Skip to main content

Entrepreneurship and Public Policy

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Handbook of Entrepreneurship Research

Part of the book series: International Handbook Series on Entrepreneurship ((IHSE,volume 5))

Abstract

Public policy is currently shifting from SME policy toward entrepreneurship policy, which supports entrepreneurship without directing attention to quantitative goals and specific firms or employment groups. The institutional framework set by public policy affects the prevalence and performance of both productive entrepreneurship and so-called high-impact entrepreneurship in turn. Although varying contexts and economic systems make prescribing a general panacea impossible, a number of relevant policy areas are identified and analyzed. Independent of environment, productive entrepreneurship should be rewarded and unproductive entrepreneurship should be discouraged. Successful ventures must also have the incentive to continue renewing themselves just as it must be easy to start and expand a business. In particular, we analyze regulatory entry and growth barriers, labor market regulation, liquidity constraints, and tax policy at length.

This is a draft chapter for the new edition of Handbook of Entrepreneurship Research (New York: Springer), edited by Zoltan J. Acs and David B. Audretsch. We are grateful for useful comments and suggestions from Robin Douhan and Linda Nyberg. Financial support from the Gustaf Douglas Research Program on Entrepreneurship at IFN and from the Jan Wallander and Tom Hedelius Research Foundation is gratefully acknowledged.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 259.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 329.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 329.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Audretsch et al. (2007).

  2. 2.

    See, e.g., Storey (2003) and Cumming and MacIntosh (2006).

  3. 3.

    Lundström and Stevenson (2005, 37).

  4. 4.

    See Henrekson and Johansson (2010) for a survey of the evidence.

  5. 5.

    Hoffmann (2007, 140). This does not preclude that an entrepreneurial venture is sold to an incumbent fairly quickly. The full potential of a business idea will more likely be realized if it is sold to an established business with the requisite know-how and financial strength (Norbäck & Persson 2009).

  6. 6.

    See Iversen et al. (2008) and Henrekson (2007) for a further discussion.

  7. 7.

    Reynolds et al. (2002). Sometimes the terms “pull” and “push” effects are used instead to distinguish whether individuals start ventures due to their lack of better alternatives or to exploit entrepreneurial opportunities.

  8. 8.

    See, e.g., Baumol et al. (2007).

  9. 9.

    This maximization behavior does not necessarily imply narrow selfishness. The entrepreneur could care about the welfare of kin and friends, or even about the welfare of the general public. It suffices that the business decisions are decoupled from such considerations. The entrepreneur maximizes profits selfishly, but no constraint is put on the use of these profits. These may or may not be spent with altruistic considerations in mind.

  10. 10.

    Baumol (1990) and Murphy et al. (1991).

  11. 11.

    See Acs (2008) for an in-depth discussion of HIE. Acs claims that HIE should be an activity focused on (homogeneous) mass production within the product market sector. However, we find it unnecessary to restrict the concept of HIE to specific business activities and/or strategies.

  12. 12.

    See Douhan et al. (2009).

  13. 13.

    Hart (2003).

  14. 14.

    Lundström and Stevenson (2002).

  15. 15.

    See, e.g., Storey (2003) or van Stel (2007). Audretsch et al. (2007) mention network, knowledge, and learning externalities as three examples of market failures that work against SMEs in the economy. Rodrik (2007) points to information and coordination externalities as one basis for government intervention.

  16. 16.

    Audretsch et al. (2002, 45).

  17. 17.

    Cf. Holtz-Eakin (2000), who claims that it is virtually impossible to clearly identify entrepreneurs.

  18. 18.

    Cf. Holtz-Eakin (2000).

  19. 19.

    EU (2007, 2008).

  20. 20.

    Acs and Szerb (2007, 112).

  21. 21.

    See, e.g., Shane (2008, 162), who states that: “[N]ew company formation per se isn’t what matters; rather it’s the creation of a small number of super-high-potential new companies, which among them generate almost all the economic growth and job and wealth creation that comes from having an entrepreneurial economy […] A strategy that revolves around increasing the number of new business created every year is flawed.”

  22. 22.

    Johansson (2010).

  23. 23.

    Lundström and Stevenson (2002).

  24. 24.

    Audretsch et al. (2002).

  25. 25.

    Orszag and Snower’s (1998) study of the complementarity of different policies in the area of unemployment provides an interesting parallel. They show how the effectiveness of one policy depends on the implementation of other policies.

  26. 26.

    OECD (2007).

  27. 27.

    Cf. Boetttke and Coyne (2009, 144).

  28. 28.

    Cf. Rodrik (2007), Boettke and Coyne (2009), and Lundström and Stevenson (2002).

  29. 29.

    Acs and Szerb (2007).

  30. 30.

    Acs and Szerb (2007) state that information, opportunity recognition, and skill development are the most important factors influencing entrepreneurial activity in the short run.

  31. 31.

    Bowles (1998), Baumol et al. (2007, 203ff), and Smith (2003).

  32. 32.

    Audretsch et al. (2002).

  33. 33.

    See Boettke and Coyne (2003, 2009) for a further discussion.

  34. 34.

    Storey (1994).

  35. 35.

    OECD (2007).

  36. 36.

    Kleiner (2006). For an early critique of occupational licensing, see Friedman (1962, Chapter 9).

  37. 37.

    The income elasticity of these services has been estimated to be as high as 1.6 (Fogel 1999).

  38. 38.

    Adema (2001), Adema and Ladaique (2005), and Andersen (2008).

  39. 39.

    See, e.g., Shleifer (1998).

  40. 40.

    See, e.g., Jensen and Stonecash (2005) for an overview of public sector outsourcing. Even if only part of public production is privatized, the non-privatized part may improve. Bergström and Sandström (2005) have found that school results in Swedish public schools improved due to competition from independent schools under a voucher system covering all children.

  41. 41.

    Baumol (1993) and Jansson (2006).

  42. 42.

    See, e.g., OECD (2007) and EU (2008) for a further discussion.

  43. 43.

    Ho and Wong (2007). In a highly influential paper, Djankov et al. (2002) discuss and analyze entry costs across 85 countries.

  44. 44.

    See, e.g., World Bank (2005a, 2005b). The methodology is based on Djankov et al. (2002), which is greatly inspired by de Soto (1989).

  45. 45.

    See, e.g., Desai et al. (2003) and Klapper et al. (2004).

  46. 46.

    Ho and Wong (2007).

  47. 47.

    Dean and Meyer (1996).

  48. 48.

    OECD (1998).

  49. 49.

    Nijsen (2000).

  50. 50.

    EU (2008). Crain and Hopkins (2001) found that the total cost of federal regulation in the United States is about 45% greater per employee in small firms (< 20) relative to large firms (> 500).

  51. 51.

    Audretsch et al. (2002).

  52. 52.

    Kauffman Foundation (2008).

  53. 53.

    van Stel et al. (2007, 173). Ho and Wong (2007) claim, however, that necessity entrepreneurship should not be hampered by regulatory costs, as they are driven by lack of alternative employment and not by exploiting new profitable opportunities.

  54. 54.

    Ho and Wong (2007).

  55. 55.

    Ho and Wong (2007).

  56. 56.

    de Soto (1989) and Henrekson and Sanandaji (2010).

  57. 57.

    Cf. Baumol (1990). Capelleras et al. (2008) find support for this idea. They show that there is lower business activity in Spain’s highly regulated formal sector than in the less-regulated UK. This difference disappears, however, if the informal sector is included in the analysis.

  58. 58.

    OECD (2005) and Haggarty et al. (2006).

  59. 59.

    Klinger and Lederman (2006).

  60. 60.

    Audretsch et al. (2002).

  61. 61.

    See, e.g., Audretsch et al. (2002).

  62. 62.

    See, e.g., Parker (2004, Section II) and van Auken (1999).

  63. 63.

    Hurst and Lusardi (2004) and Shane (2008, 79).

  64. 64.

    Baumol et al. (2007, 236).

  65. 65.

    Baumol et al. (2007, 205).

  66. 66.

    Fazzari et al. (1988).

  67. 67.

    EU (2008).

  68. 68.

    Kauffman Foundation (2007, 34).

  69. 69.

    See de Meza (2002) and de Meza and Southey (1996) for an in-depth discussion. de Meza actually claims that too many low-quality projects are being funded due to asymmetric information. The problem is then that too many projects are financed. In accordance, he argues that public policy should be used to reduce lending to entrepreneurs.

  70. 70.

    See, e.g., Hayward et al. (2006) who discuss the Hubris theory of entrepreneurship; many potential entrepreneurs have overconfidence in their knowledge, predictions, and personal ability.

  71. 71.

    See Shane (2008, Chapter 5) for an interesting discussion.

  72. 72.

    Hurst and Lusardi (2004). Nykvist (2008) examines this relationship using similar methods with Swedish data, but the result that wealth is not important for new entrepreneurs could not be replicated.

  73. 73.

    Kauernman et al. (2005) and Bamford et al. (2004).

  74. 74.

    Pelikan (1988) provides forceful arguments supporting this view. Data from the United States show that businesses below 2 years of age are equity financed to 48%, in which the bulk comes from internal sources. Consequently, debt financing constituted 52%, but only 28% of the debt consisted of funding from financial institutions (Berger and Udell 1988).

  75. 75.

    See Parker (2004) and Nykvist (2008).

  76. 76.

    Ho and Wong (2007).

  77. 77.

    An example is the Enterprise Initiative Scheme, introduced in 1994, which under certain conditions gives business angel investors tax relief from capital gains and the possibility to write off the amount invested (up to a cap) against income tax. See, e.g., Boyns et al. (2003) and Mason (2006).

  78. 78.

    See, e.g., Reynolds et al. (2002) and Bygrave and Hunt (2004).

  79. 79.

    OECD (1998).

  80. 80.

    Ho and Wong (2007) and Keuschnigg and Nielsen (2004a).

  81. 81.

    See, e.g., Bottazzi and Da Rin (2002) and Da Rin et al. (2006)

  82. 82.

    OECD (1998).

  83. 83.

    Scarpetta et al. (2002).

  84. 84.

    Borger et al. (2000).

  85. 85.

    See, e.g., Gompers and Lerner (2004) or Gompers et al. (2009). Cf. Birch (2006), who claims that it is impossible to “pick winners.” Svensson (2008) has also shown that soft public financing in the early stage (seed) phase often leads to inferior firm performance and that public loans always should be granted on commercial terms. See also Bergström (2000).

  86. 86.

    However, openly and politically influenced decisions are at times deliberate support of, e.g., impoverished regions. Supporting specific minority groups, like immigrants or women, may also be a way to compensate for possible (credit market) discrimination in the economy.

  87. 87.

    Baumol et al. (2007, 220).

  88. 88.

    Cf. Shane (2008) who claims that politicians should think like venture capitalists and copy their strategies instead of supporting the “typical” venture with a supposedly low impact on the economy. Politicians cannot “pick winners” but they can try to avoid “picking losers”. Baumol et al. (2007) asserts that the Advanced Technology Program (ATP), administered by the Commerce Department in the US, only supported ventures which also attracted private money and there is some support that this has been successful. The largest program in the United States is the Small Business Innovation Research (SBIR) program. Program evaluation can be very complex, but Siegel et al. (2003) concludes that both ATP and SBIR have been successful.

  89. 89.

    Gompers and Lerner (1999) find that a crucial factor behind the growth of the United States venture capital industry was that the decrease of capital gains tax rates boosted demand for venture capital as more workers got an incentive to become entrepreneurs. Keuschnigg and Nielsen (2004b) have shown theoretically that inefficiently low entrepreneurial effort and venture capital support may arise in the economy and that capital gains taxation may be particularly harmful. See also Keuschnigg and Nielsen (2004a) for an additional discussion.

  90. 90.

    Henrekson and Rosenberg (2001).

  91. 91.

    Da Rin et al. (2006). They conclude: ”[T]he European experience suggests that the creation of active venture capital markets might depend on providing investors and entrepreneurs with the possibility to reap the benefits of their efforts rather than providing them with more funds.”

  92. 92.

    Drucker (1976).

  93. 93.

    Hart (2003, 10).

  94. 94.

    Audretsch et al. (2002, 47).

  95. 95.

    van Stel et al. (2007).

  96. 96.

    OECD (1994).

  97. 97.

    OECD provided an update of the 1994 study in 2009. See Shedinger (2010) for details.

  98. 98.

    van Stel et al. (2007).

  99. 99.

    OECD (1998, 2000).

  100. 100.

    Niehof (1999).

  101. 101.

    OECD (2003).

  102. 102.

    Baumol et al. (2007, 210, 222).

  103. 103.

    See Caballero (2007).

  104. 104.

    Ho and Wong (2007).

  105. 105.

    Lazerson and Lorenzoni (1999) and Pyke et al. (1990).

  106. 106.

    See, e.g., Ilmakunnas and Kanniainen (2001) for an econometric analysis of the effects of risk insurance in the welfare state.

  107. 107.

    See, e.g., Audretsch et al. (2002).

  108. 108.

    Nickell (1997) and Koellinger and Minniti (2009).

  109. 109.

    Delmar et al. (2005).

  110. 110.

    See, e.g., Acs et al. (2009).

  111. 111.

    Baumol (2002).

  112. 112.

    See, e.g., Acs (2008).

  113. 113.

    See, e.g., EU (2002).

  114. 114.

    Bhidé (2008).

  115. 115.

    The amount of R&D may not only be large but also exploited inefficiently. Da Rin et al. (2006) examined 14 European countries in a panel between 1988 and 2001 and did not find any positive relationship between public R&D spending and the rate of innovation, defined as the share of high-tech and early stage venture capital investments.

  116. 116.

    To make the point crystal clear: it was neither Bill Gates nor Henry Ford who invented the technologies they used in their ventures. They were entrepreneurs who successfully exploited new or existing technologies. These entrepreneurs were needed to successfully exploit the inventions. Only focusing on inventions and R&D misses at least half of the story. Increased R&D will not automatically bring forth entrepreneurs undertaking entrepreneurial activity based on new R&D. Perhaps it is even the other way around, i.e., in an economic system encouraging productive entrepreneurship a great deal of R&D is undertaken because the results from R&D are demanded (Holcombe, 2007).

  117. 117.

    See, e.g., Acs (2008) and Acs et al. (2009) for a further discussion.

  118. 118.

    Audretsch et al. (2002).

  119. 119.

    Lindelöf and Löfsten (2003).

  120. 120.

    Carlsson (2009).

  121. 121.

    Kauffman Foundation (2007).

  122. 122.

    Kauffman Foundation (2008) and Baumol et al. (2007). See also Henrekson and Rosenberg (2001). There are innumerable examples of programs supporting science parks, clusters, and spin-offs, especially within the academic sector. Even if many studies find a positive effect from these programs, fair evaluations are difficult due to endogeneity problems and a lack of a counterfactual benchmark (how institutional arrangements would have spontaneously evolved had there been no public support). There are, however, also examples of failed policy programs such as the UK support program for young people (Meager et al., 2003). See OECD (2007) for a further discussion of evaluations of entrepreneurship policies and programs.

  123. 123.

    Holtz-Eakin (2000, 288).

  124. 124.

    Audretsch et al. (2002, 55). Research based on UK data also shows that targeted regional start-up subsidies to under-performing regions tends to encourage individuals with limited human capital to start firms. This group seldom develops high-impact firms and often leaves the market after some time. See van Stel and Storey (2004).

  125. 125.

    Baumol et al. (2007, 234).

  126. 126.

    Cf. Ho and Wong (2007).

  127. 127.

    See, e.g., Libecap (1993), Baumol (2002), Rodrik et al. (2004), and Acemoglu and Johnson (2005).

  128. 128.

    Rodrik (2007) and North and Weingast (1989).

  129. 129.

    de Soto (2000).

  130. 130.

    Rodrik (2007, 156). Rodrik stresses the importance of control. Formal property rights which in practice do not render control rights are useless. In the same way, even if formal property rights are absent, sufficiently strong control rights may be enough to provide sufficient incentives for potential entrepreneurs.

  131. 131.

    See Johnson et al. (2002) who investigates new firms in the post-communist countries.

  132. 132.

    Bandiera (2003), and Milhaupt and West (2000). See Douhan and Henrekson (2010) for a further discussion.

  133. 133.

    These effects can, e.g., be compared to Slemrod (1986) who only distinguishes between two effects to tax changes: real responses and avoidance responses.

  134. 134.

    See, e.g., the discussion in OECD (1998).

  135. 135.

    See, e.g., Long (1982), Watson (1985), Kesselman (1989), Pestieau and Possen (1991) for a discussion of tax evasion and choice of occupation. Robson and Wren (1999) conclude that it is mainly the average tax rate that affects evasion behavior.

  136. 136.

    Engström and Holmlund (2009).

  137. 137.

    Henrekson and Johansson (2009).

  138. 138.

    This argument was first put forward by Domar and Musgrave (1944).

  139. 139.

    A recent discussion of this effect is Cullen and Gordon (2007). It is noteworthy that in practice no tax system has full loss offset.

  140. 140.

    Gentry and Hubbard (2000).

  141. 141.

    Audrestch et al. (2002, 46).

  142. 142.

    Audrestch et al. (2002, 46).

  143. 143.

    For a general overview of the research until 2003, see Schuetze and Bruce (2004).

  144. 144.

    See, e.g., Robson and Wren (1999).

  145. 145.

    Gentry and Hubbard (2000).

  146. 146.

    Kauffman Foundation (2007) and Cullen and Gordon (2007).

  147. 147.

    This is true for Sweden, where the so-called 3:12 rules restrict how much of profits from closely held firms that can be taxed as dividends and not as earned income by the owners. See Agell et al. (1998) and Davis and Henrekson (2010).

  148. 148.

    Henrekson and Johansson (2009).

  149. 149.

    Henrekson (2007).

  150. 150.

    Michaelas et al. (1999).

  151. 151.

    Cf. Audretsch et al. (2002, 46).

  152. 152.

    Henrekson and Johansson (2009). High corporate and capital gains taxation may also discourage the venture capital industry (Da Rin et al., 2006). See, however, Holtz-Eakin (2000, 288) for a critical discussion and calculation of the importance of capital gains taxation.

  153. 153.

    See Rosen (2005) for an overview.

  154. 154.

    Misher (1984) and Gompers and Lerner (2001).

  155. 155.

    These kinds of highly complicated estimates have been made for a number of countries using the methodology developed by King and Fullerton (1984).

  156. 156.

    Jorgenson and Landau (1993).

  157. 157.

    Rydqvist et al. (2009).

  158. 158.

    Henrekson and Johansson (2009).

  159. 159.

    Cf. Acs and Szerb (2007).

  160. 160.

    Audretsch et al. (2002) and OECD (1998).

  161. 161.

    Gilbert et al. (2004) and Holbrook et al. (2000). Armour and Cummings (2005) show that the harshness of the bankruptcy law has a statistically and economically significant negative effect on self-employment levels.

  162. 162.

    Audretsch et al. (2002) and OECD (1998).

  163. 163.

    EU (2008) and OECD (1998). A survey has, e.g., shown that 47% of the Europeans would be reluctant to order from a business owned by somebody who has previously filed for bankruptcy. This will hardly facilitate entrepreneurial activities for re-starters. The average time to complete a bankruptcy varies also considerable within EU, from 4 months to 9 years (EU, 2008).

  164. 164.

    Audretsch et al. (2002).

  165. 165.

    See Ucbasaran et al. (2008) for an overview of habitual entrepreneurs.

  166. 166.

    See Baumol et al. (2007) for a further and more detailed discussion.

  167. 167.

    Gilbert et al. (2004).

  168. 168.

    Baumol et al. (2007), Kauffman Foundation (2007), and Acs and Szerb (2007). See Merrill et al. (2004) for an in-depth discussion.

  169. 169.

    Jaffee and Lerner (2004). In the United States, the United States Patent and Trademark Office (USPTO) is overburdened as it is too easy to get a patent; the special court in the United States that deals with these issues (CAFC) has over time given greater protection to patent claimants (Kauffman Foundation 2007, 24).

  170. 170.

    Cf. Baumol et al. (1982).

References

  • Acemoglu, D., & Johnson, S. 2005. Unbundling institutions. Journal of Political Economy, 113(5): 947–997.

    Google Scholar 

  • Acs, Z. J. 2008. Foundations of high impact entrepreneurship. Foundations and Trends in Entrepreneurship, 4(6): 535–620.

    Google Scholar 

  • Acs, Z. J., Braunerhjelm, P., & Audretsch, D. B. 2009. The knowledge spillover theory of entrepreneurship. Small Business Economics, 32(1): 15–30.

    Google Scholar 

  • Acs, Z. J., & Szerb, L. 2007. Entrepreneurship, economic growth and public policy. Small Business Economics, 28(2–3): 109–122.

    Google Scholar 

  • Adema, W. 2001. Net social expenditure: 2nd edition. OECD Labor Market and Social Policy Occasional Papers No. 52. Paris: OECD.

    Google Scholar 

  • Adema, W., & Ladaique, M. 2005. Net social expenditure, 2005 edition: More comprehensive measures of social support. OECD Social, Employment and Migration Working Papers No. 29. Paris: OECD.

    Google Scholar 

  • Agell, J., Englund, P., & Södersten, J. 1998. Incentives and Redistribution in the Welfare State – The Swedish Tax Reform. London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Andersen, T. M. 2008. The Scandinavian model – prospects and challenges. International Tax and Public Finance, 15(1): 45–66.

    Google Scholar 

  • Armour, J., & Cumming, D. J. 2005. Bankruptcy law and entrepreneurship. American Law & Economic Review, 10(2): 303–350.

    Google Scholar 

  • Audretsch, D. B., Grilo, I., & Thurik, A. R. 2007. Explaining entrepreneurship and the role of policy: A framework. In D. Audretsch, I. Grilo, & A. R. Thurik (Eds.), Handbook of Entrepreneurship Policy. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Audrestch, D. B., Thurik, A. R., Verheul, I., & Wennekers, S. (Eds.). 2002. Entrepreneurship: Determinants and Policy in a European–US Comparison. Boston, Dodrecht and London: Kluwer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bamford, C. E., Dean, T. J., & Douglas, T. J. 2004. The temporal nature of growth determinants in new bank founding: Implications for new venture research design. Journal of Business Venturing, 19(6): 223–242.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bandiera, O. 2003. Land reform, the market for protection, and the origins of the Sicilian Mafia: Theory and evidence. Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 19(1): 218–244.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baumol, W. J. 1990. Entrepreneurship: Productive, unproductive, destructive. Journal of Political Economy, 98(5): 893–921.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baumol, W. J. 1993. Health care, education and the cost disease: A looming crisis for public choice. Public Choice, 77(1): 17–28.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baumol, W. J. 2002. The Free-Market Innovation Machine. Princeton, NJ and Oxford: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baumol, W. J., Litan, R. E., & Schramm, C. J. 2007. Good Capitalism, Bad Capitalism and the Economics of Growth and Prosperity. New Haven, CT and London: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baumol, W. J., Panzar, J. C., & Willig, R. D. 1982. Contestable Markets and the Theory of Industry Structure. New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich.

    Google Scholar 

  • Berger, A. N., & Udell, G. F. 1988. The economics of small business finance: The roles of private equity and debt markets in the financial growth cycle. Journal of Banking and Finance, 22(6–8): 613–673.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bergström, F. 2000. Capital subsidies and the performance of firms. Small Business Economics, 13(3): 183–193.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bergström, F., & Sandström, M. 2005. School vouchers in practice: Competition will not hurt you. Journal of Public Economics, 89(2–3): 351–380.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bhidé, A. 2008. The Venturesome Economy. Princeton, NJ and Oxford: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Birch, D. L. 1979. The Job Generation Process. Cambridge, MA: MIT Program on Neighborhood and Regional Change.

    Google Scholar 

  • Birch, D. L. 2006. What have we learned? Foundations and Trends in Entrepreneurship, 2(3): 197–202.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boettke, P. J., & Coyne, C. J. 2003. Entrepreneurship and development: Cause or consequence? Advances in Austrian Economics, 6: 67–88.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boettke, P. J., & Coyne, C. J. 2009. Context matters: Institutions and entrepreneurship. Foundations and Trends in Entrepreneurship, 5(3): 135–209.

    Google Scholar 

  • Borger, J. C., Janssen, N. L. C. M., & van Noort, E. A. 2000. The Venture Capital Market for SMEs. An International Perspective. Zoetermeer: EIM Business and Policy Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bottazzi, L., & Da Rin, M. 2002. Venture capital in Europe and the financing of innovative companies. Economic Policy, 17(34): 229–270.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bowles, S. 1998. Endogenous preferences: The cultural consequences of markets and other economic institutions. Journal of Economic Literature, 36(1): 75–111.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boyns, N., Cox, M., Spires, R., & Hughes, A. 2003. Research into the Enterprise Investment Scheme and Venture Capital Trusts. PACEC Report for Inland Revenue.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bygrave, W. D., & Hunt, S. A. 2004. Global Entrepreneurship Monitor (GEM) 2004 Financing Report. Wellesley and London: Babson College and London Business School.

    Google Scholar 

  • Caballero, R. 2007. Specificity and the Macroeconomics of Restructuring. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Capelleras, J.-L., Mole, K. F., Greene, F. J., & Storey, D. J. 2008. Do more heavily regulated economies have poorer performing new ventures: Evidence from Britain and Spain? Journal of International Business Studies, 39(4): 688–704.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carlsson, B. 2009. Entrepreneurship and public policy in emerging clusters. SNEE Working Paper, May 2009.

    Google Scholar 

  • Crain, W. M., & Hopkins, T. D. 2001. The impact of regulatory costs on small firms. Report prepared for the Office of Advocacy, US Small Business Administration.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cullen, J. B., & Gordon, R. H. 2007. Taxes and entrepreneurial risk-taking: Theory and evidence for the U.S. Journal of Public Economics, 91(7–8): 1479–1505.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cumming, D. J., & Macintosh, J. G. 2006. Crowding out private equity: Canadian evidence. Journal of Business Venturing, 21(5): 569–609.

    Google Scholar 

  • Da Rin, M., Nicodano, G., & Sembenelli, A. 2006. Public policy and the creation of active venture capital markets. Journal of Public Economics, 90(8–9): 1699–1723.

    Google Scholar 

  • Davis, S. J., & Henrekson, M. 2010. Economic performance and work activity in Sweden after the crisis of the early 1990s. In R. M. Freeman, B. Swedenborg, & R. Topel (Eds.), Reforming the Welfare State – Recovery and Beyond in Sweden. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • de Meza, D. 2002. Overlending? Economic Journal, 112(477): F17–F31.

    Google Scholar 

  • de Meza, D., & Southey, C. 1996. The borrower’s curse. Optimism, finance and entrepreneurship. Economic Journal, 106(435): 375–386.

    Google Scholar 

  • de Soto, H. 1989. The Other Path. New York: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • de Soto, H. 2000. The Mystery of Capital: Why Capitalism Triumphs in the West and Fails Everywhere else. New York: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dean, T. J., & Meyer, G. D. 1996. Industry environments and new venture formations in U.S. manufacturing: A conceptual and empirical analysis of demand determinants. Journal of Business Venturing, 11(2): 107–132.

    Google Scholar 

  • Delmar, F., Wennberg, K., Wiklund, J., & Sjöberg, K. 2005. Self-employment among the Swedish science and technology labor force: The evolution of firms between 1990 and 2000. Report A2005:001. Östersund: Swedish Institute for Growth Policy Studies.

    Google Scholar 

  • Desai, M., Gompers, P. A., & Lerner, J. 2003. Institutions, capital constraints and entrepreneurial firm dynamics: Evidence from Europe. NBER Working Paper No. 10165.

    Google Scholar 

  • Djankov, S., La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., & Shleifer, A. 2002. The regulation of entry. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(1): 1–37.

    Google Scholar 

  • Domar, E., & Musgrave, R. A. 1944. Proportional income taxation and risk sharing. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 58(3): 388–422.

    Google Scholar 

  • Douhan, R., & Henrekson, M. 2010. Entrepreneurship and second-best institutions: Going beyond Baumol’s typology. Journal of Evolutionary Economics (in press).

    Google Scholar 

  • Douhan, R., Norbäck, P.-J., & Persson, L. 2009. Entrepreneurial innovations, Entrepreneurship policy and globalization. IFN Working Paper No. 807. Stockholm: Research Institute of Industrial Economics.

    Google Scholar 

  • Drucker, P. F. 1976. The Unseen Revolution: How Pension Fund Socialism Came to America. London: Heinemann.

    Google Scholar 

  • Engström, P., & Holmlund, B. 2009. Tax evasion and self-employment in a high-tax country: Evidence from Sweden. Applied Economics, 41(19): 2419–2430.

    Google Scholar 

  • EU. 2002. More research for Europe: Towards 3% of GDP. COMM 2002(499). Brussels: European Commission.

    Google Scholar 

  • EU. 2007. Models to reduce the disproportionate regulatory burden on SMEs. Enterprise and industry directorate-general. Report of the expert group. Brussels: European Commission.

    Google Scholar 

  • EU. 2008. Think small first. A small business act for Europe. DG Enterprise. Brussels: European Commission.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fazzari, S. M., Hubbard, R. G., & Petersen, B. C. 1988. Financing constraints and corporate investment. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1: 141–195.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fogel, R. W. 1999. Catching up with the economy. American Economic Review, 89(1): 1–21.

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, M. 1962. Capitalism and Freedom. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gentry, W. M., & Hubbard, R. G. 2000. Tax policy and entrepreneurial entry. American Economic Review, 90(2): 283–287.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gilbert, B. A., Audretsch, D. B., & McDougall, P. P. 2004. The emergence of entrepreneurship policy. Small Business Economics, 22(3–4): 313–323.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gompers, P. A., & Lerner, J. 1999. What drives venture capital funding? NBER Working Paper No. 6906.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gompers, P. A., & Lerner, J. 2001. The Money of Invention: How Venture Capital Creates New Wealth. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gompers, P. A., & Lerner, J. 2004. The Venture Capital Cycle (2nd ed.). Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gompers, P. A., Lerner, J., & Kovner, A. R. 2009. Specialization and success: Evidence from venture capital. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 18(3): 817–844.

    Google Scholar 

  • Haggarty, L., Rada, K., & Dohm, E. 2006. Cutting red tape simplifying regulation at the municipal level in Latin America: Lessons from IFC’s experience in Peru and Nicaragua. International Finance Corporation.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hart, D. M. 2003. Entrepreneurship policy: What it is and where it came from. In D. M. Hart (Ed.), The Emergence of Entrepreneurship Policy: Governance, Start-Ups, and Growth in the U.S. Knowledge Economy. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayward, M. L. A., Shepherd, D. A., & Griffin, D. 2006. A hubris theory of entrepreneurship. Management Science, 52(2): 160–172.

    Google Scholar 

  • Henrekson, M. 2007. Entrepreneurship and institutions. Comparative Labor Law & Policy Journal, 28(3): 717–742.

    Google Scholar 

  • Henrekson, M., & Johansson, D. 2009. Competencies and institutions fostering high-growth firms. Foundations and Trends in Entrepreneurship, 5(1): 1–82.

    Google Scholar 

  • Henrekson, M., & Johansson, D. 2010. Gazelles as job creators – A survey and interpretation of the evidence. Small Business Economics (in press).

    Google Scholar 

  • Henrekson, M., & Rosenberg, N. 2001. Designing efficient institutions for science-based entrepreneurship: Lessons from the US and Sweden. Journal of Technology Transfer, 26(3): 207–231.

    Google Scholar 

  • Henrekson, M., & Sanandaji, T. 2010. The Interaction between Entrepreneurship and Institutions. IFN Working Paper No. 830 Stockholm.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ho, Y.-P., & Wong, P.-K. 2007. Financing, regulatory costs and entrepreneurial propensity. Small Business Economics, 28(2–3): 187–204.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hoffman, A. N. 2007. A rough guide to entrepreneurship policy. In D. B. Audretsch, I. Grilo, & A. R. Thurik (Eds.), Handbook of Entrepreneurship Policy. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holbrook, D., Cohen, W. M., Hounshell, D. A., & Klepper, S. 2000. The nature, sources, and consequences of firm differences in the early history of the semiconductor industry. Strategic Management Journal, 21(10–11): 1017–1041.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holcombe, R. G. 2007. Entrepreneurship and Economic Progress. New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holtz-Eakin, D. 2000. Public policy toward entrepreneurship. Small Business Economics, 15(4): 283–291.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hurst, E., & Lusardi, A. 2004. Liquidity constraints, household wealth, and entrepreneurship. Journal of Political Economy, 112(2): 319–347.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ilmakunnas, P., & Kanniainen, V. 2001. Entrepreneurship, economic risks and risk insurance in the welfare state: Results with OECD data 1978–93. German Economic Review, 2(3): 195–218.

    Google Scholar 

  • Iversen, J., Jørgensen, R., & Malcow-Møller, N. 2008. Defining and measuring entrepreneurship. Foundations and Trends in Entrepreneurship, 4(1): 1–63.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jaffee, A. B., & Lerner, J. 2004. Innovation and Its Discontents: How Our Broken Patent System Is Endangering Innovation and Progress, and What to Do about It? Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jansson, J. O. 2006. The Economics of Services: Development and Policy. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jensen, P. H., & Stonecash, R. E. 2005. Incentives and the efficiency of public sector-outsourcing contracts. Journal of Economic Surveys, 19(5): 767–787.

    Google Scholar 

  • Johansson, D. 2010. The theory of the experimentally organized economy and competence blocs: An introduction. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 20(2): 185–201.

    Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, S., McMillan, J., & Woodruff, C. 2002. Property rights and finance. American Economic Review, 92(5): 1335–1356.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jorgenson, D. W., & Landau, R. (Eds.). 1993. Tax Reform and the Cost of Capital: An International Comparison. Washington, DC: The Brookings Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kauermann, G., Tutz, G., & Brüdel, J. 2005. The survival of newly founded firms: A case-study into varying-coefficient models. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society Series A – Statistics in Society, 168(1): 145–158.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kauffman Foundation. 2007. On the road to an entrepreneurial economy: A research and policy guide. Ewing Marion Kauffman foundation Working Paper, July 2007.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kauffman Foundation. 2008. Entrepreneurship summit. Executive summary. Ewing Marion Kauffman Foundation and the International Economic Development Council Working Paper, September 2008.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kesselman, J. R. 1989. Income tax evasion: An intersectoral analysis. Journal of Public Economics, 38(2): 137–182.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keuschnigg, C., & Nielsen, S. 2004a. Taxation and venture capital backed entrepreneurship. International Tax and Public Finance, 11(4): 369–390.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keuschnigg, C., & Nielsen, S. 2004b. Start-ups, venture capitalists, and the capital gains tax. Journal of Public Economics, 88(5): 1011–1042.

    Google Scholar 

  • King, M. A., & Fullerton, D. (Eds.). 1984. The Taxation of Income from Capital: A Comparative Study of the United States, the United Kingdom, Sweden and West Germany. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Klapper, L. F., Laeven, L. A., & Rajan, R. G. 2004. Business environment and firm entry: Evidence from international data. NBER Working Paper No. 10380.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kleiner, M. M. 2006. Licensing Occupations: Ensuring Quality or Restricting Competition? Kalamazoo, MI: W.E. Upjohn Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Klinger, B., & Lederman, D. 2006. Diversification, innovation and imitation inside the global technological frontier. World Bank Policy Research Department Working Paper No. 3872.

    Google Scholar 

  • Koellinger, P., & Minniti, M. 2009. Unemployment benefits crowd out entrepreneurial activity. Economics Letters, 103(2): 96–98.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lazerson, M. H., & Lorenzoni, G. 1999. The firms that feed industrial districts: A return to the Italian source. Industrial and Corporate Change, 8(2): 235–266.

    Google Scholar 

  • Libecap, G. 1993. Entrepreneurship, property rights and economic growth. Advances in the Study of Entrepreneurship, Innovation and Economic Growth: A Research Annual, Vol. 6. Greenwich, CT: JAI Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lindelöf, P., & Löfsten, H. 2003. Science park location and new technology based firms in Sweden – Implications for strategy and performance. Small Business Economics, 20(3): 245–258.

    Google Scholar 

  • Long, J. E. 1982. The income tax and self-employment. National Tax Journal, 35(1): 31–42.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lundström, A., & Stevenson, L. 2002. On the Road to Entrepreneurship Policy. Volume 1 of the Entrepreneurship Policy for the Future Series. Örebro: FSF.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lundström, A., & Stevenson, L. 2005. Entrepreneurship Policy: Theory and Practices. ISEN International Studies in Entrepreneurship. New York: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mason, C. M. 2006. Informal sources of venture finance. In S. C. Parker (Ed.), The Life Cycle of Entrepreneurial Ventures, Vol. 3. International Handbook on Entrepreneurship. New York: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meager, N., Bates, P., & Cowling, M. 2003. An evaluation of business start-up support for young people. National Institute Economic Review, 186(1): 59–72.

    Google Scholar 

  • Merrill, S. A., Levin, R. C., & Myers, M. B. 2004. A Patent System for the 21st Century. Washington, DC: National Academic Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Michaelas, N., Chittenden, F., & Poutziouris, P. 1999. Financial policy and capital structure choice in UK SMEs: Empirical evidence from company panel data. Small Business Economics, 12(2): 113–130.

    Google Scholar 

  • Milhaupt, C. J., & Mark, D. W. 2000. The dark side of private ordering: An institutional and empirical analysis of organized crime. University of Chicago Law Review, 67(1): 41–98.

    Google Scholar 

  • Misher, N. 1984. Tax consequences of exercising an incentive stock option with stock of the granting corporation. The Tax Executive, July, 357–363.

    Google Scholar 

  • Moore, K. B. 2004. The effects of the 1986 and 1993 tax reforms on self-employment. FEDS Working Paper No. 2004–05.

    Google Scholar 

  • Murphy, K. M., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. 1991. The allocation of talent: Implications for growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106(2): 503–530.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nickell, S. 1997. Unemployment and labor market rigidities: Europe versus north America. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 11(3): 55–74.

    Google Scholar 

  • Niehof, J. 1999. Barriers for hiring personnel. Research Report 9807/E. Zoetermeer: EIM Business and Policy Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nijsen, A. F. M. 2000. Phases in the recognition of information transfer compliance costs. In E. Brauchlin, & J. H. Pichler (Eds.), Unternehmer und Unternehmensperspektiven für Klein- und Mittelunternehmen. Berlin and S:t Gallen: Duncker and Humblot.

    Google Scholar 

  • Norbäck, P.-J., & Persson, L. 2009. The organization of the innovation industry: Entrepreneurs, venture capitalists, and oligopolists. Journal of the European Economic Association, 7(6): 1261–1290.

    Google Scholar 

  • North, D. C., & Weingast, B. R. 1989. Constitutions and commitment: Evolution of institutions governing public choice in seventeenth century England. Journal of Economic History, 49(4): 803–832.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nykvist, J. 2008. Entrepreneurship and liquidity constraints: Evidence from Sweden. Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 110(1): 23–43.

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD. 1994. Employment protection regulation and labor market performance. OECD Employment Outlook. Paris: OECD.

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD. 1998. Fostering Entrepreneurship, the OECD Jobs Strategy. Paris: OECD.

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD. 2000. OECD Employment Outlook. Paris: OECD.

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD. 2003. The Sources of Economic Growth in the OECD Countries. Paris: OECD.

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD. 2005. Small and Medium Enterprise and Entrepreneurship Outlook. Paris: OECD.

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD. 2007. OECD Framework for the Evaluation of SME and Entrepreneurship Policies and Programmes. Paris: OECD.

    Google Scholar 

  • Orszag, M., & Snower, D. J. 1998. Anatomy of Policy Complimentarities. Swedish Economic Policy Review, 5(2): 303–343.

    Google Scholar 

  • Parker, S. C. 1996. A time-series model of self-employment under uncertainty. Economica, 63(251): 459–475.

    Google Scholar 

  • Parker, S. C. 2004. The Economics of Self-Employment and Entrepreneurship. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pelikan, P. 1988. Can the imperfect innovation systems of capitalism be outperformed? In G. Dosi et al. (Eds.), Technical Change and Economic Theory. London: Pinter.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pestieau, P., & Possen, U. M. 1991. Tax evasion and occupational choice. Journal of Public Economics, 45(1): 107–125.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pyke, F., Becattini, G., & Sengenberger, W. (Eds.). 1990. Industrial Districts and Inter-firm Cooperation in Italy. Geneva: IILS.

    Google Scholar 

  • Reynolds, P. D., Bygrave, W. D., Autio, E., & Hay, M. 2002. Global Entrepreneurship Monitor Executive Report 2002. Wellesley and London: Babson College and London Business School.

    Google Scholar 

  • Robson, M. T., & Wren, C. 1999. Marginal and average tax rates and the incentive for self-employment. Southern Economic Journal, 65(4): 757–773.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rodrik, D. 2007. One Economics, Many Recipes: Globalization, Institutions, and Economic Growth. Princeton, NJ and Oxford: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rodrik, D., Subramanian, A., & Trebbi, F. 2004. Institutions rule: The primacy of institutions over geography and integration in economic development. Journal of Economic Growth, 9(2): 131–165.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosen, H. S. 2005. Entrepreneurship and taxation: Empirical evidence. In V. Kanniainen, & C. Keuschnigg (Eds.), Venture Capital, Entrepreneurship and Public Policy. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rydqvist, K., Spizman, J., & Strebulaev, I. 2009. The evolution of aggregate stock ownership: A unified explanation. ECGI Finance Working Paper No. 263/2009.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scarpetta, S., Hemmings, P., Thierry, T., & Jaujoon, W. 2002. The role of policy and institutions for productivity and firm dynamics: Evidence from the micro and industry data. OECD Economic Department Working Paper No. 329.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schuetze, H. J. 2000. Taxes, economic conditions and recent trends in male self-employment: Canada-U.S. comparison. Labour Economics, 7(5): 507–544.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schuetze, H. J., & Bruce, D. 2004. Tax policy and entrepreneurship. Swedish Economic Policy Review, 11(2): 233–265.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shane, S. A. 2008. The Illusions of Entrepreneurship. New Haven, CT and London: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shleifer, A. 1998. State versus private ownership. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 12(4): 133–150.

    Google Scholar 

  • Siegel, D. S., Wessner, C., Binks, M., & Lockett, A. 2003. Policies promoting innovation in small firms: Evidence from the U.S. and U.K. Small Business Economics, 20(2): 121–127.

    Google Scholar 

  • Slemrod, J. 1986. Income creation or income shifting? Behavioral responses to the tax reform act of 1986. American Economic Review, 85(2): 175–180.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, V. 2003. Constructivist and ecological rationality in economics. American Economic Review, 93(3): 465–490.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shedinger, P. 2010. Employment Protection Legislation: Evolution, Effects, Winners and Losers. Cheltenham, UK and Northampton MA: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stenkula, M. 2009. Taxation and entrepreneurship in a welfare state. IFN Working Paper No. 800.

    Google Scholar 

  • Storey, D. J. 1994. Understanding the Small Business Sector. London and New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Storey, D. J. 2003. Entrepreneurship, small and medium sized enterprises and public policies. In Z. J. Acs, & D. B. Audretsch (Eds.), Handbook of Entrepreneurship Research. Boston, Dordrecht and London: Kluwer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Svensson, R. 2008. Innovation performance and government financing. Journal of Small Business and Entrepreneurship, 21(1): 95–116.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ucbasaran, D., Alsos, A. G., Westhead, P., & Wright, M. 2008. Habitual entrepreneurs. Foundations and Trends in Entrepreneurship, 4(4): 309–450.

    Google Scholar 

  • van Auken, H. E. 1999. Obstacles to business launch. Journal of Developmental Entrepreneurship, 4(2): 175–187.

    Google Scholar 

  • van Stel, A., Storey, D. J., & Thurik, A. R. 2007. The effect of business regulations on nascent and young business entrepreneurship. Small Business Economics, 28(2–3): 171–186.

    Google Scholar 

  • van Stel, A., & Storey, D. J. 2004. The link between firm births and job creation: Is there a upas tree effect? Regional Studies, 38(8): 893–909.

    Google Scholar 

  • Watson, H. 1985. Tax evasion and labor markets. Journal of Public Economics, 27(2): 231–246.

    Google Scholar 

  • World Bank. 2005a. Doing Business 2005: Poor Nations Struggle to Reduce Red Tape for Business, Miss Large Growth Opportunities. Washington, DC: World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • World Bank. 2005b. World Development Report 2005: A Better Investment Climate for Everyone. Washington, DC: World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Magnus Henrekson .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2010 Springer Science+Business Media, LLC

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Henrekson, M., Stenkula, M. (2010). Entrepreneurship and Public Policy. In: Acs, Z., Audretsch, D. (eds) Handbook of Entrepreneurship Research. International Handbook Series on Entrepreneurship, vol 5. Springer, New York, NY. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4419-1191-9_21

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics