Skip to main content
Log in

On the empirical relevance of Condorcet’s paradox

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Condorcet’s paradox occurs when there is no alternative that beats every other alternative by majority. The paradox may pose real problems to democratic decision making such as decision deadlocks and democratic paralysis. However, its relevance has been discussed again and again since the celebrated works of Arrow (Social choice and individual values, 1963) and Black (The theory of committees and elections, 1958). The discussion varies from one extreme to the other: from very relevant to practically irrelevant. This paper tries to bring more clarity to the discussion by reviewing the literature on the empirical relevance of Condorcet’s paradox. Since a definition of the paradox for even numbers of voters and alternatives, and for weak voter preferences is missing in the literature, we first define the paradox clearly and simply. Then, three topics are investigated, namely domain conditions, culture and the likelihood of the paradox, and the empirical detection of the paradox. Domain conditions express regularities in voter-preference profiles that prevent the paradox. Frequent observations of these domain conditions would make Condorcet’s paradox empirically less important. Cultures define probability distributions over the set of voter preferences. Observation of cultures might be a first step to indicate the relevance of the paradox. The empirical detection of the paradox speaks for itself; we will try to identify the number of observations of the paradox so far. The overall conclusion is that the empirical relevance of Condorcet’s paradox is still unsettled.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Abramson, P., Aldrich, J., Paolini, P., & Rohde, D. (1995). Third-party and independent candidates in American politics. Political Science Quarterly, 110, 349–367.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. (1963). Social choice and individual values (2nd ed.). New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Beck, J. (1997). Voting cycles in business curriculum reform: a note. The American Economic Review, 41, 83–88.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bianco, W., Lynch, M., Miller, G., & Sened, I. (2006). “A theory waiting to be discovered and used”: a reanalysis of canonical experiments on majority decision making. The Journal of Politics, 68, 838–851.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bjurulf, B. H., & Niemi, R. G. (1978). Strategic voting in Scandinavian parliaments. Scandinavian Political Studies, 1, 5–22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Black, D. (1958). The theory of committees and elections. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blydenburgh, J. C. (1971). The closed rule and the paradox of voting. The Journal of Politics, 33, 57–71.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bochsler, D. (2010). The Marquis de Condorcet goes to Bern. Public Choice, 144, 119–131.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Browne, E. C., & Hamm, K. E. (1996). Legislative politics and the paradox of voting: electoral reform in the Fourth Republic France. British Journal of Political Science, 26, 165–198.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Campbell, C. D., & Tullock, G. (1965). A measure of importance of cyclical majorities. Economic Journal, 75, 853–857.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chamberlin, J. R., Cohen, J. L., & Coombs, C. H. (1984). Social choice observed: five presidential elections of the American psychological association. The Journal of Politics, 46, 479–502.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Condorcet, M. (1785). Essai sur l’application de l’analyse a la probabilité des decisions rendues a la pluralité des voix. In M. Condorcet (Ed.), Sur les élections et autres textes. Corpus des Oeuvres de philosophie en langue Française. Paris: Librairie Arthème Fayard. (1986).

    Google Scholar 

  • Dahl, R. (1956). A preface to democratic theory. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dahl, R. (1989). Democracy and its critics. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Davis, O. M., DeGroot, H., & Hinich, M. J. (1972). Social preference orderings and majority rule. Econometrica, 40, 147–157.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Meyer, F., & Plott, C. (1970). The probability of a cyclical majority. Econometrica, 38, 345–354.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dietz, H. A., & Goodman, M. J. (1987). An empirical analysis of preferences in the 1983 multicandidate Peruvian mayoral election. American Journal of Political Science, 31, 281–295.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dobra, J. (1983). An approach to empirical studies in voter paradoxes: an update and extension. Public Choice, 41, 241–250.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dobra, J., & Tullock, G. (1981). An approach to the empirical measures of voting paradoxes. Public Choice, 41, 193–194.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dodgson, C. L. (1876). A method of taking votes on more than two issues. In D. Black (Ed.) (1958).

    Google Scholar 

  • Dyer, J. S., & Miles, R. F. (1976). An application of collective choice theory to the selection of trajectories for the Mariner Jupiter/Saturn project. Operational Research, 24, 220–244.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Enelow, J., & Hinich, M. (1984). The spatial theory of voting. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Feld, S., & Grofman, B. (1987). Necessary and sufficient conditions for a majority winner in n-dimensional spatial voting games: an intuitive geometric approach. American Journal of Political Science, 31, 709–728.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feld, S. L., & Grofman, B. (1992). Who’s afraid of the big bad cycle? Evidence from 36 elections. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 4, 231–237.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fiorina, M., & Plott, C. (1978). Committee decisions under majority rule: an experimental study. American Political Science Review, 72, 575–598.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fishburn, P. (1973a). The theory of social choice. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fishburn, P. (1973b). Voter concordance, simple majority, and group decision methods. Behavioral Science, 18, 364–376.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fishburn, P., & Little, J. D. C. (1988). An experiment in approval voting. Management Sciences, 34, 555–568.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Flanagan, T. (1997). The staying power of the legislative status quo: collective choice in Canada’s parliament after Morgenthaler. Canadian Journal of Political Science, 30, 31–53.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Flood, M. (1955). A group preference experiment. In Mathematical models of human behavior (pp. 130–148). Stanford: Dunlap and Associates.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gaertner, W. (2001). Domain conditions in social choice theory. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Garman, M. B., & Kamien, M. I. (1968). The paradox of voting: probability calculations. Behavioral Science, 13, 306–316.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gaubatz, K. T. (1995). Intervention and intransitivity: public opinion, social choice, and the use of military forces abroad. World Politics, 47, 534–554.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gehrlein, W. V. (1983). Condorcet’s paradox. Theory and Decision, 15, 161–197.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gehrlein, W. V. (2004). The likelihood of complete breakdown by majority rule. In: Proceedings of National Decision Sciences Institute, Boston, MA (pp. 411–416).

    Google Scholar 

  • Gehrlein, W. V. (2006). Condorcet’s paradox. Berlin: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gehrlein, W. V., & Fishburn, P. (1976). The probability of the paradox of voting: a computable solution. Journal of Economic Theory, 13, 14–25.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gehrlein, W. V., & Lepelley, D. (2011). Voting paradoxes and group coherence. Berlin: Springer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Hsieh, J. F., Niou, E. M., & Paolino, P. (1997). Analytical representations of probabilities under the IAC condition. Social Choice and Welfare, 17, 143–156.

    Google Scholar 

  • Inada, K. (1964). A note on the simple majority decision rule. Econometrica, 32, 316–338.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Inada, K. (1969). On the simple majority decision rule. Econometrica, 37, 490–506.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jones, B., Radcliff, B., Taber, C., & Timpone, T. (1995). Condorcet winners and the paradox of voting: probability calculations for weak preference orders. American Political Science Review, 89, 137–147.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kemeny, J., & Snell, J. (1962). Mathematical models in the social sciences. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Klahr, D. (1966). A computer simulation of the paradox of voting. The American Political Science Review, 60, 384–390.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kurrild-Klitgaard, P. (2001). An empirical example of the Condorcet paradox of voting in a large electorate. Public Choice, 107, 135–145.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kurrild-Klitgaard, P. (2005). Individ, Stat og Marked: Studier i Rationalitet og Politik, København: Politiske Studier. Available at SSRN. http://ssrn.com/abstract=1972300 or doi:10.2139/ssrn.1972300.

  • Kurrild-Klitgaard, P. (2008). Voting paradoxes under proportional representation: evidence from eight Danish elections. Scandinavian Political Studies, 31, 242–267.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lagerspetz, E. (1997). Social choice in the real world II: cyclical preferences and strategic voting in the Finnish presidential elections. Scandinavian Political Studies, 20, 53–67.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lepelley, D., & Martin, M. (2001). Condorcet’s paradox for weak preference orderings. European Journal of Political Economy, 17, 163–177.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mackie, G. (2003). Democracy defended. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • May, R. M. (1971). Some mathematical remarks on the paradox of voting. Behavioral Science, 16, 143–151.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McKelvey, R. (1976). Intransitivities in multidimensional voting models and some implications for agenda control. Journal of Economic Theory, 12, 472–482.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McKelvey, R. (1979). General conditions for global intransitivities in formal voting models. Econometrica, 47, 1085–1112.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McKelvey, R., & Ordeshook, P. (1990). A decade of experimental research on spatial models. In J. Enelow & M. Hinich (Eds.), Advances in the spatial theory of voting (pp. 99–145). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Miller, N. R. (2007). In search of the uncovered set. Political Analysis, 15, 21–45.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morse, J. R. (1997). Constitutional rules, political accidents, and the course of history: new light on the annexation of Texas. Independent Review, 2, 173–201.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nakamura, K. (1975). The core of a simple game with ordinal preferences. International Journal of Game Theory, 4, 95–104.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nakamura, K. (1979). The vetoers in a simple game with ordinal preferences. International Journal of Game Theory, 8, 55–61.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Neufeld, J. L., Hausman, W. J., & Rapoport, R. B. (1994). A paradox of voting. Cyclical majorities and the case of muscle shoals. Political Research Quarterly, 47, 423–438.

    Google Scholar 

  • Niemi, R. G. (1969). Majority decision-making with partial unidimensionality. The American Political Science Review, 63, 488–497.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Niemi, R. G. (1970). The occurrence of the paradox of voting in university elections. Public Choice, 8, 91–100.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Niemi, R. G., & Weisberg, H. F. (1968). A mathematical solution for the probability of the paradox of voting. Behavioral Science, 13, 317–323.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Norpoth, H. (1979). The parties come to order! Dimensions of preferential choice in the West German electorate. The American Political Science Review, 73, 724–736.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nurmi, H. (1999). Voting paradoxes and how to deal with them. Berlin: Springer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Owen, G. (1990). Stable outcomes in spatial voting games. Mathematical Social Sciences, 19, 269–279.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Owen, G., & Shapley, L. S. (1989). Optimal location of candidates in ideological space. International Journal of Game Theory, 18, 339–356.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pattanaik, P. (1971). Voting and collective choice. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Peleg, B. (1984). Game theoretic analysis of voting in committees. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Plott, C. (1967). A notion of equilibrium and its possibility under majority rule. The American Economic Review, 57, 787–806.

    Google Scholar 

  • Radcliff, B. (1994). Collective preferences in presidential elections. Electoral Studies, 13, 50–57.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Regenwetter, M., & Grofman, B. (1998). Approval voting, Borda winners, and Condorcet winners: evidence from seven elections. Management Science, 44, 520–533.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Regenwetter, M., Adams, J., & Grofman, B. (2002a). On the (sample) Condorcet efficiency of majority rule: an alternit e view of majority cycles and social homogeneity. Theory and Decision, 53, 153–186.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Regenwetter, M., Grofman, B., & Marley, A. A. J. (2002b). On the model dependence of majority preference relations reconstructed from ballot or survey data. Mathematical Social Sciences, 43, 451–466.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Regenwetter, M. B., Marly, A. A. J., & Grofman, B. (2003). General concepts of value restriction and preference majority. Social Choice and Welfare, 21, 149–173.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Regenwetter, M., Grofman, B., Marley, A., & Tsetlin, I. (2006). Behavioral social choice. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Regenwetter, M., Kim, A., Kantor, A., & Ho, M. (2007). The unexpected empirical consensus among consensus methods. Psychological Science, 18, 629–635.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Riker, W. H. (1958). The paradox of voting and congressional rules for voting on amendments. The American Political Science Review, 52, 349–366.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Riker, W. H. (1965). Arrow’s theorem and some examples of the paradox of voting. In J. M. Claunch (Ed.), Mathematical applications in political science, Dallas (pp. 41–60).

    Google Scholar 

  • Riker, W. H. (1980). Implications from the disequilibrium of majority rule for the study of institutions. American Political Science Review, 74(2), 432–446.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Riker, W. H. (1982). Liberalism against populism. San Francisco: Freeman.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosen, M. D., & Sexton, R. J. (1993). Irrigation districts and water markets: an application of cooperative decision making. Land Economics, 69, 39–54.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sen, A. (1966). A possibility theorem on majority decisions. Econometrica, 34, 491–496.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sen, A. (1970). Collective choice and social welfare. San Fransisco: Holden Day.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sen, A., & Pattanaik, P. (1969). Necessary and sufficient conditions for rational choice under majority decision. Journal of Economic Theory, 1, 178–202.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shapley, L. S. (1963). Simple games: an outline of the descriptive theory. Behavioral Science, 7, 59–66.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith, W. D. (2009). The Romanian 2009 presidential election featured Condorcet cycles. http://www.rangevoting.org/Romania2009.html.

  • Stensholt, E. (1999). Voteringens kvaler: flypkasen I Stortinget 8 Okotber 1992. Sosialøkonomen, 4, 28–40.

    Google Scholar 

  • Taplin, R. H. (1997). The statistical analysis of preference data. Applied Statistics, 46, 493–512.

    Google Scholar 

  • Taylor, M. (1968). Graph-theoretic approaches to the theory of social choice. Public Choice, 4, 35–47.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taylor, A. (1997). A glimpse of impossibility: Kenneth Arrow’s impossibility theory and voting. Perspectives on Political Science, 26, 23–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tideman, N. (2006). Collective decisions and voting. Chippenham: Ashgate.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tideman, N. (2012). Personal communication. March 23, 2012 (by email).

  • Toda, M., Sugiyama, K., & Tagawa, S. (1982). A method for aggregating ordinal assessments by a majority decision rule. Mathematical Social Sciences, 3, 227–242.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Truchon, M. (1998). Rating skating and the theory of social choice. Université Laval. Unpublished.

  • Van Dam, M. J. (1998). The purple paradox: decision making on the MUB. Acta Politica, 33, 77–85.

    Google Scholar 

  • Van Deemen, A. (1997). Coalition formation and social choice. Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Van Deemen, A. (1999). The probability of the paradox of voting for weak preference orderings. Social Choice and Welfare, 10, 171–182.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van Deemen, A., & Saiz, H. (2010). Extremal restriction, Condorcet sets, and majority decision making. In A. Van Deemen & A. Rusinowska (Eds.), Collective decision making (pp. 69–85).

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Van Deemen, A., & Vergunst, N. (1998). Empirical evidence of paradoxes of voting in Dutch elections. Public Choice, 97, 475–490.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vergunst, N. (1996). Besluitvorming over kerncentrale Borssele: een analyse van de stemparadox in de Nederlandse politiek. Acta Politica, 31, 209–228.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wilson, S. (2003). O boy. Sun Journal, July 3.

Download references

Acknowledgements

The author would like to thank the five anonymous referees for their critical remarks, useful comments, and valuable suggestions for improvements. Of course, the author is responsible for the remaining errors and omissions.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Adrian Van Deemen.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Van Deemen, A. On the empirical relevance of Condorcet’s paradox. Public Choice 158, 311–330 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-013-0133-3

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-013-0133-3

Keywords

Navigation