Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Corruption in public health and its effects on the economic growth of Brazilian municipalities

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
The European Journal of Health Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This study’s objective is to estimate the effects of corruption in the public health sector on the economic growth of Brazilian municipalities. To build three corruption measures, data from audits conducted by the office of the comptroller general (Controladoria Geral da Uniao, CGU henceforth) in 2009 and 2010 in the health and sanitation sectors were used. Two analysis steps were performed. The first verified the relationship between the performance of the audit and the economic growth rate of the municipalities, using the Ordinary Least Squares (OLS); the second analyses the effects of corruption on public health on the economic growth of the audited municipalities, using OLS and Quantile Regressions. First, in a sample of 5547 municipalities, the evidence indicates that being audited is related to slower economic growth. From this, when the sample is restricted to the 180 municipalities audited in 2009 and the corruption variables constructed from the audit reports conducted in the year, the results indicate negative effects of corruption on economic growth. The results show that in the larger quantiles of economic growth, the adverse effects of corruption are felt more significantly. Both methods tested with the three corruption variables created provide similar evidence, showing robustness of results. Therefore, the study allowed us to conclude that corruption in the public health sector hampered the economic growth of Brazilian municipalities, which is a delayed effect: Corruption in 2009 had negative effects on growth in 2011.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See more: https://www.transparency.org/cpi2018.

  2. Civil Society Organization of Public Interest, consisting of companies seeking advances in basic sanitation and the protection of the country’s water resources.

  3. As per note of FIESP [14], after postponement the deadline in 2015, only 31% of the municipalities declared to have the Municipal Basic Sanitation Plan and another 38% declared to be in the elaboration phase yet.

  4. Full news: www.g1.globo.com/jornal-nacional/noticia/2017/04/operacao-da-pf-investiga-esquema-decorrupcao-na-area-da-saude-do-rj.html.

  5. Henceforth, we will refer to the health and sanitation sectors as the public health sector.

  6. Table 10 in the Appendix shows the correlations between the corruption indices.

  7. In the appendix, we present Table 13, which shows evidence that there is no reverse effect of corruption on economic growth.

  8. Estimation of corruption occurrences for the median was not statistically significant, although the graph gives us the opposite impression. As a matter of curiosity, we estimated the model to a position close to the median 0.55 and observed significance of the explanatory variable, which helped us to better understand the graphical result.

  9. We also present in the Appendix the results obtained for Wald tests performed (See Table 15).

  10. In this case, ∆= ∆t −∆t− 1.

References

  1. Achim, M.V., Vaidean, V.L., Borlea, S.N.: Corruption and health outcomes within an economic and cultural framework. Eur. J. Health Econ. (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10198-019-01120-8

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  2. Aidt, T.S.: Corruption, institutions, and economic development. Oxf. Rev. Econ. Policy 25, 271–291 (2009)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  3. Avelino, G., Barberia, L.G., Biderman, C.: Governance in managing public health resources in Brazilian municipalities. Health Policy Plann. 29, 694–702 (2013)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  4. Barro, R.J.: Government spending in a simple model of endogenous growth. J. Polit. Econ. 98, 103–125 (1990)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  5. Billger, S.M., Goel, R.K.: Do existing corruption levels matter in controlling corruption? Cross-country quantile regression estimates. J. Dev. Econ. 90, 299–305 (2009)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  6. Brollo, F., Nannicini, T., Perotti, R., Tabellini, G.: The political resource curse. Am. Econ. Rev. 103, 1759–1796 (2013)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  7. Cerqueti, R., Coppier, R.: Economic growth, corruption and tax evasion. Econ. Modell. 28, 489–500 (2011)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  8. Chen, B.-L.: Tax evasion in a model of endogenous growth. Rev. Econ. Dyn. 6, 381–403 (2003)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  9. DAgostino, G., Dunne, J.P., Pieroni, L.: Government spending, corruption and economic growth. World Dev. (2016). https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2016.03.011

    Article  Google Scholar 

  10. Ertimi, B.E., et al.: The impact of corruption on economic growth in OIC countries. Int. J. Econ. Financ. 8, 91 (2016)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  11. Ferraz, C., Finan, F.: Exposing corrupt politicians: the effects of brazil’s publicly released audits on electoral outcomes. Q. J. Econ. 123, 703–745 (2008)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  12. Ferraz, C., Finan, F.: Electoral accountability and corruption: evidence from the audits of local governments. Am. Econ. Rev. 101, 1274–1311 (2011)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  13. Ferraz, C., Finan, F., Moreira, D.B.: Corrupting learning evidence from missing federal education funds in brazil. J. Public Econ. 96, 712–726 (2012)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  14. FIESP Só 31% dos municípios brasileiros tem plano municipal de saneamento básico, segundo Ministério das Cidades. Report, Federação das Indústrias do Estado de São Paulo (2015)

  15. Goel, R.K., Ram, R.: Quantile-regression estimates of cigarette demand elasticities for the united states. J. Econ. Financ. 28, 413–421 (2004)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  16. Gyimah-Brempong, K.: Corruption, economic growth, and income inequality in Africa. Econ. Gov. 3, 183–209 (2002)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  17. Johnson, S., Kaufmann, D., Zoido-Lobaton, P.: Regulatory discretion and the unofficial economy. Am. Econ. Rev. 88, 387–392 (1998)

    Google Scholar 

  18. Koenker, R., Bassett, J.G.: Regression quantiles. Econometrica 46, 33–50 (1978)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  19. Leff, N.H.: Economic development through bureaucratic corruption. Am. Behav. Sci. 8, 8–14 (1964)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  20. Lichand, G.M., Lopes, M.: Is corruption good for your health? (Job Market Paper) (2016)

  21. Loayza N.A.: The economics of the informal sector: a simple model and some empirical evidence from Latin America. Policy Research Working Paper (1997)

  22. Mackey, T.K., Vian, T., Kohler, J.: The sustainable development goals as a framework to combat health-sector corruption. Bull. World Health Organ. 96, 634–643 (2018)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  23. Mankiw, N.G.D., Romer, D.N.: A contribution to the empirics of economic growth. Q. J. Econ. (1992). https://doi.org/10.3386/w3541

    Article  Google Scholar 

  24. Mauro, P.: Corruption and growth. Q. J. Econ. 110, 681–712 (1995)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  25. Mendonça, H.F.D., Baca, A.C.: Relevance of corruption on the effect of public health expenditure and taxation on economic growth. Appl. Econ. Lett. (2017). https://doi.org/10.1080/13504851.2017.1374533

    Article  Google Scholar 

  26. Mo, P.H.: Corruption and economic growth. J. Compar. Econ. (2001). https://doi.org/10.1006/jcec.2000.1703

    Article  Google Scholar 

  27. Moreira, S., Barros, P.P.: Double health insurance coverage and health care utilization: evidence from quantile regression. Health Econ. 19, 1075–1092 (2010)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  28. Pasioura, F., et al.: How bureaucracy and corruption affect economic growth and convergence in the European Union. Manag. Fin. 39, 837–847 (2013)

    Google Scholar 

  29. Pereira, M.W.G., Cruz, W.V.: Corruption in a neoclassical growth model with a non-convex production function. Int. Rev. Econ. 59, 335–346 (2010)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  30. Pusok, K.: Public-private partnerships and corruption in the water and sanitation sectors in developing countries. Polit. Res. Q. (2016). https://doi.org/10.1177/1065912916658552

    Article  Google Scholar 

  31. Resende, G.M., de Figueiredo, L.: Economic growth of Minas Gerais, 1980-2000: a quantile regression approach. RDE Revista de Desenvolvimento Econômico 21, 100–111 (2010)

    Google Scholar 

  32. Robert, J.B.: Economic growth, 2nd edn. The MIT Press, London (2003)

    Google Scholar 

  33. Swaleheen, M.: Economic growth with endogenous corruption: an empirical study. Public Choice 146, 23–41 (2011)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  34. Tanzi, V., H. R. Davoodi: Corruption, growth and public finances. IMF Working Paper (2000)

  35. Temple, J.: The new growth evidence. J. Econ. Lit. 37, 112–156 (1999)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  36. Trata Brasil Institute and Reinfra Consultoria: Análise dos impactos na saúde decorrentes de agravos relacionados a um saneamento básico inadequado nos 100 maiores municípios brasileiros em população, no período 2007–2014. Technical report, Trata Brasil Institute (2017)

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Eduarda Machoski.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix

Appendix

Economic growth and corruption

This section presents a version of the neoclassical economic growth model applied to the public health sector. Building on neoclassical growth models such as those of Barro [4] and Robert [32], Pereira and da Cruz Vieira [29] develop a model that considers the effects of bureaucrat corruption on economic growth.

The economy is made up of agents, firms, and the public sector. In this case, non-bureaucratic agents, m, are the society, and bureaucratic agents, n, are politicians and policy makers. Firms form the private sector of the economy, consisting of engineering offices, laboratories, and other entities. Agents are optimizers, so they seek to maximize their usefulness over time:

Agents are optimizers, so they seek to maximize their usefulness over time:

$${ \hbox{max} }\mathop \smallint \limits_{0}^{\infty } u\left[ {c\left( t \right)} \right]e^{ - \delta t} dt.$$

It is assumed that a fraction of these agents, more specifically bureaucrats, are corrupt; that is, they divert public resources to benefit their private consumption. Each corrupt bureaucrat has access to a \({\raise0.7ex\hbox{${\tau y}$} \!\mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{\tau y} n}}\right.\kern-0pt} \!\lower0.7ex\hbox{$n$}}\) amount of public resources that can be diverted for his own benefit. He or she will choose to be corrupt if:

$$\varPhi \left( {w - \sigma + \frac{\tau y}{n}} \right) \ge w - \sigma ,$$

where Φ is the probability of the agent not being corrupt. By acting corruptly, the agent longs for greater utility. That is, given that utility is a function of consumption, the bureaucrat chooses to divert public resources and act corruptly knowing that the income from this behavior is greater than the income from acting honestly, since the term \({\raise0.7ex\hbox{${\tau y}$} \!\mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{\tau y} n}}\right.\kern-0pt} \!\lower0.7ex\hbox{$n$}}\) is predominantly positive.

It is also assumed that such diverted resources were intended exclusively for the provision of public goods and services—in this case, of the public health sector. Therefore, the corruption of this dishonest fraction of bureaucrats diminishes the public provision of such services, harming society (non-bureaucratic agents). In addition, in the presence of corruption, the rate of capital and asset accumulation is lower. Thus, the marginal productivity of capital is reduced, reducing the level of investments as well as the level of consumption of agents. As a result, there is a reduction in consumption growth rates, capital accumulation, and economic output growth. Therefore, in this study’s case, the presence of corruption supposedly causes a reduction in the public supply of goods and services related to the public health sector. Thus, the economy is affected in many ways, with the reduction of the economic growth rate the final effect.

See Figs. 6 and 7.

See Tables 915.

Fig. 6
figure 6

Total municipalities audited by state—2009 and 2010. Source CGU data, worked by the authors

Fig. 7
figure 7

Effects of corruption occurrences (2009) and irregular fraction of the amount (2009) on the municipal. GDP growth rates quantiles (2011)—models with controls. Source Own elaboration

Table 9 Definition and sources of the variables used
Table 10 Correlation matrices between corruption indices—2009 and 2010
Table 11 Descriptive statistics of municipal GDP growth rates, 2009–2011, Municipalities audited in 2009
Table 12 Descriptive statistics of control variables—Municipalities audited in 2009
Table 13 Relationship between corruption indices (2009) and municipal GDP growth rate (2008)
Table 14 Effects of corruption (2009) on the quantiles of municipal GDP growth rate (2011)
Table 15 Wald test results—Quantile regressions

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Machoski, E., de Araujo, J.M. Corruption in public health and its effects on the economic growth of Brazilian municipalities. Eur J Health Econ 21, 669–687 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10198-020-01162-3

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10198-020-01162-3

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation