Skip to main content

Regional Policy and Fiscal Competition

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Regional Research Frontiers - Vol. 1

Part of the book series: Advances in Spatial Science ((ADVSPATIAL))

Abstract

Governments around the world implement policies aimed at developing certain geographic areas or regions within their respective countries. During the last few decades, local authorities have been assuming a predominant role in the design and execution of these policies. It has been argued that the decentralization of such responsibilities can potentially induce regional governments to behave strategically, initiating a fiscal competition game that would diminish the effectiveness of regional policies. This chapter critically reviews some of the most recent advancements in the literature, focusing on the work that examines the impact of fiscal competition on policy outcomes. At the same time, it intends to identify issues that require further study and provide guidance on the direction of future research in the area.

The views expressed are those of the author and do not necessarily represent official positions of the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, or of the Federal Reserve System.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 119.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 159.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 159.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. 1.

    The literature on fiscal competition, both theoretical and empirical, is very extensive. For survey papers in this area, see Brueckner (2006), Wildasin (2003), Wildasin (2006), or Zodrow (2010).

  2. 2.

    Wilson (1986) and Zodrow and Mieszkowski (1986) were the first papers to formalize this idea.

  3. 3.

    Even though this chapter examines exclusively models of fiscal competition involving regional governments (also known as models of horizontal fiscal competition), it is important to acknowledge that a strand of the literature has focused on the outcomes arising from the strategic interaction between different levels of governments (vertical fiscal competition). In the latter case, strategic behavior may be triggered by the fact that the regional and federal governments levy taxes on the same tax base.

  4. 4.

    See Ladd (1994) for a detailed classification of policies aimed at dealing with distressed areas.

  5. 5.

    See Epple and Nechyba (2004) for a survey on fiscal decentralization.

  6. 6.

    For example, it is generally believed that regional governments are limited in their capabilities of redistributing income because household mobility reduces the effectiveness of these policies. As a result, the federal government should undertake this responsibility.

  7. 7.

    We will revisit the assumptions required for this conclusion to hold in Sect. 13.4.

  8. 8.

    See Brueckner (2004) for a detailed discussion on the benefits and costs of centralization versus decentralization. Wildasin (1991) focuses on income redistributive policies and explores what happens when different levels of government are responsible for undertaking such polices.

  9. 9.

    All policies should aim at improving the well-being of people. The difference between policies rests on the specific way in which they are structured to achieve the intend goal. To some extent, the discussion about which policy is better has been exaggerated. Empirical evidence is far from conclusive, suggesting that no policy clearly dominates another.

  10. 10.

    The complete list of assumptions is the following: (i) consumers are perfectly mobile; (ii) there is full information; (iii) the number of communities is large; (iv) income is exogenous; (v) there are no spillovers across communities; (vi) the average cost curve for the provision of local public goods is U-shaped (i.e. there exists a cost minimizing population size); and (vii) communities with population sizes below (above) the cost minimizing size seek to expand (contract).

  11. 11.

    The basic tax competition model, for example, focuses on the strategic determination of capital tax rates. Regional governments, however, compete on many other dimensions, so fiscal competition takes place through multiple channels.

  12. 12.

    In the basic tax competition literature, the outcome is characterized by a lower than optimal spending on local public goods. The fact that the size of the local public sector becomes smaller under tax competition is not perceived as something necessarily bad by the public choice literature. This literature (see, for example, Brennan and Buchanan 1980) questions the assumption that governments are benevolent and choose the tax rates that maximize the welfare of their citizens. The primary objective of self-interested, rent-seeking governments, according to this view, is to maximize tax revenues and use those resources for unproductive purposes. So anything that would limit such behavior would be an improvement for the society.

  13. 13.

    See, for example, Besley and Case (1995).

  14. 14.

    Decisions by regional governments may generate other types of spillovers, such as direct geographic spillovers, which do not affect the relocation of mobile factors of production. For instance, consider spending on pollution abatement. When a region devotes more resources to reduce pollution, it creates a positive externality on neighboring jurisdictions. The latter does not include the case in which regions strategically choose regulatory policies to attract firms. Also, parks and other local amenities provided by one jurisdiction may be enjoyed and visited by residents from other locations. The decentralized solution in these two examples, as in the previous cases of fiscal competition, will also be sub-optimal, and a system of inter-regional transfers would be required to restore efficiency. This chapter will not focus on these external effects, however, since in principle they do not generate fiscal competition among regions.

  15. 15.

    The model presented here follows closely Brueckner (2006).

  16. 16.

    Note that in the case of R regions, z would simply represent an (R × 1) vector of policies.

  17. 17.

    Assuming that the second-order condition for a maximum \(\partial ^{2}V ^{i}(\mathbf{z})/\partial (z^{i})^{2}\ \equiv \ V _{z^{i}z^{i}}^{i}(\mathbf{z}) < 0\) holds.

  18. 18.

    It is generally assumed that decisions are made simultaneously. Among other things, this setup considers a situation in which no jurisdiction have the advantage of moving first.

  19. 19.

    It should be noted that in general region i’s best response to z j may consist of a set of values of z i. This means that b i(z j) is actually a correspondence rather than a function. When not necessary, we will stay away from such technicalities and refer to b i(z j) simply as a function.

  20. 20.

    While some papers derive the optimal allocations from the central planner’s problem and compares the optimal allocations to the decentralized solution, most of the literature simply compares the outcomes arising in the non-cooperative (decentralized) and cooperative (centralized) cases. In the latter case, it is assumed that governments have access to the same set of policy instruments.

  21. 21.

    Note that this is different to the effect of policy z i on the marginal payoffs \(V _{z^{j}}\) defined earlier, or \(V _{z^{j}z^{i}}^{j}(\mathbf{z})\). Eaton (2004) classifies policies depending on their effects on the payoffs of the other region. Specifically, policies are called plain complements when the spillover effects are positive, and plain substitutes when they are negative.

  22. 22.

    For example, Rota-Graziosi (2015) provides conditions to establish the plain and strategic complementarity of capital tax rates in the traditional tax competition.

  23. 23.

    Another complication arises when households are also mobile, in which case it is necessary to keep track of where capital is employed and where households end up residing.

  24. 24.

    See, for instance, Brueckner and Saavedra (2001), or Vrijburg and Mooij (2016), for further discussion.

  25. 25.

    The theory on supermodular games has been used until now simply to characterize the solution of the basic model of fiscal competition. However, to some extent, this theory has been underexploited in the literature. This theory is a lot more general, and can be applied to more complicated games in which regions have access to multiple policy instruments.

  26. 26.

    For instance, the effects may compensate each other.

  27. 27.

    Pinto (2007a) considers another model in which regional governments choose more than one policy instrument. Specifically, the paper studies the strategic determination of the structure of the corporate profit tax system when firms operate in multiple regions and regions use an apportionment formula to calculate the proportion of the firms’ income subject to regional taxation. The formula, as used in the USA, assigns weights to the proportion of the firm’s total sales, property, and payroll in a state. In the model, regions choose both the corporate income tax rate and the type of formula.

  28. 28.

    See, for example, Forslid (2005) and Baldwin et al. (2005), for a review of the literature.

  29. 29.

    These challenges have been pointed out by Brueckner (2006) or Isen (2014), for example.

  30. 30.

    It should be emphasized that the development of these techniques is far from uniform across different fields in economics. See, for example, Nevo and Whinston (2010) and Heckman and Vytlacil (2007) for general discussions on structural methods, and Epple and Nechyba (2004) or Holmes and Sieg (2015) for surveys on different applications of structural estimation to urban equilibrium and local public finance models.

  31. 31.

    Some recent work has already taken such direction. For instance, Ossa (2015) uses a quantitative economic geography model to study the motives underlying the decision to subsidize the relocation of firms by regional governments.

References

  • Baldwin R, Forslid R, Martin P (2005) Economic geography and public policy. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Besley T, Case A (1995) Incumbent behavior: vote seeking, tax setting and yardstick competition. Am Econ Rev 85(1):25–45.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brennan G, Buchanan JM (1980) The power to tax: analytic foundations of a fiscal constitution. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Brueckner JK (2004) Fiscal decentralization with distortionary taxation: Tiebout vs. tax competition. Int Tax Public Financ 11(2):133–153

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brueckner JK (2006) Strategic interaction among governments. In: Arnott RJ, McMillen DP (eds) A companion to urban economics. Blackwell Publishing Ltd, Malden, pp 332–347

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Brueckner JK, Saavedra LA (2001) Do local governments engage in strategic property–tax competition? Natl Tax J 54(2):203–229

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eaton CB (2004) The elementary economics of social dilemmas. Can J Econ 37(4), 805–829

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Epple D, Nechyba T (2004) Fiscal decentralization. In: Handbook of regional and urban economics, vol 4. Elsevier, Amsterdam, Chap. 55, pp 2423–2480

    Google Scholar 

  • Forslid R (2005) Tax competition and agglomeration: main effects and empirical implications. Swed Econ Policy Rev 12(1):113

    Google Scholar 

  • Heckman JJ, Vytlacil EJ (2007) Econometric evaluation of social programs, Part I: causal models, structural models and econometric policy evaluation. In: Heckman JJ, Leamer EE (eds) Handbook of econometrics, Part B, vol. 6, Elsevier, Amsterdam, Chap. 70, pp 4779–4874

    Google Scholar 

  • Holmes TJ, Sieg H (2015) Structural estimation in urban economics. In: Duranton G, Henderson JV, Strange WC (eds) Handbook of regional and urban economics, vol 5. Elsevier, Amsterdam, Chap. 2, pp 69–114

    Google Scholar 

  • Isen A (2014) Do local government fiscal spillovers exist? evidence from counties, municipalities, and school districts. J Public Econ 110(C):57–73

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ladd HF (1994) Spatially targeted economic development strategies: do they work? Cityscape 1(1):193–218

    Google Scholar 

  • Nevo A, Whinston MD (2010) Taking the dogma out of econometrics: Structural modeling and credible inference. J Econ Perspect 24(2):69–81

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ossa R (2015) A quantitative analysis of subsidy competition in the US. NBER Working Paper 20975

    Google Scholar 

  • Pinto SM (2007a) Corporate profit tax, capital mobility, and formula apportionment. J Urban Econ 62(1):76–102

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pinto SM (2007b) Tax competition in the presence of interjurisdictional externalities: The case of crime prevention. J Reg Sci 47(5):897–913

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pinto PM, Pinto SM (2008) The politics of investment partisanship and the sectoral allocation of foreign direct investment. Econ Polit 20(2):216–254

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rota-Graziosi G (2015) The supermodularity of the tax competition game. Working Paper

    Google Scholar 

  • Tiebout CM (1956) A pure theory of local expenditures. J Polit Econ 64(5):416–424

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vrijburg H, de Mooij RA (2016) Tax rates as strategic substitutes. Int Tax Public Financ 23:1–23

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wilson JD (1986) A theory of interregional tax competition. J Urban Econ 19(3):296–315

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wildasin DE (1988) Nash equilibria in models of fiscal competition. J Public Econ 35(2): 229–240

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wildasin DE (1991) Income redistribution in a common labor market. Am Econ Rev 81(4), 757–774

    Google Scholar 

  • Wildasin D (2003) Fiscal competition: an introduction. J Public Econ 5(2):169–176

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wildasin DE (2006) Fiscal competition. The Oxford handbook of political economy. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 502–520

    Google Scholar 

  • Zodrow GR (2010) Capital mobility and capital tax competition. Natl Tax J 63(4):865–901

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zodrow GR, Mieszkowski P (1986) Pigou, Tiebout, property taxation, and the underprovision of local public goods. J Urban Econ 19(3):356–370

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Santiago M. Pinto .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2017 Springer International Publishing AG

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Pinto, S.M. (2017). Regional Policy and Fiscal Competition. In: Jackson, R., Schaeffer, P. (eds) Regional Research Frontiers - Vol. 1. Advances in Spatial Science. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-50547-3_13

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics