Skip to main content
Log in

Divergence of opinion and initial public offerings

  • Original Research
  • Published:
Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This article analyzes several IPO patterns in the framework of divergence of opinion. Considering a new industry with few publicly traded companies, the investors in this IPO market do not initially have complete knowledge about the industry, but may learn from other IPOs in the sector. Our model shows that the equilibrium is consistent with empirical evidence documented for IPO underpricing and hot issue markets. We also characterize the association between share overhang, trading volume, and IPO prices. Furthermore, we discuss the decision of going public, analyst coverage, and IPO lockup expiration in the presence of divergent opinions.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Various models have been developed to explain underpricing based on different categories of participants. Among them, Rock (1986) argues that issuers price IPOs at a discount to compensate uninformed investors for the winner’s curse problem because informed investors do not participate in bad issues but only in good issues. Derrien (2005) presents a model with information cascade in which institutional participants in an IPO market receive private signals and bullish noise traders raise the aftermarket price on the offer date.

  2. Other related theories focusing on the role of investment banks and underwriters are Baron (1982) and Benveniste and Spindt (1989).

  3. Other theories on capital markets addressing the difference of opinion can be found in Varian (1985, 1989), Harris and Raviv (1993), and Hong and Stein (2003).

  4. See Fig. 1 in Miller (1977) that allows each investor to purchase only one unit of the risky asset and the discussion about the role of the minority of optimistic investors who purchase to absorb total supply.

  5. The role of short sales constraints is especially addressed in Houge et al. (2001), who suggest that short sellers face difficulty borrowing stocks as regulations and market practices restrict. Gao et al. (2006) also discuss the influence of short sales constraint on long-run underperformance. In our model a limited amount of short sales can be allowed in a generalized framework, where an additional supply arising from the short sales can be included.

  6. The assumptions regarding information and signals are similar to those used in Teoh and Hwang (1991, p. 287) and Biais and Gollier (1997, p. 908).

  7. Scheinkman and Xiong (2003) present a model of price bubbles in which an asset owner has an option to sell the asset to other agents with more optimistic beliefs. In their framework, the bubble is based on the recursive expectations of traders.

  8. The post-IPO quiet period lasts for 25 calendar days. As of July 2002, the quiet period has been prolonged to 40 days for managing underwriters including lead underwriters and co-managers.

  9. Based on our assumption and the Bayesian rule, the probability f can be alternatively interpreted as the probability that the company is a good firm conditional on receiving positive analyst coverage. The setting of signals are also adopted similarly in Teoh and Hwang (1991) and Biais and Gollier (1997).

References

  • Akerlof G (1970) The market for ‘lemmons’: quality and the market mechanism. Q J Econ 84:488–500

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aumann R (1966) Existence of competitive equilibrium in markets with a continuum of traders. Econometrica 34:1–17

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baron D (1982) A model of the demand for investment banking advising and distribution services for new issues. J Finance 37:955–976

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beatty R, Ritter J (1986) Investment banking, reputation, and the underpricing of initial public offerings. J Financ Econ 15:213–232

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benveniste L, Spindt P (1989) How investment bankers determine the offer price and allocation of new issues. J Financ Econ 24:343–361

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Biais B, Gollier C (1997) Trade credit and credit rationing. Rev Financ Stud 10:903–937

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Booth J, Smith R (1986) Capital raising, underwriting and the certification hypothesis. J Financ Econ 15:261–281

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bradley D, Jordan B (2002) Partial adjustment to public information and IPO underpricing. J Financ Quant Anal 37:595–616

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bradley D, Jordan B, Roten I, Yi H (2001) Venture capital and IPO lockup expiration: an empirical analysis. J Financ Res 24:465–492

    Google Scholar 

  • Bradley D, Jordan B, Ritter J (2003) The quiet period goes out with a bang. J Finance 58:1–36

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brav A, Gompers P (2003) The role of lockups in initial public offerings. Rev Financ Stud 16:1–29

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carter R, Manaster S (1990) Initial public offerings and underwriter reputation. J Finance 45:1045–1067

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chemmanur T, Fulghieri P (1999) A theory of the going-public decision. Rev Financ Stud 12:249–279

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cliff M, Denis D (2004) Do initial public offering firms purchase analyst coverage with underpricing? J Finance 59:2871–2901

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Derrien F (2005) IPO pricing in “hot market conditions: who leaves money on the table?”. J Finance 60:487–521

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Field L, Hanka G (2001) The expiration of IPO share lockups. J Finance 56:471–500

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gao Y, Mao C, Zhong R (2006) Divergence of opinion and long-term performance of initial public offerings. J Financ Res 29:113–129

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hanley K (1993) The underpricing of initial public offerings and the partial adjustment phenomenon. J Financ Econ 34:231–250

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harris M, Raviv A (1993) Differences of opinion make a horse race. Rev Financ Stud 6:473–506

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Helwege J, Liang N (2004) Initial public offerings in hot and cold markets. J Financ Quant Anal 39:541–569

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hong H, Stein J (2003) Differences of opinion, short-sales constraints, and market crashes. Rev Financ Stud 16:487–525

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Houge T, Loughran T, Suchanek G, Yan X (2001) Divergence of opinion, uncertainty, and the quality of initial public offerings. Financ Manag 30:5–23

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ibbotson R (1975) Price performance of common stock new issues. J Financ Econ 2:235–272

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ibbotson R, Jaffe JF (1975) Hot issue markets. J Finance 30:1027–1042

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • James C, Wier P (1990) Borrowing relationships, intermediation, and the cost of issuing public securities. J Financ Econ 28:149–171

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ljungqvist A, Wilhelm WJ (2003) IPO pricing in the dot-com bubble. J Finance 58:723–752

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ljungqvist A, Nanda V, Singh R (2006) Hot markets, investor sentiment, and IPO pricing. J Bus 79:1667–1702

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Logue D (1973) On the pricing of unseasoned equity issues: 1965–69. J Financ Quant Anal 8:91–103

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Loughran T, Ritter J (1995) The new issues puzzle. J Finance 50:23–51

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Loughran T, Ritter J (2002) Why don’t issuers get upset about leaving money on the table in IPOs? Rev Financ Stud 15:413–444

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Loughran T, Ritter J (2004) Why has IPO underpricing changed over time? Financ Manag 33:5–37

    Google Scholar 

  • Loughran T, Ritter J, Rydqvist K (1994) Initial public offerings: international insights. Pac Basin Financ J 2:165–199

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maksimovic V, Pichler P (2001) Technological innovation and initial public offerings. Rev Financ Stud 14:459–494

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miller E (1977) Risk, uncertainty, and divergence of opinion. J Finance 32:1151–1168

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morris S (1996) Speculative investor behavior and learning. Q J Econ 111:1111–1133

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nelson L (2002) Persistence and reversal in herd behavior: theory and application to the decision to go public. Rev Financ Stud 15:65–95

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ritter J (1984) The “hot issue market of 1980”. J Bus 57:215–240

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ritter J (1991) The long-run performance of initial public offerings. J Finance 46:3–27

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rock K (1986) Why new issues are underpriced? J Financ Econ 15:187–212

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scheinkman J, Xiong W (2003) Overconfidence and speculative bubbles. J Polit Econ 111:1183–1219

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schultz P (2003) Pseudo market timing and the long-run underperformance of IPOs. J Finance 58:483–517

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Subrahmanyam A, Titman S (1999) The going-public decision and the development of financial markets. J Finance 54:1045–1082

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Teoh S, Hwang C (1991) Nondisclosure and adverse disclosure as signals of firm value. Rev Financ Stud 4:283–313

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Teoh S, Welch I, Wong T (1998) Earnings management and the long-run market performance of initial public offerings. J Finance 53:1935–1974

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Varian HR (1985) Divergence of opinion in complete markets: a note. J Finance 40:309–317

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Varian HR (1989) Differences of Opinion in Financial Markets. In: Stone CC (ed) Financial risk: theory, evidence and implications. Proceedings of the eleventh annual economic policy conference of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

  • Welch I (1989) Seasoned offerings, imitation costs, and the underpricing of initial public offerings. J Finance 44:421–449

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Welch I (1992) Sequential sales, learning, and cascades. J Finance 47:695–732

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We are grateful to the editor and two anonymous referees for their insightful comments and suggestions. Hsuan-Chi Chen wishes to thank the Anderson School of Management at the University of New Mexico for providing financial support; Wen-Chung Guo would like to thank the National Science Council of Taiwan for research grant (NSC 93-2416-H-305-011).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Wen-Chung Guo.

Appendix

Appendix

Lemma 1

The function

$$ G(x) = \frac{\phi (x|N,k)}{{\phi (x|N,k) + (1 - \phi (x|N,k))\left( {\tfrac{1 - q}{q}} \right)^{2j - 1} }}V $$

is increasing in x.

Proof of Lemma 1

Because \( \frac{\partial G(x)}{\partial x} = \frac{\partial G}{\partial \phi }\frac{\partial \phi }{\partial x}, \) the lemma is proved by noting that

$$ \frac{\partial \phi }{\partial x} > 0 $$

is obtained from both (1) and (2), and \( \frac{\partial G}{\partial \phi } = \frac{{\left( {\tfrac{1 - q}{q}} \right)^{2j - 1} }}{{\left[ {\phi + (1 - \phi )\left( {\tfrac{1 - q}{q}} \right)^{2j - 1} } \right]^{2} }}V > 0. \)

Proof of Proposition 1

We prove the uniqueness of equilibrium first. From the conditions (6) and (7), it follows that the solution satisfies:

$$ \frac{(1 - x)e}{m} = \frac{\phi (x|N,k)}{{\phi (x|N,k) + (1 - \phi (x|N,k))\left( {\tfrac{1 - q}{q}} \right)^{2j - 1} }}V $$

The left term is a monotonically decreasing function of x, while the right term increases in x based on Lemma 1. Then we have a unique solution based on the intermediate value theorem. Next, we prove the result of underpricing by contradiction. Let p* ≤ p 0. From (6), it follows

$$ x^{*} \ge 1 - m\frac{{p_{0} }}{e} > 1 - m = x_{0} . $$

Then it leads to p* > p 0 because the function in (4) increases in x. Thus, we prove p* > p 0 and x* > x 0.

Proof of Proposition 2

From (1), it is obvious that B(x|N,k) increases in 2k − N. Then from (2), it follows that ϕ(x|N,k) is increasing in 2k − N. Therefore, from (5) and (7), we obtain that p 0 and p* increase in 2k − N.

Proof of Proposition 3

When N approaches infinity, B(x|N,k) converges to 1 (successful industry) or 0 (unsuccessful industry), which implies that investors have full knowledge about whether the industry is successful, as in the case of rational expectation.

Proof of Proposition 4

From x 0 = 1 − m, (57) it can be proved. Because B(x|N,k) is positively associated with x, a decrease in m will increase x 0, and thus increase ϕ(x 0|Nk). From Eq. 5 it follows that p 0 will decrease with m. The effect of m on p* can be proved by contradiction. Assume that p* does not increase with a decrease in m. From (6) it follows that x* will increases, and therefore from Eq. 7 p* will increase. This leads to a contradiction.

Proof of Proposition 5

If \( \tilde{e} > e, \) because \( \tilde{x}_{0} = x_{0} = 1 - m, \) by Eqs. 2 and 4 we have \( \tilde{p}_{0} = p_{0}. \) Next we prove \( \tilde{x}^{*} > x^{*} \) and \( \tilde{p}^{*} > p^{*} \) by contradiction. If \( \tilde{x}^{*} \le x^{*}, \) then from Eq. 6 and \( \tilde{e} > e, \) it leads to \( \tilde{p}^{*} > p^{*}. \) However, from (7) and \( \tilde{x}^{*} \le x^{*}, \) it leads to\( \tilde{p}^{*} \le p^{*}, \) which is a contradiction.

Proof of Proposition 6

When investors have received a good signal, j = 1, from (57) it can be shown that p 0 and p* increase in q by a similar argument to Proposition 4 because

$$ \frac{\phi (x|N,k)}{{\phi (x|N,k) + (1 - \phi (x|N,k))\left( {\tfrac{1 - q}{q}} \right)^{2j - 1} }} $$

increases (decreases) in q if j = 1 (j = 0).

Proof of Proposition 7

If \( \tilde{B}(x) > B(x), \) because \( \tilde{x}_{0} = x_{0} = 1 - m, \) by Eq. 2 we have \( \tilde{\phi }(\tilde{x}_{0} |N,k) > \phi (x_{0} |N,k) \), and therefore \( \tilde{p}_{0} > p_{0}. \) Next we prove \( \tilde{x}^{*} < x^{*} \) and \( \tilde{p}^{*} > p^{*} \) by contradiction. If \( \tilde{x}^{*} \ge x^{*}, \) then from Eq. 6 it leads to \( \tilde{p}^{*} \le p^{*}. \) However, from (7) and \( \tilde{x}^{*} \ge x^{*} \) it leads to \( \tilde{p}^{*} > p^{*}, \) which is a contradiction.

Proof of Proposition 8

From (6), x* can be stated as x* = 1 − mp*/e. Thus, trading volume would be: \( (x^{*} + m - 1)I = I(1 - mp^{*} /e + m - 1) = Im(e - p^{*} )/e. \)

By the proof of Proposition 4, p* is decreasing in m. Differentiating the right hand side of the above identity with respect to m, we conclude that trading volume is increasing in m. Because share overhang is decreasing in m, the chain rule would establish that trading volume is negatively associated with share overhang. In the proof of Proposition 5, we know that \( \tilde{x}^{*} > x^{*} \) if \( \tilde{e} > e. \) Similarly, by the proof of Proposition 7, we have observed that \( \tilde{x}^{*} > x^{*} \) if \( \tilde{B}(x) > B(x). \) Thus, trading volume in the aftermarket is positively related to the investment amount e and the extent of investor optimism.

Proof of Proposition 9

From (9), the going public condition becomes mp 0 + A ≥ mλV when the entrepreneur believes that the industry is a successful one, and mp 0 + A ≥ m(1 − λ)V in an unsuccessful industry. Because p 0 is positively associated with the degree of optimism of investors, the results are obviously obtained. From Eqs. 1, 2, and 5, we have:

$$ H(\lambda ,B_{0} ,2k - N) = 1 + \frac{{\lambda + (1 - \lambda )\left( {\tfrac{{1 - B_{0} (x_{0} )}}{{B_{0} (x_{0} )}}} \right)\left( {\tfrac{1 - \lambda }{\lambda }} \right)^{2k - N} }}{{1 - \lambda + \lambda \left( {\tfrac{{1 - B_{0} (x_{0} )}}{{B_{0} (x_{0} )}}} \right)\left( {\tfrac{1 - \lambda }{\lambda }} \right)^{2k - N} }}\left( {\tfrac{1 - q}{q}} \right)^{2j - 1} $$
$$ p_{0} = \left[ {\frac{1}{{1 + \frac{{\lambda + (1 - \lambda )\left( {\tfrac{{1 - B_{0} (x_{0} )}}{{B_{0} (x_{0} )}}} \right)\left( {\tfrac{1 - \lambda }{\lambda }} \right)^{2k - N} }}{{1 - \lambda + \lambda \left( {\tfrac{{1 - B_{0} (x_{0} )}}{{B_{0} (x_{0} )}}} \right)\left( {\tfrac{1 - \lambda }{\lambda }} \right)^{2k - N} }}\left( {\tfrac{1 - q}{q}} \right)^{2j - 1} }}} \right]V = \left[ {\frac{1}{{H(\lambda ,B_{0} ,2k - N)}}} \right]V. $$

The two inequalities in Proposition 9 are obtained by substituting the above equation into (9). In addition, \( {{(H(\lambda ,B_{0} ,2k - N) - 1)} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{(H(\lambda ,B_{0} ,2k - N) - 1)} {\left( {\tfrac{1 - q}{q}} \right)^{2j - 1} }}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {\left( {\tfrac{1 - q}{q}} \right)^{2j - 1} }} = \frac{{\lambda + (1 - \lambda )\left( {\tfrac{{1 - B_{0} (x_{0} )}}{{B_{0} (x_{0} )}}} \right)\left( {\tfrac{1 - \lambda }{\lambda }} \right)^{2k - N} }}{{1 - \lambda + \lambda \left( {\tfrac{{1 - B_{0} (x_{0} )}}{{B_{0} (x_{0} )}}} \right)\left( {\tfrac{1 - \lambda }{\lambda }} \right)^{2k - N} }} = \frac{\lambda + (1 - \lambda )h}{1 - \lambda + \lambda h}, \) where \( h = \left( {\tfrac{{1 - B_{0} (x_{0} )}}{{B_{0} (x_{0} )}}} \right)\left( {\tfrac{1 - \lambda }{\lambda }} \right)^{2k - N}. \)  Note that λ > 0.5 and h is strictly decreasing in B 0 and 2k − N. The following derivative shows that:

$$ \frac{{\partial \{ (\lambda + (1 - \lambda )h)/(1 - \lambda + \lambda h)\} }}{\partial h} = (1 - 2\lambda )/(1 - \lambda + \lambda h)^{2} < 0. $$

Therefore, H(λB 0, 2k − N) is increasing in 2k − N and B 0. Eq. 11 holds if B 0 and 2k − N is relatively large. Moreover, Eq. 11 also tends to hold if A is relatively large and m is relatively small.

Proof of Proposition 10

It can be shown that

$$ \frac{k(x)f}{k(x)f + (1 - k(x))(1 - f)} > k(x)\quad {\text{if}}\;f > 0.5, $$

because

$$ \frac{k(x)f}{k(x)f + (1 - k(x))(1 - f)} - k(x) = \frac{k(x)(1 - k(x))(2f - 1)}{k(x)f + (1 - k(x))(1 - f)} $$

and k(x) < 1. Therefore, from (6a) and (12), it follows to that \( p_{a}^{*} (s,N,k) > p^{*} (s,N,k) \) by a contradiction. From (6a), the representation \( p_{a}^{*} \left( {s,N,k} \right) = \left( {1 - x_{a}^{*} } \right)e/m \) is a decreasing function in \( x_{a}^{*}, \)  and from (12), \( p_{a}^{*} (s,N,k) = \frac{{k\left( {x_{a}^{*} } \right)f}}{{k(x_{a}^{*} )f + \left( {1 - k\left( {x_{a}^{*} } \right)} \right)(1 - f)}}V \)  is an increasing function of \( x_{a}^{*}. \) By the fact that

$$ \frac{k(x)f}{k(x)f + (1 - k(x))(1 - f)} > k(x) $$

if \( p_{a}^{*} (s,N,k) \le p^{*} (s,N,k) \) holds, by \( p_{a}^{*} (s,N,k) = (1 - x_{a}^{*} )e/m \) it follows that \( x_{a}^{*} \ge x^{*}, \) which contradicts to \( p_{a}^{*} (s,N,k) = \frac{{k\left( {x_{a}^{*} } \right)f}}{{k\left( {x_{a}^{*} } \right)f + \left( {1 - k\left( {x_{a}^{*} } \right)} \right)(1 - f)}}V. \) Note that

$$ \frac{k(x)f}{k(x)f + (1 - k(x))(1 - f)} = k(x) $$

when f = 0.5, that is, the analyst coverage does not provide additional information to investors. In this degenerated case, it leads to \( p_{a}^{*} (s,N,k) = p^{*} (s,N,k). \) Moreover,

$$ \frac{{\partial p_{a}^{*} (s,N,k)}}{\partial f} > 0 $$

can be proved because \( \frac{{\partial \left[ {\frac{k(x)f}{k(x)f + (1 - k(x))(1 - f)}} \right]}}{\partial f} = \frac{k(x)(1 - k(x)}{{[k(x)f + (1 - k(x))(1 - f)]^{2} }} > 0. \)

Proof of Proposition 11

From (13), \( p_{{m^{\prime}}}^{*} (s,N,k) = (1 - x_{{m^{\prime}}}^{*} )e/(m + m^{\prime}) \) is decreasing in m′ and x. From (12a), p is increasing in x. We prove it by contradiction similarly to the proof of Proposition 10. If \( p_{{m^{\prime}}}^{*} \) is not decreasing in m′, then from (12a) an increase in m′ will be related to an increase in x, which contradicts to (13). Therefore, the proposition is proved.

Proof of Proposition 12

First, note that p 0 is unchanged and solved by (5). The aftermarket price and marginal investor (p *,x *) will satisfy the equilibrium conditions (15) and (16). Because B(x) is increasing in (2k − N) from (1), it follows that e(x, B(x)) is increasing in (2k−N), which means that the endogenous investment amount will be positively related to the number of positive outcomes minus the total number of IPOs in history. Next, we prove the impact of investment function e(x, B(x)) on the aftermarket price by contradiction. For any (N,k) and given \( \tilde{e}(x, B(x)) > e(x, B(x)), \) if \( \tilde{p}^{*} \le p^{*}, \) from (16) it follows that \( \tilde{x}^{*} \le x^{*}. \) From (15), this suggests that

$$ p_{{}}^{*} = \int_{{x^{*} }}^{1} {e(y, B(y)){\text{d}}y} /m $$

is decreasing in x* but increasing in e. Therefore, by \( \tilde{x}^{*} \le x^{*} \) and the inequality \( \tilde{e}(x, B(x)) > e(x, B(x)) \) for all x, it leads to \( \tilde{p}^{*} > p^{*}, \) which is a contradiction.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Chen, HC., Guo, WC. Divergence of opinion and initial public offerings. Rev Quant Finan Acc 34, 59–79 (2010). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11156-009-0125-z

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11156-009-0125-z

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation