economic productivity and temperatures and Dell et al. (2014) for a survey.

  3. More precisely called the Convention on the Protection and Use of Transboundary Watercourses and International Lakes.

  4. The database on WTs states that “it is not clear if this treaty ever entered into force”.

  5. See also Zawahri et al. (2014) that analyze treaties according to their content in order to study the factors influencing treaty design.

  6. Cooperation can be boosted by the level of development or by the specialization of countries.

  7. We only use indicators of water scarcity as a control because these indicators often have limitations in terms of the number of countries and the number of years. For example, the data in the FAO database, Aquastat, are four-year average measures of water stress and are available for only a handful of countries in the 1960 s (and even in the 1970 s).

  8. In an online appendix (see Candau and Gbandi 2022), we relax this specification with fixed effects and add political and economic variables (such as the presidential election one year before the signing of a treaty, the common political regime between the partners, past conflicts between the countries, economic interdependence as measured by international trade, etc.).

  9. See “Appendix 1” for the list of countries.

  10. This database has been produced by the Oregon State University, additional information can be found at: http://www.transboundarywaters.orst.edu.”

  11. The database is constantly updated and a new database is coming (summer 2023) with more than 100 treaties translated into English.

  12. The number of bilateral combinations per treaty is given by the following combination (without double counting): \(C_{n}^{2}=\frac{(n!)/((n-k)!)}{2}\), with \(n\ge 2\) and \(k=2\); n designing the number of countries engage in a cooperation on water resources, and k is the number of countries in a dyad.

  13. Not reported here, we have also estimated our baseline equation by considering a sample where all the possible dyads in each continent were considered (and not just dyads that share a basin). We find similar result with this sample, but further investigations may be interesting in order to better understand how managing freshwater resources may have effects beyond the river/lake basins. As such, a country not close geographically, but indirectly affected by resource depletion, may have an incentive to enter into an agreement.

  14. https://www.prio.org/projects/1291.

  15. Indeed, unlike the previous version of PRIO, this newest database accounts for dyads that share river basin without sharing a border.

  16. A mean temperature is generated with these maximum and the minimum temperatures.

  17. These regions are often specialized in agriculture and/or are the location of large cities. Therefore, in these regions flooding or drought often have serious consequences that are also largely mediatized at the national level. Weather fluctuations in these regions can thus have political implication at the national level. We also rely on climate variables built on the countries’ total surface as robustness checks.

  18. Available on request at https://www.emdat.be/.

  19. Though not reported here, we also verify that these variables still have a similar effect when taken separately (for instance, the coefficient of temperature in country i equals 0.0099 (significant at 5%) and that of precipitation in i equals \(-\,\)0.023, also significant at 5%).

  20. In an online Appendix (see Candau and Gbandi 2022), we also analyze to what extent these weather variables have a non-linear effect on the signature of WTs.

  21. See for instance Battaglini and Harstad (2020) who propose a model explaining under which conditions strong or weak treaties are negotiated. They assume that politicians focus on their probability to be elected (or re-elected) and then chose strategically the content of international treaties to win votes accordingly.

  22. We have carried out several other estimations not reported here. For instance, by considering treaties with fewer than thirty signatories, we find that temperature and precipitation are significant, while this result does not hold for a number of members above this threshold.

  23. More precisely we exclude: Albania; Austria; Belgium; Bosnia and Herzegovina; Bulgaria; Croatia; Denmark; Estonia; Finland; France; Germany; Greece; Hungary; Italy; Latvia; Lithuania; Luxembourg; Netherlands; Norway; Poland; Portugal; Republic of Moldova; Slovakia; Slovenia; Spain; Sweden; Switzerland; Ukraine.

  24. It is worth noting that this approach serves to overcome the limitations of cross-sectional approaches. Indeed, in comparison with the literature where the averages of different variables are taken over a long period of time with the risk of bias due to omitted variables, here the estimates are immune to time-invariant omitted variables by long differentiating. Furthermore, in comparison with the FE model presented in (2), coefficients \(\alpha\), \(\beta\) and \(\mu\) are estimated from long-term changes in average conditions instead of year-on-year changes and can thus be used to take into account the adaptation of governments to signing WTs.

  25. See for instance the New York Times article of Stevens (1998).

  26. The distinction between the content (development or environmental issues) and the nature (weak or strong) of treaties may, however, be related. For instance, Battaglini and Harstad (2020) argue that weak treaties are more numerous when they concern environmental issues than when they are related to security issues.

  27. To select these contents, we use the “Issue Area” column of the International Freshwater Treaty Database that identifies, in the text of the treaty, the main issue area of the document. Since more than one issue area can be listed, we focus on treaties that are exclusively on “Water quantity and Water quality issues”, “Economic development” and “Environmental services or protection”.

  28. See the Stata command “nlcom”.

References

  • Bapat NA, Morgan TC (2009) Multilateral versus unilateral sanctions reconsidered: a test using new data. Int Stud Q 53(4):1075–1094

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barrett S (1994) Self-enforcing international environmental agreements. Oxford economic papers, pp 878–894

  • Battaglini M, Harstad B (2020) The political economy of weak treaties. J Polit Econ 128(2):544–590

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bergquist M, Nilsson A, Schultz PW (2019) Experiencing a severe weather event increases concern about climate change. Front Psychol. https://doi.org/10.3389/fpsyg.2019.00220

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Besedeš T, Johnson EP, Tian X (2020) Economic determinants of multilateral environmental agreements. Int Tax Public Finance 27(4):832–864

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borick CP, Rabe BG (2017) Personal experience, extreme weather events, and perceptions of climate change

  • Burke M, Emerick K (2016) Adaptation to climate change: evidence from US agriculture. Am Econ J Econ Pol 8(3):106–140

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Burke M, Hsiang SM, Miguel E (2015) Global non-linear effect of temperature on economic production. Nature 527(7577):235–239

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Candau F, Gbandi T (2022) Water treaties, non linear effects and politics. github

  • Candau F, Regnacq C, Schlick J (2022) Climate change, comparative advantage and the water capability to produce agricultural goods. World Dev 158:105963

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dell M, Jones BF, Olken BA (2014) What do we learn from the weather? the new climate-economy literature. J Econ Lit 52(3):740–98

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dinar A, Blankespoor B, Dinar S, Kurukulasuriya P (2010) Does precipitation and runoff variability affect treaty cooperation between states sharing international bilateral rivers? Ecol Econ 69(12):2568–2581

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dinar S, Dinar A, Kurukulasuriya P (2011) Scarcity and cooperation along international rivers: an empirical assessment of bilateral treaties1. Int Stud Q 55(3):809–833

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dixit A, Olson M (2000) Does voluntary participation undermine the Coase theorem? J Public Econ 76(3):309–335

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elliott R, Nguyen-Tien V, Strobl E, Tveit T (2022) Natural disasters and voting behavior: evidence from environmental legislation in the US senate. J Assoc Environ Resour Econ. https://doi.org/10.1086/722540

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • FAO, (2022) Transboundary waters. https://www.fao.org/land-water/water/water-management/transboundary-water-management/en/

  • Faure MG, Partain RA (2019) Environmental law and economics: theory and practice. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Gagliarducci S, Paserman MD, Patacchini E (2019) Hurricanes, climate change policies and electoral accountability. Technical report

  • Gain AK, Giupponi C, Wada Y (2016) Measuring global water security towards sustainable development goals. Environ Res Lett 11(12):124015

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Giordano M, Drieschova A, Duncan JA, Sayama Y, Stefano LD, Wolf AT (2013) A review of the evolution and state of transboundary freshwater treaties. Int Environ Agreem: Politics Law Econ 14(3):245–264

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hansen J, Sato M, Ruedy R (2012) Perception of climate change. Proc Natl Acad Sci 109(37):E2415–E2423

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harris I, Jones P, Osborn T, Lister D (2013) Updated high-resolution grids of monthly climatic observations—the CRU TS3.10 dataset. Int J Climatol 34(3):623–642

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • IPCC (2007) Climate change 2007: impacts, adaptation and vulnerability. Contribution of Working Group II to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovermental Panel on Climate Change, chapter 5, p 22. Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC)

  • IPCC (2022) Sixth assessment report

  • Kolstad CD, Toman M (2005) The economics of climate policy. In: Maler K-G, Vincent JR (eds) Handbook of enviromental economics. Elsevier, Amsterdam

    Google Scholar 

  • Mann ME, Bradley RS, Hughes MK (1998) Global-scale temperature patterns and climate forcing over the past six centuries. Nature 392(6678):779–787

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McCracken M, Wolf AT (2019) Updating the register of international river basins of the world. Int J Water Resour Dev 35(5):732–782

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meadows D, Meadows L, Randers BWB (1972) The limits to growth. Universe Books, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Neumayer E (2002) Do democracies exhibit stronger international environmental commitment? a cross-country analysis. J Peace Res 39(2):139–164

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom E (1990) Governing the commons: the evolution of institutions for collective action. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Rosa L, Chiarelli DD, Rulli MC, Dell’Angelo J, D’Odorico P (2020) Global agricultural economic water scarcity. Sci Adv 6(18):eaaz6031

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sambrook K, Konstantinidis E, Russell S, Okan Y (2021) The role of personal experience and prior beliefs in shaping climate change perceptions: a narrative review. Front Psychol 12:669911

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schlenker W, Roberts MJ (2009) Nonlinear temperature effects indicate severe damages to U.S. crop yields under climate change. Proc Natl Acad Sci 106(37):15594–15598

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simmons M (2000) Revisiting the limits to growth: could the club of rome have been correct, after all? an energy white paper

  • Stefano LD, Duncan J, Dinar S, Stahl K, Strzepek KM, Wolf AT (2012) Climate change and the institutional resilience of international river basins. J Peace Res 49(1):193–209

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stevens W (1998) New evidence nds this is warmest century in 600 years. New York Times

  • Tir J, Ackerman JT (2009) Politics of formalized river cooperation. J Peace Res 46(5):623–640

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • UN-Water (2020) Policy brief on the united nations global water conventions. Geneva, Switzerland

  • Vallino E, Ridolfi L, Laio F (2020) Measuring economic water scarcity in agriculture: a cross-country empirical investigation. Environ Sci Policy 114:73–85

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Victor DG, Lumkowsky M, Dannenberg A (2022) Determining the credibility of commitments in international climate policy. Nat Clim Change 12(9):793–800

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wilder MO, Varady RG, Gerlak AK, Mumme SP, Flessa KW, Zuniga-Teran AA, Scott CA, Pablos NP, Megdal SB (2020) Hydrodiplomacy and adaptive governance at the U.S.-Mexico border: 75 years of tradition and innovation in transboundary water management. Environ Sci Policy 112:189–202

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Young OR (1999) The effectiveness of international environmental regimes: causal connections and behavioral mechanisms. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Zawahri NA, Dinar A, Nigatu G (2014) Governing international freshwater resources: an analysis of treaty design. Int Environ Agreem Politics Law Econ 16(2):307–331

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Fabien Candau.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendix 1: List of Countries

The current study is based on a sample of countries that includes: Afghanistan; Albania; Algeria; Angola; Argentina; Armenia; Austria; Azerbaijan; Bangladesh; Belgium; Belize; Benin; Bhutan; Bosnia and Herzegovina; Botswana; Brazil; Bulgaria; Burkina Faso; Burundi; Cambodia; Cameroon; Canada; Central African Republic; Chad; Chile; China; Colombia; Congo; Costa Rica; Croatia; Denmark; Djibouti; Dominican Republic; Ecuador; Egypt; El Salvador; Equatorial Guinea; Eritrea; Estonia; Ethiopia; Finland; France; Gabon; Gambia; Georgia; Germany; Ghana; Greece; Guatemala; Guinea; Guinea-Bissau; Guyana; Haiti; Honduras; Hungary; India; Indonesia; Iran (Islamic Republic of); Iraq; Israel; Italy; Jordan; Kazakhstan; Kenya; Kyrgyzstan; People’s Democratic Republic; Latvia; Lebanon; Lesotho; Liberia; Libya; Lithuania; Luxembourg; Malawi; Malaysia; Mali; Mauritania; Mexico; Mongolia; Morocco; Mozambique; Myanmar; Namibia; Nepal; Netherlands; Nicaragua; Niger; Nigeria; Norway; Pakistan; Panama; Paraguay; Peru; Poland; Portugal; Republic of Korea; Republic of Moldova; Rwanda; Senegal; Sierra Leone; Slovakia; Slovenia; Somalia; South Africa; Spain; Sudan; Suriname; Sweden; Switzerland; Syrian Arab Republic; Tajikistan; Thailand; Togo; Tunisia; Turkey; Turkmenistan; Uganda; Ukraine; United Republic of Tanzania; United States of America; Uruguay; Uzbekistan; Zambia; Zimbabwe.

Appendix 2: Descriptive Statistics

See Table 7.

Table 7 Descriptive statistics

Appendix 3: Two Lags

In this appendix we analyze temperature and precipitations shocks over two years. The join effects over these periods are obtained by summing up the coefficients on the lags over the periods. The join coefficients and their standard errors and significance levels are computed using on the “Delta method”.Footnote 28 We find that temperature shocks during the two years preceding the WTs increase the likelihood to enter a WT while the join precipitations’ shocks during this time periods reduce this probability (Table 8).

Table 8 Water Treaties and Climate Change in the Short Run - Repeated shocks analyses

Appendix 4: Downstream/Upstream Countries

Another interesting discussion concerns the role of countries’ geographic location relative to the basin’s common resource. Where does the change in temperature/precipitation have the most impact on the likelihood of signing a treaty, in the downstream country or in the upstream country? One could argue that since upstream countries have the ability to control river flows (e.g. through dams), the incentive to sign an agreement in the event of a water shortage could be zero for these countries. Such a proposal, however, is based on the assumption that water storage by upstream countries is sufficiently large to compensate for the water shortage due to a warmer climate (and on the inability of the downstream country to respond in other ways). If this capacity is not met, it is likely that the signing of the treaty will depend on the temperature/rainfall in that upstream country. If we now consider downstream countries, especially weak countries (with economic and/or military power disadvantage), then the change in temperature/precipitation may not impact treaties, since these countries may not have the bargaining power to negotiate them. On the contrary, if the power asymmetry is reversed (strong country downstream vs. weak country upstream), then it may be the temperature fluctuation at that location that will be decisive. In short, from this narrative approach, it is difficult to know what to expect. We therefore propose a simple empirical test of whether location along the river matters. We estimate our baseline equation by adding for each pair only the temperature and precipitation of the downstream (column 1) and upstream (column 2) countries. The upstream/downstream dummy variable is also constructed from the shared watershed database (PRIO project). We only consider country pairs where the upstream/downstream relationship is clear, i.e. we do not consider river border cases or mixed upstream/downstream cases.

The results are ambiguous. On the one hand, precipitation has a greater effect in downstream countries, but on the other hand, temperature has a significant effect only in upstream countries. These results can therefore be interpreted in different ways, by focusing on temperature one could argue that upstream countries are the key players, while the results concerning precipitation are less conclusive. These ambiguous results explain our choice not to go into detail about upstream versus downstream countries in our baseline estimate. After all “it takes two to tango” and it is not sure that a systematic relationship can be established for dowstream/upstream countries. More data on the timing of climate shocks and their policy implications in each country, as well as the exogenous determinants of downstream and upstream country dependence and power asymmetry, can help advance this issue (Table 9).

Table 9 Upstream versus Downstream countries

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Candau, F., Gbandi, T. When Climate Change Determines International Agreements: Evidence from Water Treaties. Environ Resource Econ 85, 587–614 (2023). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-023-00776-4

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-023-00776-4

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation