Skip to main content
Log in

Best-response equilibrium: an equilibrium in finitely additive mixed strategies

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
International Journal of Game Theory Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

A generalization of mixed strategy equilibrium is proposed, where mixed strategies need only be finitely additive and payoff functions are not required to be integrable or bounded. This notion of best-response equilibrium is based on an extension of the idea that an equilibrium strategy is supported in the player’s set of best-response actions, but is applicable also when no best-response actions exist. It yields simple, natural equilibria in a number of well-known games where other kinds of mixed equilibrium are complicated, not compelling or do not exist.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

We’re sorry, something doesn't seem to be working properly.

Please try refreshing the page. If that doesn't work, please contact support so we can address the problem.

We’re sorry, something doesn't seem to be working properly.

Please try refreshing the page. If that doesn't work, please contact support so we can address the problem.

Notes

  1. This contrasts with the usual definition of mixed strategy, where the domain is some pre-specified measurable structure on \(S_{i}\), for example, the collection of all Borel sets. A conceptual problem with the latter approach is that, unless \(S_{i}\) is finite, the choice of measurable structure is arguably arbitrary, as it is not indicated by the game itself. Yet choosing it is necessary for defining the mixed extension of the game, where players use mixed strategies rather than actions. In the framework presented here, there is no mixed extension.

  2. An example is \(f(x,\;y) = x\sin 1/y:(0,\;1)^{2} \to {\mathbb{R}}\). With \(\mu_{1} = \mu_{2} = \delta_{{0^{ + } }}\) and the algebra \({\mathcal{I} }\) (both are defined at the end of Sect. 3), \(\int f\,d\mu = \int \int f\,d\mu_{1}\, d\mu_{2} = 0\) but the other iterated integral does not exist.

  3. Recall that the asterisk denotes outer measure.

  4. An open problem is to find a two-player game with bounded payoff functions that does not have a best-response equilibrium, or to prove that such a game does not exist.

  5. The collection of all sets \(A\) satisfying the first or second condition is easily seen to be an algebra. If neither condition holds, \(A\) is not measurable. However, by Proposition 2, there are extensions of \(\sigma\) that render all sets measurable. Such an extension is the function \(A \mapsto \mathop {\lim }\nolimits_{n \to \infty } \delta_{{s^{n} }} (A)\), where \({\text{lim}}\) refers to some fixed Banach limit (so that it exists for every bounded sequence).

  6. More generally, for any \(S \subseteq {\mathbb{R}}\), the collection \(\left\{ {A \cap S \mid A \in {\mathcal{I}}} \right\}\) is an algebra on \(S\), which may also be denoted by \({\mathcal{I}}\) if the meaning is clear from the context.

  7. For an alternative solution to the problem of nonexistence of equilibrium, which employs a set-valued solution concept, see Milchtaich (2019).

  8. It is easy to see that a legitimate equilibrium \(\sigma\) remains so if one (or more) of the algebras \({\mathcal{A}}_{i}\) is replaced by a subalgebra, to which the strategy \(\sigma_{i}\) is restricted. Note that this is the opposite of the situation for best-response equilibria, which are preserved by extensions rather than restrictions.

References

  • Bhaskara Rao KPS, Bhaskara Rao M (1983) Theory of charges: a study of finitely additive measures. Academic Press, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Dasgupta P, Maskin E (1986) The existence of equilibrium in discontinuous economic games, I: theory. Rev Econ Stud 53:1–26

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dastidar KG (2011) Existence of Bertrand equilibrium revisited. Int J Econ Theory 7:331–350

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de Finetti B (1974) Theory of probability. Wiley, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Dubins LE, Savage LJ (2014) How to gamble if you must: inequalities for stochastic processes. Edited and updated by Sudderth WD, Gilat D. Dover, New York

  • Dunford N, Schwartz JT (1988) Linear operators. Part I. Wiley, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Eaton BC, Lipsey RG (1975) The principle of minimum differentiation reconsidered: some new developments in the theory of spatial competition. Rev Econ Stud 42:27–49

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Flesch J, Vermeulen D, Zseleva A (2021) Legitimate equilibrium. Int J Game Theory 50:787–800

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harris CJ, Stinchcombe MB, Zame WR (2005) Nearly compact and continuous normal form games: characterizations and equilibrium existence. Games Econ Behav 50:208–224

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hoernig SH (2007) Bertrand games and sharing rules. Econ Theory 31:573–585

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Karlin S (1950) Operator treatment of minmax principle. In: Kuhn HW, Tucker AW (eds) Contributions to the theory of games I, Annals of Mathematics Studies, vol 24. Princeton University Press, Princeton, pp 133–154

    Google Scholar 

  • Marinacci M (1997) Finitely additive and epsilon Nash equilibria. Int J Game Theory 26:315–333

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Milchtaich I (2019) Polyequilibrium. Games Econ Behav 113:339–355. https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0899825618301556

  • Osborne MJ, Pitchik C (1986) The nature of equilibrium in a location model. Int Econ Rev 27:223–237

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Savage, LJ (1954) The foundations of statistics. Wiley, New York (Revised and enlarged edition, Dover, New York, 1972)

  • Shaked A (1982) Existence and computation of mixed strategy Nash equilibrium for 3-firms location problem. J Ind Econ 31:93–96

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sion M, Wolfe P (1957) On a game without a value. In: Dresher M, Tucker AW, Wolfe P (eds) Contributions to the theory of games III, Annals of Mathematics Studies, vol 39. Princeton University Press, Princeton, pp 299–306

    Google Scholar 

  • Vasquez MA (2017) Optimistic equilibria in finitely additive mixed strategies. Mimeo

  • Ville J (1938) Sur la théorie général des jeux où intervient l’habilité des joueurs. In: Traité du Calcul des Probabilités et de ses Applications by Borel É et al., vol 2, Paris, pp 105–113

  • von Neumann J, Morgenstern O (1953) Theory of games and economic behavior, 3rd edn. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Yanovskaya EB (1970) The solution of infinite zero-sum two-person games with finitely additive strategies. Theory Probab Appl 15:153–158

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

I am grateful to János Flesch and Miklós Pintér for stimulating discussions concerning the subject matter. I also thank two anonymous referees for their detailed and helpful reports.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Igal Milchtaich.

Additional information

Communicated by Bernhard von Stengel.

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Milchtaich, I. Best-response equilibrium: an equilibrium in finitely additive mixed strategies. Int J Game Theory 52, 1317–1334 (2023). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00182-023-00871-2

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00182-023-00871-2

Keywords

Navigation