Skip to main content
Log in

Paretian dictators: constraining choice in a voluntary contribution game

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Constitutional Political Economy Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We explore individuals’ preferences over limiting the choice sets of others in an environment with externalities. Specifically, we conduct public goods games in which participants can mandate the contributions of others or restrict choices to a subset of feasible contributions levels. We find that, relative to a baseline treatment in which individuals make choices from the set of all contribution alternatives, allowing individuals to constrain the choices of others results in more efficient outcomes. We discuss these results in light of the literature on behavioral theories of reciprocity and conditional cooperation and in regards to the literature on pre-constitutional design, political institutions, and social choice.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For example, while redistribution may be supported by theories of social preferences (e.g. Fehr and Fischbacher 2002), a large literature (e.g. Tullock 1959; Usher 1981) suggests that redistribution may lead to instability.

  2. Throughout the paper we refer to the outcome yielding joint wealth maximization as the Pareto efficient outcome. Such would be the case in environments with transfers.

  3. For discussions of behaviors in other types of public goods games, see Holt and Laury (2005).

  4. Other factors affecting contributions in linear public goods games include the marginal product of contributions, group size, and differences in wealth levels (Buckley and Croson 2006; Chan et al. 1996; Cherry et al. 2005; Isaac et al. 1994). Other research has suggested that contributions are driven by decision errors (e.g. Anderson et al., 1998; e.g. Goeree et al. 2002). Additionally, there is evidence that differences in the source of individuals’ endowments (and hence differences in individuals’ perceived property rights) affect allocation decisions (e.g. see Cherry et al. 2002; Hoffman and Spitzer 1985; Hoffman et al. 1994; Konow 2000; Oxoby and Spraggon 2008).

  5. Instructions available upon request.

  6. While some experiments find no difference in behavior resulting from the use of this elicitation procedure (e.g. Brandts and Charness 2000; Oxoby and McLeish 2004) other have found that the use of the strategy method affects behavior (e.g. Brosig et al. 2003). Note that our method is not strictly the strategy method (individuals are not making a schedule of decisions); rather each individual makes a decision and one individual’s decision is randomly chosen and implemented.

  7. Such high observed contributions are similar to pubic goods games with communication such as Cason and Khan (1999) and Isaac and Walker (1988) where communication between subjects results in higher contribution levels which (in the latter) are maintained and approach the efficient provision of the public good. In a related experimental design, Cason and Mui (1997) find that, consistent with Social Comparison Theory, teams of two dictators make offers which display a greater regard for others’ payoffs than single dictators. This suggests that communication, even in a sub-sample of the population, results in greater cooperative behavior.

  8. It is interesting to note that two groups in the QD treatment had implemented menus of {c Ac Bc C} = {5, 8, 10} and {c Ac Bc C} = {4, 7, 10}. In these two groups, average contributions were 5.00 (σ = 2.00) and 5.75 (σ = 1.5). This suggests that when the implemented menu left open the possibility for substantial free-riding (i.e. a value of c A significantly less than c C), participants interpreted this as a signal that the quasi-dictator (i.e. the individual who chose the implemented menu) would free-ride. This result is akin to the menu dependency discussed by Sen (1997) and identified in the experiments of Bolton et al. (2005) and Güth et al. (2001) in which “less fair” outcomes are rejected less when “more equal” allocations are unavailable. From a signalling perspective, this result is similar to the behaviors of decision makers in Van Huyck et al. (1993) in which auction bids served as signals of individuals’ intended strategies.

  9. Alternate measures of inequality (e.g. Atkinson’s index) yield similar results regarding the relative inequality across the treatments.

  10. Andreoni (1988) suggests that individuals may choose larger-than-Nash contributions strategically in repeated public goods environments.

  11. From the stance of equity theory (Walster et al. 1978), these outcomes are also efficient in that the inputs individuals have contributed are proportional to the outputs they receive. The behavior in our environment may also be reflective of the norms a decision maker thinks she and others should abide by, as suggested by the “Kantian norms” discussed in Bilodeau and Gravel (2004).

  12. In terms of limiting choices, Boudreaux and Lipford (1998) use a Buchanan-Tullock framework to argue for less inclusive voting rules in the European Union. The central idea here is that as group size and heterogeneity increases, less inclusive voting rules reduce costs. In our environment, “less inclusive” rules over contribution levels reduce the cost of uncertainty over others’ behavior, resulting in in more efficient outcomes. It should be noted that the work of Kocher et al. (2011) has demonstrated that risk preferences alone are not sufficient to explain contributions in public good games.

  13. A possible interpretation of this result is in broad terms as evidence that individuals prefer equality in treatment, as in before the law or by the government.

  14. Our experiment does not consider individuals’ willingness to give up some choices nor the value assigned to “freedom of choice” discussed by Hayek (1960) and Sen (1976).

  15. In a similar spirit, Sethi-Iyengar et al. (2004) find that participation in 401(k) plans is greater when there are fewer option choices.

References

  • Aghion, P., Alesina, A., & Trebbi, F. (2004). Endogenous political institutions. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119(2), 565–611.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, S. P., Goeree, J. K., & Holt, C. A. (1998). A theoretic analysis of altruism and decision error in public goods games. Journal of Public Economics, 70, 297–323.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andreoni, J. (1988). Why free ride? Strategies and learning in public goods environments. Journal of Public Economics, 70, 291–304.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andreoni, J. (1990). Impure altruism and donations to public goods: A theory of warm glow giving. Economic Journal, 70, 464–477.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bilodeau, M., & Gravel, N. (2004). Voluntary provision of a public good and individual morality. Journal of Public Economics, 88(3–4), 645–666.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bolton, G. E., Brandts, J., & Ockenfels, A. (2005). Fair procedures: Evidence from games involving lotteries. The Economic Journal, 115, 1054–1076.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bolton, G. E., & Ockenfels, A. (2000). A theory of equity, reciprocity, and competition. American Economic Review, 30(1), 166–193.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boudreaux, K., & Lipford, J. (1998). Group size, group heterogeneity, and voting rule: An application of the Buchanan-Tullock model to the European Union. European Journal of Law and Economics, 5, 133–152.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brandts, J., & Charness, G. (2000). Hot vs. cold: Sequential responses and preference stability in experimental games. Experimental Ecnoomics, 2, 227–238.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brosig, J., Weimann, J., & Yang, C.-L. (2003). The hot versus cold effect in a simple bargaining experiment. Experimental Economics, 6(1), 75–90.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J., & Tullock, G. (1962). The calculus of consent. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buckley, E., & Croson, R. (2006). Income and wealth heterogeneity in the voluntary provision of linear public goods. Journal of Public Economics, 90(4–5), 935–955.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cason, T. N., & Khan, F. U. (1999). A laboratory study of voluntary public goods provision with imperfect monitoring and communication. Journal of Development Economics, 58(2), 533–552.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cason, T. N., & Mui, V.-L. (1997). A laboratory study of group polarisation in the team dictator game. Economic Journal, 107(444), 1465–83.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cettolin, E., & Riedl, A. (2011). Partial coercion, conditional cooperation, and self-commitment in voluntary contributions to public goods. Technical report.

  • Chan, K. S., Godby, R., Mestelman, S., & Muller, R. A. (1996). Spite, guilt and the voluntary provision of public goods when income is not distributed equally. Canadian Journal of Economics, 29(2), S605–S609.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Charness, G., & Rabin, M. (2002). Understanding social preferences with simple tests. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(3), 817–869.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cherry, T. L., Frykblom, P., & Shogren, J. F. (2002). Hardnose the dictator. American Economic Review, 92(4), 1218–1221.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cherry, T. L., Shogren, J. F., & Kroll, S. (2005). The impact of endowment heterogeneity and origin on public good contributions: Evidence from the lab. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 57(3), 357–365.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Croson, R., Fatas, E., & Neugebauer, T. (2005). Reciprocity, matching and conditional cooperation in two public goods games. Economics Letters, 87(1), 95–101.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dufwenberg, M., & Kirchsteiger, G. (2004). A theory of sequential reciprocity. Games and Economic Behavior, 47(2), 268–298.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Falk, A., & Fischbacher, U. (2006). A theory of reciprocity. Games and Economic Behavior, 54(2), 293–315.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, E., & Fischbacher, U. (2002). Why social preferences matter—The impact of non-selfish motives on competition, cooperation, and incentives. The Economic Journal, 112, C1–C33.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, E., & Gächter, S. (2000). Cooperation and punishment in public goods experiments. American Economic Review, 90(4), 980–994.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, E., & Gächter, S. (2001). Fairness and retaliation: The economics of reciprocity. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 14(3), 159–181.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, E., & Schmidt, K. (1999). A theory of fairness, competition, and cooperation. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(3), 817–868.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fischbacher, U. (2007). z-Tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments. Experimental Economics, 10(2), 171–178.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fischbacher, U., Gächter, S., & Fehr, E. (2001). Are people conditionally cooperative? Evidence from a public goods experiment. Economics Letters, 71, 397–404.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fischbacher, U., & Gaechter, S. (2008). Social preferences, beliefs, and the dynamics of free riding in public good experiments. Technical report.

  • Gächter, S., & Riedl, A. (2005). Moral property rights in bargaining with infeasible claims. Management Science, 51(2), 249–263.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goeree, J. K., Holt, C. A., & Laury, S. K. (1999, September). Altruism and noisy behavior in one-shot public goods experiments. Virginia Economics online papers 331, University of Virginia, Department of Economics.

  • Goeree, J. K., Holt, C. A., & Laury, S. K. (2002). Private costs and public benefits: unraveling the effects of altruism and noisy behavior. Journal of Public Economics, 83(2), 255–276.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greiner, B. (2004). The online recruitment system ORSEE 2.0—a guide for the organzation of experiments in economics. Working paper series in Economics 10, University of Cologne.

  • Güth, W., Huck, S., & Mueller, W. (2001). The relevance of equal splits in ultimatum games. Games and Economic Behavior, 37, 161–169.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harstad, B. (2005). Majority rules and incentives. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 2005(120), 1535–1568.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1955). The political ideal of the rule of law. Cairo: National Bank of Egypt.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1960). The constitution of liberty. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hoffman, E., McCabe, K., & Smith, V. L. (1994). Preferences, property rights, and anonymity in bargaining games. Games and Economic Behavior, 7, 346–380.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hoffman, E., & Spitzer, M. (1985). Entitlements, rights, and fairness: An experimental examination of subjects’ concepts of distributive justice. Journal of Legal Studies, 14, 259–297.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holt, C. A., & Laury, S. K. (2005). Theoretical explanations of treatment effects in voluntary contributions experiments. In C. Plott & V. Smith (Eds.), Handbook of experimental economics results, Vol. 1. New York: Elsevier Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Isaac, R. M., & Walker, J. M. (1988). Communication and free-riding behavior: The voluntary contribution mechanism. Economic Inquiry, 26(4), 585–608.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Isaac, R. M., Walker, J. M., & Schmidtz, D. (1989). The assurance problem in a laboratory market. Public Choice, 62, 217–236.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Isaac, R. M., Walker, J. M., Williams, A. W. (1994). Group size and the voluntary provision of public goods: Experimental evidence utilizing large groups. Journal of Public Economics, 54(1), 1–36.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Iyengar, S. S., & Lepper, M. R. (2000). When choice is demotivating: Can one desire too much of a good thing?. Journal of Personalilty and Social Psychology, 79(6), 995–1006.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keser, C., & van Winden, F. (2000). Conditional cooperation and voluntary contributions to public goods. Scandanavian Journal of Economics, 102(1), 23–39.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kocher, M. G., Martinsson, P., Matzat, D., & Wollbrant, C., (2011, January). The role of beliefs, trust, and risk in contributions to a public good. Working papers in Economics 482, University of Gothenburg, Department of Economics.

  • Kocher, M. G., Martinsson, P., & Visser, M. (2008). Does stake size matter for cooperation and punishment?. Economics Letters, 99(3), 508–511.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Konow, J. (2000). Fair shares: Accountability and cognitive dissonance in allocation decisions. American Economic Review, 90(4), 1072–1091.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Konow, J. (2003). Which is the fairest one of all? A positive analysis of justice theories. Journal of Economic Literature, 41(4), 1186–1237.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kroll, S., Cherry, T. L., & Shogren, J. F. (2007). Voting, punishment, and public goods. Economic Inquiry, 45(3), 557–570.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laffont, J.-J. (1975). Macroeconomic constraints, economic efficiency and ethics: An introduction to kantian economics. Economica, 42(168), 430–37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ledyard, J. O. (1995). Public goods: A survey of experimental research. In J. H. Kagel & A. E. Roth (Eds.), Handbook of experimental economics. New Jersey: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marks, M., & Croson, R. (1998). Alternative rebate rules in the provision of a threshold public good: An experimental investigation. Journal of Public Economics, 67(2), 195–220.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oxoby, R. J., & McLeish, K. N. (2004). Sequential decision and strategy vector methods in ultimatum bargaining: Evidence on the strength of other-regarding behavior. Economics Letters, 84(3), 399–405.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oxoby, R. J., & Spraggon, J. (2008). Yours and mine: Property rights in dictator games. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 65, 703–713.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sen, A. K. (1970). The impossibility of a Paretian liberal. Journal of Political Economy, 78, 152–157.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sen, A. K. (1976). Liberty, unanimity, and rights. Economica, 43, 217–245.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sen, A. K. (1997). Maximization and the act of choice. Econometrica, 65, 745–779.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sethi-Iyengar, S., Huberman, G., & Jiang, W. (2004). How much choice is too much? Contributions to 401(k) retirement plans. In O. S. Mitchell & S. Utkus (Eds.), Pension design and structure: new lessons from behavioral finance. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Spraggon, J. M., & Oxobby, R. J. (2009). Game theory for playing games: Sophistication in a negative-externality experiment. Economic Inquiry, 47(3), 467–481.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1959). Problems of majority voting. Journal of Political Economy, 67, 571–579.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Usher, D. (1981). The economic prerequisite to democracy. New York: Columbia University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Van Huyck, J. B., Battalio, R. C., & Beil, R. O. (1993). Asset markets as an equilibrium selection mechanism: Coordination failure, game form auctions, and tacit communication. Games and Economic Behavior, 5(3), 485–504.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Voigt, S. (1997). Positive constitutional economics: A survey. Public Choice, 90, 11–53.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Walker, J. M., & Halloran, M. A. (2004). Rewards and sanctions and the provision of public goods in one-shot settings. Experimental Economics, 7(3), 235–247.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Walster, E., Walster, G., & Berscheid, E. (1978). Equity: Theory and research. Boston: Allyn and Bacon.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zelmer, J. (2003). Linear public goods experiments: A meta-analysis. Experimental Economics, 5, 299–310.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We thank Robin Boadway, John Boyce, Francisco Gonzalez, Erin Krupka, Michael McKee, Kendra McLeish and John Spraggon for suggestions. Financial support was provided by the Social Sciences and Humanities Research Council of Canada and the Canadian Institute for Advanced Research.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Robert J. Oxoby.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Oxoby, R.J. Paretian dictators: constraining choice in a voluntary contribution game. Const Polit Econ 24, 125–138 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10602-013-9139-6

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10602-013-9139-6

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation