Skip to main content
Log in

Economic Evaluation and Cost-Effectiveness Thresholds

Signals to Firms and Implications for R&D Investment and Innovation

  • Current Opinion
  • Published:
PharmacoEconomics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this article we describe how reimbursement cost-effectiveness thresholds, per unit of health benefit, whether set explicitly or observed implicitly via historical reimbursement decisions, serve as a signal to firms about the commercial viability of their R&D projects (including candidate products for in-licensing). Traditional finance methods for R&D project valuations, such as net present value analyses (NPV), incorporate information from these payer reimbursement signals to help determine which R&D projects should be continued and which should be terminated (in the case of the latter because they yield an NPV < 0). Because the influence these signals have for firm R&D investment decisions is so significant, we argue that it is important for reimbursement thresholds to reflect the economic value of the unit of health benefit being considered for reimbursement.

Thresholds set too low (below the economic value of the health benefit) will result in R&D investment levels that are too low relative to the economic value of R&D (on the margin). Similarly, thresholds set too high (above the economic value of the health benefit) will result in inefficiently high levels of R&D spending. The US in particular, which represents approximately half of the global pharmaceutical market (based on sales), and which seems poised to begin undertaking cost effectiveness in a systematic way, needs to exert caution in setting policies that explicitly or implicitly establish cost-effectiveness reimbursement thresholds for healthcare products and technologies, such as pharmaceuticals.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Some of the material in this paper is based on previous research undertaken jointly with several co-authors. See, for example, Vernon et al.[1,2] Portions of the introduction section and Section 2 come from unpublished earlier versions of the aforementioned joint research.

  2. A QALY is a year of life in perfect health; because life-years are often not lived in perfect health, utility scores ranging from 0 (death) to 1 (perfect health) are used to adjust life-years based on the degree of health in a given year. As such, these utility adjustments place survival and life-years on a level playing field. For example, 2 years lived in a state of poor health associated with a utility score of 0.5 would be equivalent to a year of life in perfect health, in which the utility score would be 1 (this ignores discounting).

  3. In a previously published paper,[1] we describe the various methods used within this context by firm managers, especially for potential projects in the earliest stages of drug development.

  4. In addition to the aforementioned studies, the interested reader is also referred to the paper by Devlin and Parkin.[32]

  5. This assumes several things. Abbott and Vernon[33] provide a detailed analysis and discussion of these assumptions. In simple terms, a lower equilibrium price, i.e. P max, all else held constant, will lead to lower net present values (NPVs) for developmental products (or potential in-license products) and fewer R&D projects will satisfy the NPV > 0 investment criterion, and thus will be discontinued. A similar but more complicated logic holds when R&D projects are modelled as real options.

  6. As was suggested to us by one of the referees of this article, publicly subsidized R&D and potential inefficiencies resulting from patent races might result in an optimal value of k < v.

  7. It is also true that hedonic estimates of the value of a life-year have been undertaken and conclude that a life-year is valued at levels greater than $US175 000.

  8. We thank an anonymous reviewer for bringing this point to our attention.

References

  1. Vernon JA, Hughen WK, Johnson S. Mathematical modeling and pharmaceutical pricing for in-licensing and developmental go/no-go decisions. Health Care Manage Sci 2005; 8 (2): 167–79

    Article  Google Scholar 

  2. Vernon JA, Johnson S, Hughen K, et al. Economic and developmental considerations for pharmacogenomic technology. Pharmacoeconomics 2006; 24 (4): 335–43

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  3. Neumann PJ, Rosen AB, Weinstein MC. Medicare and cost-effectiveness analysis. N Engl J Med 2005; 353: 1516–22

    Article  PubMed  CAS  Google Scholar 

  4. Neumann PJ. Why don’t Americans use cost-effectiveness analysis. Am J Manag Care 2004; 10 (5): 308–12

    PubMed  Google Scholar 

  5. Orszag PR. The long-term budget outlook and options for slowing the growth of health care costs: CBO testimony [online]. Available from URL: http://www.cbo.gov/doc.cfm?index=9385&type=0 [Accessed 2009 Aug 28]

  6. American Recovery and Reinvestment Act of 2009 [online]. Available from URL: https://www.ecri.org/Documents/CERC/HR1.pdf [Accessed 2009 Aug 28]

  7. Baucus Comparative Effectiveness Research Act of 2008: section-by-section overview [online]. Available from URL: http://finance.senate.gov/sitepages/leg/LEG%202008/080108%20CE%20Section-by-Section.pdf [Accessed 2009 Feb 5]

  8. Enthoven AC. The history and principles of managed competition. Health Aff 1993; 12 Suppl.: 24–48

    Article  Google Scholar 

  9. Sloan FA, editor. Valuing health care: costs, benefits, and effectiveness of pharmaceuticals and other medical technologies. Cambridge (UK): Cambridge University Press, 1995

    Google Scholar 

  10. Iffe S. Thriving on challenge: NICE’s dementia guidelines. Exp Rev Pharmacoeconomics Outcomes Res 2007; 7 (6): 535–8

    Article  Google Scholar 

  11. Kaduszkiewicz H, Zimmermann T, Beck-Bornholdt H-P, et al. Cholinesterase inhibitors for patients with Alzheimer’s disease: systematic review of randomised clinical trials. BMJ 2005; 331 (7512): 321–7

    Article  PubMed  CAS  Google Scholar 

  12. No to Alzheimer’s drugs: NICE decision. Chem Ind 2006 Oct 16; 20: 8

  13. Peters A. No QALY in Germany’s cost-effectiveness draft: expert. APM Health Europe [online]. Available from URL: http://www.apmhealtheurope.com/story.php?mots=REIMBURSEMENT&searchScope=1&searchType=0&depsPage=10&numero=L9389 [Accessed 2009 Jan 22]

  14. Giacomini M. How good is good enough? Standards in policy decisions to cover new health technologies. Healthc Policy 2007; 3 (2): 91–101

    PubMed  Google Scholar 

  15. Davis K. Slowing the growth of health care costs: learning from international experience. N Engl J Med 2008 Oct 23; 359 (17): 1751–5

    Article  PubMed  CAS  Google Scholar 

  16. Kennedy I. Appraising the value of innovation and other benefits: a short study for NICE. July 2009 [online]. Available from URL: http://www.nice.org.uk/media/98F/5C/KennedyStudyFinalReport.pdf [Accessed 2009 Aug 28]

  17. Gabb M. Is it time for NICE to revise its threshold? Health Outcomes Communicator 2009 Apr; 39 [online]. Available from URL: http://www.rxcomms.com/HOC/HOC39web.htm [Accessed 2009 Sep 10]

  18. Sculpher MJ. NICE’s 2009 methods guide: sensible consolidation or opportunities missed? Pharmacoeconomics 2008; 26 (9): 721–4

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  19. Drummond MF, Sculpher MJ, Torrance GW, et al. Methods for the economic evaluation of health care programmes. New York: Oxford University Press, 1997

    Google Scholar 

  20. Torrance GW. Social preferences for health states: an empirical evaluation of three measurement techniques. Socioecon Plann Sci 1976; 10: 129–36

    Article  Google Scholar 

  21. Kingsbury K. The value of a human life: $129?000. Time 2008 May 20 [online]. Available from URL: http://www.time.com/time/health/article/0,8599,1808049,00.html [Accessed 2009 Aug 28]

  22. Lee CP, Chertow GM, Zenios SA. An empiric estimate of the value of life: updating the renal dialysis cost-effectiveness standard. Value Health 2009; 12 (1): 80–8

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  23. Mossialos E, Oliver A. An overview of pharmaceutical policy in four countries: France, Germany, the Netherlands and the United Kingdom. Int J Health Plann Manage 2005; 20: 291–306

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  24. Jommi C. Pharmaceutical policy and organization of the regulatory authorities in the main EU countries. Milan: Egea Publishing, 2001

    Google Scholar 

  25. Gosling H. European pharmacoeconomics: the fourth hurdle global pharmaceutical reports. Dublin: SMi Publishing, 2000

    Google Scholar 

  26. Sorenson C, Drummond M, Kanavos P. Ensuring value for money in health care: the role of health technology assessment in the European Union, 2008, European Observatory on HC Systems [online]. Available from URL: http://www.euro.who.int/observatory/[Accessed 2009 Feb 3]

  27. Atkinson T. The global parallel trade outlook 2001–2006: a country-by-country analysis. REUTERS Business Insight, Healthcare, Spring, 2002 [online]. Available from URL: http://www.globalbusinessinsights.com/content/rbhc0065t.pdf [Accessed 2009 Sep 10]

  28. Meenan RT, Feeny D, Labby D, et al. Using health-related quality of life assessments to evaluate care support within Medicaid. Care Manag J 2008; 9 (2): 42–50

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  29. Jena AB, Philipson T. Cost-effectiveness as a price control. Health Aff (Millwood) 2007 May/June;26 (3): 696–703

    Article  Google Scholar 

  30. Jena AB, Philipson T. Cost-effectiveness analysis and innovation. J Health Econ 2008; 27: 1224–36

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  31. Danzon P, Towse A. The economics of gene therapy and pharmacogenetics. Value Health 2002; 5 (1): 5–13

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  32. Devlin N, Parkin D. Does NICE have a cost-effectiveness threshold and what other factors influence its decisions? A binary choice analysis. Health Econ 2004; 13 (5): 437–52

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  33. Abbott TA, Vernon JA. The cost of US pharmaceutical price regulation: a financial simulation model of R&D decisions. Managerial Decision Econ 2007; 28 (4–5): 293–306

    Article  Google Scholar 

  34. Hirth RA, Chernew ME, Miller E, et al. Willingness to pay for a quality-adjusted life year: in search of a standard. Med Decis Making 2000; 20 (3): 332–42

    Article  PubMed  CAS  Google Scholar 

  35. Murphy KM, Topel RH. The economic value of medical research. In: Murphy KM, Topel RH, editors. Measuring the gains from medical research: an economic approach. Chicago (IL): University of Chicago Press, 2003

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  36. McCabe C, Claxton K, Culyer AJ. The NICE cost-effectiveness threshold: what it is and what that means. Pharmacoeconomics 2008; 26 (9): 733–44

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  37. National Academy of Science. Medical innovation in the changing healthcare market place. Washington, DC: National Academy Press, 2002

    Google Scholar 

  38. Macher JT, Mowery DC, editors. Innovation in global industries: US firms competing in a new world. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press, 2008

    Google Scholar 

  39. Hayek FA. The use of knowledge in society. American Econ Rev 1945; 35: 519–30

    Google Scholar 

  40. Moran N. Report blames NICE for hastening decline of UK biotech. Nat Biotechnol 2009; 27 (3): 215–7

    Article  PubMed  CAS  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors would like to thank the following individuals who have influenced this work in a significant manner: Keener Hughen, Scott Johnson, Antonio Tujillo, Fred Cox, Larry Gorkin, Jack McMillan, Lesley Shane and Dick Willke. The authors are very grateful to three anonymous referees who provided excellent feedback and suggestions for improving this article. Any errors in this paper are those of the authors. Finally, Anna Thomson and the editorial staff at PharmacoEconomics were enormously helpful in finalizing the published version of this paper. The authors are indebted to them for their painstaking review of citations and edits. The Center for Medicine in the Public Interest provided a $5 000 grant for the commissioning of this paper.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to John A. Vernon.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Vernon, J.A., Goldberg, R. & Golec, J. Economic Evaluation and Cost-Effectiveness Thresholds. Pharmacoeconomics 27, 797–806 (2009). https://doi.org/10.2165/11313750-000000000-00000

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.2165/11313750-000000000-00000

Keywords

Navigation