Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Dynamic Policy Impacts on a Technological-Change System of Renewable Energy: An Empirical Analysis

  • Published:
Environmental and Resource Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Recently, harmonization of renewable energy policies has drawn growing attention as an important issue. To find the most effective combination, this paper identifies simultaneous interactions in an endogenous technological-change system and analyzes empirically the static and dynamic impacts of renewable energy policies in solar PV and wind power. The empirical results indicate that policy outcomes create a virtuous cycle in the technological change system through market oppurntunity, learning-by-searching, and learning-by-doing. According to the results, the static impact of technology-push and tariff incentive policies are effective on invention, while renwables obligation and CO2 tax appear to encourage cost reduction in the technologies. When the dynamic impacts of policy are considered, tariff incentives appears to outperform a renewables obligation policy with very small margin.We also found that the dynamic impact of CO2 tax varies with the level of technological development maturity.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Investment covers almost all the levelized cost of renewable energy, approximately 87 %, on average, for solar PV and 75 %, on average, for wind power (IEA-NEA-OCED 2010). Accordingly, in this paper, the terminology ‘innovation’ has very narrow scope (cost reduction). However, in general, ‘innovation’ has a broader meaning like the commercialization of a new product. It may cover invention, new product development and commercialization. In this paper, we follow the definition of Söderholm and Klaassen (2007) on ‘innovation’.

  2. As anonymous reviewers pointed out, model set-up for the policy in this paper still has some limitations. One of the important limitations is that policy is treated as ‘exogenous’ although with this system approach one could expect that both the stringency and the mix of policy could change as the technology matures or market environment changes. Recently, Ek and Söderholm (2010) addressed this issue.

  3. Some previous studies mention various factors to account for international knowledge spillover such as geographic differentiation (Kneller 2005), trades between two countries (Coe and Hepman 1995; Coe et al. 2009), and internal factor of spillover’s recipients (absorptive capacity; for example, Bosetti et al. 2008; Cohen and Levinthal 1989; Griffith et al. 2003). Among them, this paper focuses on absorptive capacity [Eqs. (4), (5)] rather than other factors. First of all, we believe “knowledge” transfer may depend more on knowledge related capacity (absorptive capacity, for example) than on physical factors such as geographical differentiation. Kneller (2005) finds that absorptive capacity, rather than physical distance, plays a greater role in determining the amount of knowledge transfers on the international level. Second, it is quite difficult to access geographical and trades data between every two countries.

  4. Australia, Austria, Canada, Denmark, France, Germany, Italy, Japan, Republic of Korea, the Netherlands, Norway, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, the United Kingdom, and the United States.

  5. Canada, Denmark, Finland, Germany, Italy, Japan, the Netherlands, Norway, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, the United Kingdom, and the United States. The Annex II group is obligated to reduce \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emissions and to offer technology transfer and loan support to developing countries if clean technologies can be viably introduced and diffused, either by the country’s vested interest or because of global regulations. These developed countries are suitable for this study because they have advanced technology and well-constructed system for renewable energy.

  6. The government support for R&D in time t may affect contemporaneous invention but also can incorporate time lags creation of new invention based on government R&D expenditure may take some times and the time lags depend on certain characteristics of technologies such as a technical standard, technological level, R&D efficiency, and path-dependence (i.e., technical inertia). Accordingly referring to a study (Peters et al. 2012), in this paper we considered public R&D variable, which incorporates several time lags from \(t-1\) to \(t-3\), as well as t. As estimated results, public R&D has a significant effect on invention in time \(t-1\) of solar PV, while in time t of wind power technology.

  7. For example, the United Kingdom has levied taxes with constant rates on fossil fuel from 2001 to 2005, and Germany has set small, increased, tariff incentives, 0.24€cents/kWh, from 1991 through 2000 (IEA 2004).

  8. These specifications are based on economic reasoning. For example, we assume that science and research related variable such as ‘public R&D \((TP_{i,n,t})\)’ and ‘national scientific resource \((SR_{n,t})\)’ influence ‘invention’ (creation of new knowledge) ‘directly’ and only influence ‘cost and diffusion’ ‘indirectly’ by affecting invention. We also assume that ‘raw material prices \((RMP_{i,t})\)’ and ‘GDP’ affect ‘cost’ ‘directly’ and only influence ‘diffusion and invention’ ‘indirectly’ because renewable system costs are very sensitive to raw material price (such as silicon price) and the cost for installation of renewable system may directly depend on infrastructure development and production ability which is measured by each country’s gross domestic products (GDP). In addition, price of fossil fuels \((FFP_{n,t})\) and size of electricity market measured by electricity generation \((TEG_{n,t})\) are assumed to have ‘direct’ positive impact on ‘diffusion’ of renewable energy because fossil fuels can be the substitute goods for renewable energy technologies and diffusion level of renewables directly depends on size of electricity market.

  9. We compared estimation results of 3 different estimation methods, i.e., 2SLS, Seemingly Unrelated Regression (SUR) method, and 3SLS (Tables 8, 9, 10, 11, 12, 13 in appendix). SUR considers correlations between equations, but doesn’t consider endogeneity (Greene 2011). The results show that there are not big differences in coefficients and statistical significance level between the 3 methods. In addition, we employed tests of significance of correlation (or covariance) among error terms of three equations. For both renewable technology, null hypothesis that covariance matrix is diagonal (zero covariance between equations) is rejected with statistics 40.52 (for PV solar) and 20.22 (Wind Power) of \(\chi ^{2}\) distribution in likelihood ratio (LR) tests, which means that there is correlation among simultaneous equations. Therefore, as mentioned above, it is more appropriate to impose 3SLS techniques to estimate not individual equation but the whole of equations simultaneously.

  10. Criterion on statistical significance in this paper is 10 % significance level. If p value of a coefficient does not exceed 10 % then we cannot reject hypothesis that the coefficient is 0, which means that this coefficient is statistically significant (it is not “zero”). We may have stricter criteria such as 5 or 1 %. We also indicate significances of the coefficients not only for 10 % significance level (*) but also for 5 and 1 % significance level (**, ***) in the tables in the paper.

  11. This paper calculates the rate (for market opportunity) as \((2^{a_1}-1)\) based on Klaassen et al. (2005)’s study to show the constant increases in invention for each diffusion (cumulative capacity) doubling and to compare this paper’s results with those of previous studies. We also use the same formula for learning-by-doing rates ((\(2^{b_1 }-1)\) in innovation model) and for learning-by-searching ((\(2^{b_2 }-1)\) in innovation model).

  12. This paper calculates the rate by introduction of a certain policy as \((e^{a_5}-1)\).

  13. As we described in Sect. 2.2, in the case of the renewable obligation, virtual competitive market for renewables is created. And more intensive competition in the renewable obligation may bring up more transactions and related costs between renewable producers, electric utilities and regulator. The transaction costs include information and searching costs (finding who has the lowest cost in renewable producers, for example), cost of proving (proving that I am the cheapest option for renewable, for example), bargaining costs between chosen renewable producers and electric utilities (or regulator). For more details, see Tirole (1988), p. 21–27.

  14. This paper calculates the rate as \(((1-0.1)^{c_1 }-1)\).

  15. The result is an isolation of dynamic (long-run) impact of single policy’s introduction or change.

  16. To determine whether the public R&D reflects an overinvestment on innovation of renewables technologies or not, we calculated public R&D efficiency with respect to cost reduction (the ratio of total cost reduction, which reflects amount of diffusion increased by public R&D, to the input of the public R&D budget) based on our dynamic impact results of public R&D using cross-country average data in the analysis periods for each technology. The calculation shows the ratio of solar PV and wind power as 227.87 and 228.89, respectively, implying that public R&D do not reflect an overinvestment and shows substantial efficiency for innovation (cost reduction).

  17. An example would be the encouragement of foreign direct investment (FDI) and international cooperation for technology development.

References

  • Argote L, Epple D (1990) Learning curves in manufacturing. Science 247:920–924

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aschhoff B, Sofka W (2009) Innovation on demand—can public procurement drive market success of innovations? Res Policy 38:1235–1247

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baltagi BH (1995) Econometric analysis of panel data. Wiley, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Bosetti V, Carraro C, Massetti E, Tavoni M (2008) International energy R&D spillovers and the economics of greenhouse gas atmospheric stabilization. Energy Econ 30:2912–2929

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Butler L, Neuhoff K (2008) Comparison of feed-in tariff, quota and auction mechanisms to support wind power development. Renew Energy 33:1854–1867

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coe DT, Hepman E (1995) International R&D spillovers. Eur Econ Rev 39:859–887

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coe DT, Hepman E, Hoffmaister AW (2009) International R&D spillovers and institutions. Eur Econ Rev 53:723–742

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cohen WM, Levinthal DA (1989) Innovation and learning: the two faces of R&D. Econ J 99:569–596

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dekker T, Vollebergh H, de Vries F, Withagen C (2012) Inciting protocols. J Environ Econ Manag 64:45–67

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Noord M, Beurskens LWM, de Vries HJ (2004) Potentials and costs for renewable electricity generation: a data overview. ECN report ECN-C–03-006, Energy Research Centre of the Netherlands. http://www.ecn.nl/docs/library/report/2003/c03006.pdf. Cited 2 Dec 2013

  • Dutton JM, Thomas A (1984) Treating progress functions as a managerial opportunity. Acad Manag Rev 9:235–247

    Google Scholar 

  • Ek K, Söderholm P (2010) Technology learning in the presence of public R&D: the case of European wind power. Ecol Econ 69:2256–2362

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fischer C, Newell RG (2008) Environmental and technology policies for climate mitigation. J Environ Econ Manag 55:142–162

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Foxon TJ, Gross R, Chase A, Howes J, Arnall A, Anderson D (2005) UK innovation systems for new and renewable energy technologies: drivers, barriers and systems failures. Energy Policy 33:2123–2137

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goulder LH, Parry IW (2008) Instrument choice in environmental policy. Rev Environ Econ Policy 2:152–174

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greene WH (2011) Econometric analysis, 7th edn. Prentice Hall Press, New Jersey

    Google Scholar 

  • Griffith R, Redding S, Van Reenen J (2003) R&D and absorptive capacity: theory and empirical evidence. Scand J Econ 105:99–118

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hoppmann J, Peters M, Schneider M, Hoffmann V (2013) Two faces of market support—how deployment polices affect technological exploration and exploitation in the solar photovoltaic industry. Res Policy 42:989–1003

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ibenholt K (2002) Explaining learning curves for wind power. Energy Policy 30:1181–1189

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • International Energy Agency (IEA) (2003) World energy investment outlook 2003 insights. Paris

  • International Energy Agency (IEA) (2004) Renewable energy: market & policy trends in IEA countries. Paris

  • International Energy Agency (IEA) (2008a) Deploying renewables: principles for effective policies. Paris

  • International Energy Agency (IEA) (2009a) Electricity information. Paris

  • International Energy Agency (IEA) (2009b) Energy prices and taxes. Paris

  • International Energy Agency (IEA) (2009c) Renewables information. Paris

  • International Energy Agency (IEA), Nuclear Energy Agency (NEA) and Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) (2010) Projected cost of generating electricity, 2010 edition. Paris

  • International Energy Agency (IEA) (2011a) Key world energy statistics. Paris

  • International Energy Agency (IEA) (2011b) Energy technology RD&D budgets. Paris

  • International Energy Agency (IEA) and International Renewable Energy Agency (IRENA) (2011) Global renewable energy policies and measures database. http://www.iea.org/textbase/pm/?mode=re. Cited 2 Dec 2012

  • International Energy Agency (IEA) and Photovoltaic Power Systems Programme (PVPS) (2008) Trends in photovoltaic applications. Paris

  • International Energy Agency (IEA) (2008) Wind energy annual report. Paris

  • Jaffe AB (1986) Technological opportunity and spillovers of R&D: evidence from firms’ patents, profit, and market value. Am Econ Rev 76:984–1001

    Google Scholar 

  • Jaffe AB, Newell RG, Stavins RN (2005) A tale of two market failures: technology and environmental policy. Ecol Econ 54:164–174

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johnstone N, Hascic I, Popp D (2010) Renewable energy policies and technological innovation: evidence based on patent counts. Environ Resour Econ 45:133–155

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jones CI, Williams JC (1998) Measuring the social return to R&D. Q J Econ 113:1119–1135

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Junginger M, Faaij A, Turkenburg WC (2005) Global experience curves for wind farms. Energy Policy 33:133–150

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kamp LM, Smits REHM, Andriesse CD (2004) Notions on learning applied to wind turbine development in the Netherlands and Denmark. Energy Policy 32:1625–1637

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kim K, Kim Y (2015) Role of policy in innovation and international trade of renewable energy technology: empirical study of solar PV and wind power technology. Renew Sust Energy Rev 44:717–727

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klaassen G, Miketa A, Larsen K, Sundqvist T (2005) The impact of R&D on innovation for wind energy in Denmark, Germany and the United Kingdom. Ecol Econ 54:227–240

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kneller R (2005) Frontier technology, absorptive capacity and distance. Oxf Bull Econ Stat 67:1–23

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kobos PH, Erickson JD, Drennen TE (2006) Technological learning and renewable energy costs: implications for US renewable energy policy. Energy Policy 34:1645–1658

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kouvaritakis N, Soria A, Isoard S (2000) Modelling energy technology dynamics: methodology for adaptive expectations models with learning by doing and learning by searching. Int J Glob Energy 14:1–4

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lanjouw JO, Mody A (1996) Innovation and the international diffusion of environmentally responsive technology. Res Policy 25:549–571

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lauber V (2004) REFIT and RPS: options for a harmonized community framework. Energy Policy 32:1405–1414

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Menanteau P, Finon D, Lamy ML (2003) Prices versus quantities: choosing policies for promoting the development of renewable energy. Energy Policy 31:799–812

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meyer NI (2003) European schemes for promoting renewables in liberalized markets. Energy Policy 31:665–676

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nemet GF (2009) Demand-pull, technology-push, and government-led incentives for non-incremental technical change. Res Policy 38:700–709

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) (2010) Main science and technology indicators 2010. Paris

  • Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) (2011a) OECD patent statistics. http://www.oecd-ilibrary.org/statistics. Cited 2 Dec 2011

  • Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) (2011b) OECD.StatExtracts. http://stats.oecd.org/index.aspx?queryid=90. Cited 2 Dec 2011

  • Peters M, Schneider M, Griesshaber T, Hoffmann VH (2012) The impact of technology-push and demand-pull policies on technical change—does the locus of policies matter? Res Policy 41:1296–1308

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pizer WA, Popp D (2008) Endogenizing technological change: matching empirical evidence to modeling needs. Energy Econ 30:2754–2770

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Popp D (2001) The effect of new technology on energy consumption. Resour Energy Econ 23:215–239

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Popp D (2005) Lessons from patents: Using patents to measure technological change in environmental models. Ecol Econ 54:209–226

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Popp D (2006) International innovation and diffusion of air pollution control technologies: the effects of \(\text{ NO }_{\rm X}\) and \(\text{ SO }_{2}\) regulation in the U.S., Japan, and Germany. J Environ Econ Manag 51:46–47

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Popp D, Hascic I, Medhi N (2011) Technology and the diffusion of renewable energy. Energy Econ 33:648–662

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sagar AD, Zwaan B (2006) Technological innovation in the energy sector: R&D, deployment, and learning-by-doing. Energy Policy 34:2601–2608

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter J (1934) The theory of economic development. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Shafiei E, Saboohi Y, Ghofrani M (2009) Optimal policy of energy innovation in developing countries: development of solar PV in Iran. Energy Policy 37:1116–1127

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Söderholm P, Klaassen G (2007) Wind power in Europe: a simultaneous innovation-diffusion model. Environ Resour Econ 36:163–190

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Swanson R (2006) A vision for crystalline silicon photovoltaics: progress in photovoltaics. Res Appl 14:443–453

    Google Scholar 

  • Tirole J (1988) The theory of industrial organization. The MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Wiser R, Bolinger M (2008) Annual report on US wind power installation, cost, and performance trends: 2007. US Department of Energy. http://www.nrel.gov/docs/fy08osti/43025.pdf. Cited 2 Dec 2011

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Yeonbae Kim.

Appendix: Results Comparison for Different Estimation Methods

Appendix: Results Comparison for Different Estimation Methods

See Tables 8, 9, 10, 11 and 12.

Table 8 Estimation results of the invention model, solar PV
Table 9 Estimation results of the innovation model, solar PV
Table 10 Estimation results of the diffusion model, Solar PV
Table 11 Estimation results of the invention model, wind power
Table 12 Estimation results of the innovation model, wind power
Table 13 Estimation results of the diffusion model, wind power

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Kim, K., Heo, E. & Kim, Y. Dynamic Policy Impacts on a Technological-Change System of Renewable Energy: An Empirical Analysis. Environ Resource Econ 66, 205–236 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-015-9946-5

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-015-9946-5

Keywords

Navigation