Acessibilidade / Reportar erro

On the Contributions of Knowledge-Intensive Business-Services Multinationals to Laggard Innovation Systems

Abstract

Foreign direct investment (FDI) is assumed to be a source of knowledge flows across National Innovation Systems, with particular relevance for developing countries. Nonetheless, empirical assessments are usually manufacturing-oriented, providing only a partial view of the phenomena under scrutiny. This article aims at contributing to this body of literature by investigating the impacts of inward FDI on aggregate outcomes of developing countries' National Innovation Systems, taking into account potential contributions from Knowledge-Intensive Business-Services (KIBS) multinationals and their respective comparison with manufacturing investments. Using a panel dataset comprising 38 developing countries (2001-2010), fixed-effects regressions are applied according to a traditional endogenous growth model. Empirical findings underscore the relevance of KIBS MNCs' contributions to host innovation systems in developing countries. These impacts broadly surmount those of manufacturing FDI and they are particularly significant for: (a) value added in services; (b) value added in manufacturing; (c) aggregate export capacity; and (d) international (United States Patent and Trademark Office[USPTO]) patenting activity.

KIBS; national innovation systems; foreign direct investment; multinational corporations


Introduction

The usual assumption supporting the role played by multinational corporations (MNCs) in accelerating the pace of innovation and technological change is that host nations can benefit from foreign direct investments (FDI) through the generation and diffusion of technological and knowledge spillovers (Alfaro, Chanda, Kalemli-Ozcan,& Sayek, 2004Alfaro, L., Chanda, A., Kalemli-Ozcan, S., & Sayek, S. (2004). FDI and economic growth: the role of local financial markets. Journal of International Economics, 64(1), 89-112. doi: 10.1016/s0022-1996(03)00081-3
https://doi.org/10.1016/s0022-1996(03)00...
). This perspective puts multinational companies as significant agents in the evolutionary dynamics of National Innovation Systems (NISs), not only because of their position of endogenous growth agents(De Mello, 1997De Mello, L. (1997). Foreign direct investment in developing countries and growth: a selective survey. Journal of Development Studies, 34(1), 1-34. doi: 10.1080/00220389708422501
https://doi.org/10.1080/0022038970842250...
; Girma, 2005Girma, S. (2005). Absorptive capacity and productivity spillovers from FDI: a threshold regression analysis. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 67(3), 281-306.doi: 10.1111/j.1468-0084.2005.00120.x
https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0084.2005...
; Mayer-Foulkes & Nunnenkamp, 2009Mayer-Foulkes, D., & Nunnenkamp, P. (2009). Do multinational enterprises contribute to convergence or divergence? A disaggregated analysis of US FDI. Review of Development Economics, 13(2), 304-318. doi: 10.1111/j.1467-9361.2009.00510.x
https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9361.2009...
), but also because of their capacity of becoming embedded in different contexts, performing a bridging function across economic environments (Bruhn & Calegario, 2014Bruhn, N., & Calegario, C. (2014). Productivity spillovers from foreign direct investment in the Brazilian processing industry. Brazilian Administration Review, 11(1), 22-46. Retrieved from http://www.scielo.br/pdf/bar/v11n1/v11n1a03.pdf. doi: 10.1590/s1807-76922014000100003
//www.scielo.br/pdf/bar/v11n1/v11n1a03.p...
; Ghoshal & Bartlett, 1990Ghoshal, S., & Bartlett, C.A. (1990). The multinational corporation as an interorganizational network. Academy of Management Review, 15(4), 603-625. doi: 10.5465/amr.1990.4310825
https://doi.org/10.5465/amr.1990.4310825...
).

However, most analytical frameworks are grounded on suppositions and data oriented towards manufacturing sectors (Ramasamy & Yeung, 2010Ramasamy, B., & Yeung, M. (2010). The determinants of foreign direct investment in services. The World Economy, 33(4), 573-596. doi: 10.1111/j.1467-9701.2009.01256.x
https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9701.2009...
), meaning that conclusions on the importance of multinationals to host markets are strongly related to statistical models and case studies focused on manufacturing agents. Although important, such analyses often ignore data and phenomena involving service industries, especially for countries that lie outside the group of developed nations (Massini & Miozzo, 2012Massini, S., & Miozzo, M. (2012). Outsourcing and offshoring of business services: challenges to theory, management and geography of innovation. Regional Studies, 46(9), 1219-1242. doi: 10.1080/00343404.2010.509128
https://doi.org/10.1080/00343404.2010.50...
). Hence, traditional models are bound to have diminishing relevance, as service activities respond for most of economic activity worldwide and also for an increasing share of FDI (Riedl, 2010Riedl, A. (2010). Location factors of FDI and the growing services economy: evidence from transition countries. Economics of Transition, 18(4), 741-761. doi: 10.1111/j.1468-0351.2010.00391.x
https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0351.2010...
).

Nonetheless, services' subsectors are extremely heterogeneous in their own nature (Miles, 2004Miles, I. (2004). Innovation in services. In J. Fagerberg, D. C. Mowery,& R. R. Nelson (Eds.), The Oxford handbook of innovation(Chap. 5, pp. 433-458). New York: Oxford University Press; Miozzo, Lehrer, DeFillippi, Grimshaw,& Ordanini, 2010Miozzo, M., Lehrer, M., DeFillippi, R., Grimshaw, D., & Ordanini, A. (2010). Economies of scope through multi-unit skill systems: the organization of large design firms. British Journal of Management, 23(2), 145-164. doi: 10.1111/j.1467-8551.2010.00699.x
https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-8551.2010...
). In order to overcome this issue, narrowing down the operational definition of services to subsets of activities that share common characteristics becomes necessary. In the realm of innovation studies, a group that has rendered robust and interesting insights is that of Knowledge-Intensive Business Services (KIBS). KIBS represent a core feature of knowledge-based economies, since they leverage systemic capabilities by promoting the generation of innovative networks between agents, as well as contributing to produce, diffuse, supply and absorb knowledge across industries (He & Wong, 2009He, Z.,& Wong, P. (2009). Knowledge interaction with manufacturing clients and innovation of knowledge-intensive business services firms. Innovation: Management, Policy & Practice, 11(3), 264-278. doi: 10.5172/impp.11.3.264
https://doi.org/10.5172/impp.11.3.264...
; Miles, 2004Miles, I. (2004). Innovation in services. In J. Fagerberg, D. C. Mowery,& R. R. Nelson (Eds.), The Oxford handbook of innovation(Chap. 5, pp. 433-458). New York: Oxford University Press; Simmie & Strambach, 2006Simmie, J., & Strambach, S. (2006). The contribution of KIBS to innovation in cities: an evolutionary and institutional perspective. Journal of Knowledge Management, 10(5), 26-40. doi: 10.1108/13673270610691152
https://doi.org/10.1108/1367327061069115...
). These idiosyncrasies lead us to question what are the effective impacts of KIBS' FDI on the output dynamics of developing countries' innovation systems? And how do they compare with potential contributions related to manufacturing FDI?

The goal of this research is to investigate the impacts of inward FDI on aggregate outcomes of NISs, taking into account potential contributions from KIBS' multinationals and their respective comparison with manufacturing investments. Focus is given to the case of developing countries (classified as middle-income nations - see section Analytical Framework for a thorough conceptualization), since there is a widespread claim that positive externalities arising from FDI are particularly relevant for these nations, given their situation of innovative laggards (Hansen & Rand, 2006Hansen, H., & Rand, J. (2006). On the causal links between FDI and growth in developing countries. The World Economy, 29(1), 21-41. doi: 10.1111/j.1467-9701.2006.00756.x
https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9701.2006...
; Waldkirch, 2011Waldkirch, A. (2011). Comparative advantage FDI? A host country perspective. Review of World Economics, 147(3), 485-505. doi: 10.1007/s10290-011-0096-8
https://doi.org/10.1007/s10290-011-0096-...
). Also, these economies are playing an increasingly relevant role in FDI attraction flows (Álvarez & Marín, 2010Álvarez, I., & Marín, R. (2010). Entry modes and national systems of innovation. Journal of International Management, 16(4), 340-353. doi: 10.1016/j.intman.2010.09.005
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.intman.2010.09...
), particularly for KIBS (Yang & Yan, 2010Yang, W., & Yan, M. (2010). The policy to promote the innovative development of knowledge-intensive business services. International Journal of Business and Management, 5(11), 190-194. doi: 10.5539/ijbm.v5n11p190
https://doi.org/10.5539/ijbm.v5n11p190...
). Lastly, and perhaps more importantly, globalization issues related to developing countries' NISs are meagerly addressed in scientific literature (Teixeira, 2013Teixeira, A. (2013). Evolution, roots and influence of the literature on National Systems of Innovation: a bibliometric account. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 38(1), 181-214. doi: 10.1093/cje/bet022
https://doi.org/10.1093/cje/bet022...
), resulting in a lack of theoretical and empirical knowledge for the specificities of this group of nations. This is particularly relevant in a context in which the analysis of FDI impacts upon developing countries differs from that of industrialized economies as a function of distinct distances to the technological frontier (Wooster & Diebel, 2010Wooster, R., & Diebel, D. (2010). Productivity spillovers from foreign direct investment in developing countries: a meta-regression analysis. Review of Development Economics, 14(3), 640-655. doi: 10.1111/j.1467-9361.2010.00579.x
https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9361.2010...
).

To accomplish this objective, an unbalanced panel dataset comprising information for 38 developing countries throughout the period 2001-2010 was created. Relationships between KIBS' FDI were established with a set of eight economic output indicators that represent core dimensions of innovation systems. The simultaneous use of a heterodox set of output indicators stands for a broader comprehension of the complex dynamics involving National Innovation Systems. This approach also adds to existing literature that addresses FDI impacts based on a limited perspective of economic output (Wooster & Diebel, 2010Wooster, R., & Diebel, D. (2010). Productivity spillovers from foreign direct investment in developing countries: a meta-regression analysis. Review of Development Economics, 14(3), 640-655. doi: 10.1111/j.1467-9361.2010.00579.x
https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9361.2010...
).

Estimations were undertaken via fixed-effects methods, using regression models that follow the traditional endogenous growth rationale via an augmented production function. The use of a sound theoretical framework is an important feature of this analysis, as it provides robustness to this empirical exercise (a concern that is often overlooked in FDI-related studies, see Wooster & Diebel, 2010Wooster, R., & Diebel, D. (2010). Productivity spillovers from foreign direct investment in developing countries: a meta-regression analysis. Review of Development Economics, 14(3), 640-655. doi: 10.1111/j.1467-9361.2010.00579.x
https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9361.2010...
). Moreover, the novelty of this assessment lies in dealing with relationships between KIBS' multinationals and innovation environments from a quantitative viewpoint in the context of developing countries, a field that has received scant scientific treatment (Doloreux & Shearmur, 2013Doloreux, D., & Shearmur, R. (2013). Innovation strategies: are knowledge-intensive business services just another source of information? Industry and Innovation, 20(8), 719-738. doi: 10.1080/13662716.2013.856623
https://doi.org/10.1080/13662716.2013.85...
; Miozzo, Yamin,& Ghauri, 2012Miozzo, M., Yamin, M., & Ghauri, P. (2012). Strategy and structure of service multinationals and their impact on linkages with local firms. The Service Industries Journal, 32(7), 1171-1191. doi: 10.1080/02642069.2012.662492
https://doi.org/10.1080/02642069.2012.66...
).

After this introductory outlook, second section presents contributions from FDI-related literature regarding its connections with National Innovation Systems. Third section depicts the characteristics of KIBS, their impacts on aggregate innovative capabilities and aspects concerning impacts arising from FDI. Fourth section is dedicated to outlining the analytical framework that guides the empirical exercise carried out in this research. Information on the sample and estimation procedures is offered in fifth section. Sixth section explores results of the statistical exercise and seventh section concludes with final remarks, avenues for future research and limitations of this assessment.

Foreign Direct Investments in the Context of National Innovation Systems

A first step in this literature review consists in delimiting what National Innovation Systemsrefers to. While there is significant flexibility on the applications and operational characteristics of this analytical toolbox, for the purposes of this research the National Innovation System concept is in accordance with the Aalborg version (see Lundvall, Johnson, Andersen, & Dalum, 2002Lundvall, B., Johnson, B., Andersen, E., & Dalum, B. (2002). National systems of production, innovation and competence building. Research Policy, 31(2), 213-231. doi: 10.1016/s0048-7333(01)00137-8
https://doi.org/10.1016/s0048-7333(01)00...
, and Teixeira, 2013Teixeira, A. (2013). Evolution, roots and influence of the literature on National Systems of Innovation: a bibliometric account. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 38(1), 181-214. doi: 10.1093/cje/bet022
https://doi.org/10.1093/cje/bet022...
, for thorough reviews on the subject). Thus, the idea of NIS is assessed as a complex structure of elements and relationships contributing to innovation and competence building. Amongst agents involved in this framework are not only institutional settings, but also universities and, most importantly, firms and their respective sets of interorganizational linkages. In other words, reference to the concept of NIS functions as a neo-Schumpeterian interpretation of productive systems, encompassing issues related to business dynamics.

In its turn, Foreign Direct Investments constitute a particular sort of international capital flows that is strictly related to productive activities, usually impersonated by multinational corporations. Moreover, FDI has a close relationship with National Innovation Systems, representing a core vector of transnational integration (Guimón, 2009Guimón, J. (2009). Government strategies to attract R& D intensive FDI. The Journal of Technology Transfer, 34(4), 364-379. doi: 10.1007/s10961-008-9091-1
https://doi.org/10.1007/s10961-008-9091-...
). This contribution is believed to be fundamentally related to knowledge spillovers (Alfaro et al., 2004Alfaro, L., Chanda, A., Kalemli-Ozcan, S., & Sayek, S. (2004). FDI and economic growth: the role of local financial markets. Journal of International Economics, 64(1), 89-112. doi: 10.1016/s0022-1996(03)00081-3
https://doi.org/10.1016/s0022-1996(03)00...
). Potential causes for this knowledge leak are expected to be related to forward and backward linkages with other firms (learning processes with clients and suppliers), generation of networks, and inter-firm mobility of human resources.

Hence, in the context of National Innovation Systems, knowledge spillovers are the feature of main interest regarding FDI flows, since they are likely to generate long-run structural benefits for host countries' economic dynamics through the promotion of enduring systemic shifts on the productive structure (Hansen & Rand, 2006Hansen, H., & Rand, J. (2006). On the causal links between FDI and growth in developing countries. The World Economy, 29(1), 21-41. doi: 10.1111/j.1467-9701.2006.00756.x
https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9701.2006...
; Waldkirch, 2011Waldkirch, A. (2011). Comparative advantage FDI? A host country perspective. Review of World Economics, 147(3), 485-505. doi: 10.1007/s10290-011-0096-8
https://doi.org/10.1007/s10290-011-0096-...
). As a consequence of these theoretical postulations, FDI attraction initiatives currently represent a policy trend in developing nations (Waldkirch, 2011Waldkirch, A. (2011). Comparative advantage FDI? A host country perspective. Review of World Economics, 147(3), 485-505. doi: 10.1007/s10290-011-0096-8
https://doi.org/10.1007/s10290-011-0096-...
).

Contributions of literature regarding FDI and its relationships with developing countries' innovation systems suggest that positive externalities from MNCs presence in relatively laggard nations can function as a vector of knowledge diffusion. Nonetheless, it should be noticed that individual firms represent a rather restricted unit within macroeconomic environments. For this reason, FDI should be understood as a potential source for marginal impacts upon overall capabilities within national boundaries (as proposed by De Mello, 1997De Mello, L. (1997). Foreign direct investment in developing countries and growth: a selective survey. Journal of Development Studies, 34(1), 1-34. doi: 10.1080/00220389708422501
https://doi.org/10.1080/0022038970842250...
). In a similar vein, it is argued that the marginality of FDI contribution to developing countries' innovation systems can also be a function of companies' location strategies in these markets, mostly oriented towards an asset-exploitingrationale that involves low levels of resource commitment from investors (Miozzo et al., 2012Miozzo, M., Yamin, M., & Ghauri, P. (2012). Strategy and structure of service multinationals and their impact on linkages with local firms. The Service Industries Journal, 32(7), 1171-1191. doi: 10.1080/02642069.2012.662492
https://doi.org/10.1080/02642069.2012.66...
; Narula & Dunning, 2010Narula, R., & Dunning, J. H. (2010). Multinational enterprises, development and globalization: some clarifications and a research agenda. Oxford Development Studies, 38(3), 263-287. doi: 10.1080/13600818.2010.505684
https://doi.org/10.1080/13600818.2010.50...
), and also caused by weakness in terms of absorptive capacities in indigenous agents (Wooster & Diebel, 2010Wooster, R., & Diebel, D. (2010). Productivity spillovers from foreign direct investment in developing countries: a meta-regression analysis. Review of Development Economics, 14(3), 640-655. doi: 10.1111/j.1467-9361.2010.00579.x
https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9361.2010...
), which may lead to insignificant contributions to host environments. However, much of the background addressed in this section makes reference to a manufacturing-orientedanalytical framework. The next section explores some key aspects of knowledge-intensive business services in order to further understand the process of FDI interaction with NISs.

Knowledge-Intensive Business Services

Hertog (2000)Hertog, P. D. (2000). Knowledge-intensive business services as co-producers of innovation. International Journal of Innovation Management, 4(4), 491-528. doi: 10.1142/s136391960000024x
https://doi.org/10.1142/s136391960000024...
defines knowledge-intensive business services (KIBS) as firms that "rely heavily on professional knowledge, i.e., knowledge or expertise related to a specific (technical) discipline or (technical) functional-domain to supply intermediate products and services that are knowledge based" (p. 505). Similarly, Miles et al. (1995)Miles, I., Kastrinos, N., Flanagan, K., Bilderbeek, R., Hertog, P., Huntink, W., & Bouman, M. (1995). Knowledge-intensive business services: their role as users, carriers and sources of innovation[Report].EC DG XIII Sprint EIMS Programme, Luxembourg. Retrieved from https://research.mbs.ac.uk/INNOVATION/Portals /0/docs/ KIBSEIMS1995shortreport.pdf
research.mbs.ac.uk/INNOVATION/Portals /0...
characterize KIBS as "services that involve economic activities which are intended to result in the creation, accumulation, or dissemination of knowledge" (p. 18). These concepts place KIBS in an influential position within the broad environment of National Innovation Systems, where they represent a core feature of the knowledge-based economy by promoting stronger ties and generating innovative networks between agents (He & Wong, 2009He, Z.,& Wong, P. (2009). Knowledge interaction with manufacturing clients and innovation of knowledge-intensive business services firms. Innovation: Management, Policy & Practice, 11(3), 264-278. doi: 10.5172/impp.11.3.264
https://doi.org/10.5172/impp.11.3.264...
; Simmie & Strambach, 2006Simmie, J., & Strambach, S. (2006). The contribution of KIBS to innovation in cities: an evolutionary and institutional perspective. Journal of Knowledge Management, 10(5), 26-40. doi: 10.1108/13673270610691152
https://doi.org/10.1108/1367327061069115...
).

Nonetheless, services have long been neglected as relevant agents of innovation, given that scientific approaches have historically been biased towards technological, R& D-oriented forms of innovation (Miozzo et al., 2010Miozzo, M., Lehrer, M., DeFillippi, R., Grimshaw, D., & Ordanini, A. (2010). Economies of scope through multi-unit skill systems: the organization of large design firms. British Journal of Management, 23(2), 145-164. doi: 10.1111/j.1467-8551.2010.00699.x
https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-8551.2010...
). Increasing concerns with the validity of linear ways of thinking about the innovative process represent a call to go beyond this traditional, shallow view of economic evolution. Dedicated research must also tackle softer forms of innovation generation and facilitation, as well as the development of forward and backward linkages among organizations (Markusen, Rutherford,& Tarr, 2005Markusen, J., Rutherford, T. F., & Tarr, D. (2005). Trade and direct investment in producer services and the domestic market for expertise. Canadian Journal of Economics, 38(3), 758-773. doi: 10.1111/j.0008-4085.2005.00301.x
https://doi.org/10.1111/j.0008-4085.2005...
).

The role of KIBS within National Innovation Systems

The growing interconnection between firms in general and KIBS (concerning the generation of innovative products and processes) puts such services in a critical role for innovation systems (Miles, 2008Miles, I. (2008). Patterns of innovation in service industries. IBM Systems Journal, 47(1), 115-128. doi: 10.1147/sj.471.0115
https://doi.org/10.1147/sj.471.0115...
). Operationally, the role of KIBS is one of bridging knowledge generation and diffusion throughout Innovation Systems, functioning as agents of the knowledge infrastructure, thus complementing the role played by public institutions in brokering innovation (Hertog, 2000Hertog, P. D. (2000). Knowledge-intensive business services as co-producers of innovation. International Journal of Innovation Management, 4(4), 491-528. doi: 10.1142/s136391960000024x
https://doi.org/10.1142/s136391960000024...
; Koch & Stahlecker, 2006Koch, A., & Stahlecker, T. (2006). Regional innovation systems and the foundation of knowledge intensive business services: a comparative study in Bremen, Munich, and Stuttgart, Germany. European Planning Studies, 14(2), 123-145. doi: 10.1080/09654310500417830
https://doi.org/10.1080/0965431050041783...
; Mas-Verdú, Wensley, Alba,& Álvarez-Coque, 2011Mas-Verdú, F., Wensley, A. K. P., Alba, M. F., & Álvarez-Coque, J. M. G. (2011). How much does KIBS contribute to the generation and diffusion of innovation? Service Business, 5(3), 195-212. doi: 10.1007/s11628-011-0110-1
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11628-011-0110-...
; Simmie & Strambach, 2006Simmie, J., & Strambach, S. (2006). The contribution of KIBS to innovation in cities: an evolutionary and institutional perspective. Journal of Knowledge Management, 10(5), 26-40. doi: 10.1108/13673270610691152
https://doi.org/10.1108/1367327061069115...
; Yang & Yan, 2010Yang, W., & Yan, M. (2010). The policy to promote the innovative development of knowledge-intensive business services. International Journal of Business and Management, 5(11), 190-194. doi: 10.5539/ijbm.v5n11p190
https://doi.org/10.5539/ijbm.v5n11p190...
). From this perspective, KIBS' interaction with innovation systems can take place in three conceptual forms (Hertog, 2000Hertog, P. D. (2000). Knowledge-intensive business services as co-producers of innovation. International Journal of Innovation Management, 4(4), 491-528. doi: 10.1142/s136391960000024x
https://doi.org/10.1142/s136391960000024...
):

  1. 1

    Innovation Carriers: this involves knowledge transfer across firms and/or geographic boundaries, enabling agents to enhance their innovative potential

  2. 2

    Knowledge Facilitators: introduction of new or improved processes, or sub-contracting of specific knowledge-intensive tasks (R& D, IT management, marketing), as well as continuous support for clients

  3. 3

    Innovation Sources: de facto co-production of innovation, representing a closer connection between KIBS and client firms than observed in the conceptual forms presented above

Although these three conceptual forms stand for possibilities of interaction between KIBS' and innovation systems, the role of these firms as Innovation Sources entails a higher potential of impacts upon aggregate outcomes in innovation systems. This is because of the closer coordination between agents, generating joint innovation (instead of merely diffusing it) and promoting evolution of absorptive capacities in clients and suppliers. This seems a reasonable argument supporting the idea that such a conceptual form of KIBS' activities lies at the core of their embeddedness within NISs.

Nonetheless, in the case of developing economies, the importance of knowledge diffusion (not its creation per se) can also represent a source of significant aggregate advances in the economic and managerial realms and should not be underestimated. Hence, whenever potential contributions from KIBS to outcomes of developing countries' innovation systems are addressed, no practical distinction is made as to what mode of innovation takes place (I believe this issue lies beyond the scope of this research and it deserves attention from future studies in the field)

Foreign direct investment in the context of KIBS

The theoretical context of KIBS poses distinct dynamics for its contributions to socioeconomic environments; more than is usually assumed in business theory oriented towards manufacturing agents. KIBS are active participants in other agents' strategies and operations, shifting the customary definition of firms' limits to more open and collaborative configurations (Miozzo & Grimshaw, 2005Miozzo, M., & Grimshaw, D. (2005). Modularity and innovation in knowledge-intensive business services: IT outsourcing in Germany and the UK. Research Policy, 34(9), 1419-1439. doi: 10.1016/j.respol.2005.06.005
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2005.06...
). In this case, access to knowledge through cooperation and networking becomes a determinant aspect regarding the innovative activity in KIBS (Yang & Yan, 2010Yang, W., & Yan, M. (2010). The policy to promote the innovative development of knowledge-intensive business services. International Journal of Business and Management, 5(11), 190-194. doi: 10.5539/ijbm.v5n11p190
https://doi.org/10.5539/ijbm.v5n11p190...
). As a result, co-creation or co-production of knowledge between KIBS and its clients emerge as fundamental concepts in the analysis of their respective innovative behavior (Hertog, 2000Hertog, P. D. (2000). Knowledge-intensive business services as co-producers of innovation. International Journal of Innovation Management, 4(4), 491-528. doi: 10.1142/s136391960000024x
https://doi.org/10.1142/s136391960000024...
; Miozzo et al., 2010Miozzo, M., Lehrer, M., DeFillippi, R., Grimshaw, D., & Ordanini, A. (2010). Economies of scope through multi-unit skill systems: the organization of large design firms. British Journal of Management, 23(2), 145-164. doi: 10.1111/j.1467-8551.2010.00699.x
https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-8551.2010...
).

Thus, the very nature of KIBS' FDI is inherently different from that of manufacturing industries. Contrary to the usual rationale of technological spillovers (based on upstream, or backward, interactions with suppliers and the like), KIBS' impacts upon innovation systems rely heavily on their forward connections with clients (Miozzo et al., 2010Miozzo, M., Lehrer, M., DeFillippi, R., Grimshaw, D., & Ordanini, A. (2010). Economies of scope through multi-unit skill systems: the organization of large design firms. British Journal of Management, 23(2), 145-164. doi: 10.1111/j.1467-8551.2010.00699.x
https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-8551.2010...
). KIBS are then likely to promote productivity gains that are not restricted to any particular sector of the economy, contributing to the overall competitiveness of organizations (Golub, 2009Golub, S.S. (2009). Openness to foreign direct investment in services: an international comparative analysis. The World Economy, 32(8), 1245-1268. doi: 10.1111/j.1467-9701.2009.01201.x
https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9701.2009...
).

Nonetheless, the majority of KIBS' interactions with other firms depend on a significant level of tacitness regarding knowledge flows, thus hampering codification and transmission of these assets over long distances. Accordingly, such processes put spatial proximity as a fundamental attribute for successful interactions between KIBS and their clients (Koch & Stahlecker, 2006Koch, A., & Stahlecker, T. (2006). Regional innovation systems and the foundation of knowledge intensive business services: a comparative study in Bremen, Munich, and Stuttgart, Germany. European Planning Studies, 14(2), 123-145. doi: 10.1080/09654310500417830
https://doi.org/10.1080/0965431050041783...
). These characteristics of KIBS make them highly inclined to internationalize their activities via their physical presence abroad (Miozzo & Soete, 2001Miozzo, M., & Soete, L. (2001). Internationalization of services: a technological perspective. Technological Forecasting and Social Change, 67(2/3), 159-185. doi: 10.1016/s0040-1625(00)00091-3
https://doi.org/10.1016/s0040-1625(00)00...
; Yang & Yan, 2010Yang, W., & Yan, M. (2010). The policy to promote the innovative development of knowledge-intensive business services. International Journal of Business and Management, 5(11), 190-194. doi: 10.5539/ijbm.v5n11p190
https://doi.org/10.5539/ijbm.v5n11p190...
).

As is true for multinational companies in general (see section Foreign Direct Investments in the Context of National Innovation Systems), the spatial allocation of these particular service providers can have positive impacts on the dynamics of knowledge flows across economic systems. In the case of developing nations, the attraction of KIBS' FDI can play a beneficial role to the aggregate capabilities of host innovation systems, generating a powerful lever for future development (Miozzo & Soete, 2001Miozzo, M., & Soete, L. (2001). Internationalization of services: a technological perspective. Technological Forecasting and Social Change, 67(2/3), 159-185. doi: 10.1016/s0040-1625(00)00091-3
https://doi.org/10.1016/s0040-1625(00)00...
). Further discussions regarding these matters and their potential implications are offered in the following section.

Analytical Framework

This section offers an integrative perspective between expected relationships amongst National Innovation Systems in developing countries and FDI flows with particular interest on contributions arising from KIBS. Taking into account the core features of knowledge-intensive business services, the conceptual rationale that applies to the interactions involving these firms and the local innovative environment seem somewhat different from the one concerning manufacturing-oriented frameworks.

As suggested by literature presented in section Foreign Direct Investments in the Context of National Innovation Systems, impacts from manufacturing FDI upon NISs are strongly associated with economic externalities (technology and knowledge spillovers). Nonetheless, the role played by KIBS' firms as innovation brokers, and co-producers, suggests a more active function within the dynamics of NISs (see section Knowledge-Intensive Business Services). Hence, the foundation of this analytical framework relies on the proposition that KIBS' FDI have positive impacts on aggregate outcomes of developing countries' innovation systems that surmount contributions from manufacturing FDI.

This approach is in line with a softercomprehension of existing interactions amongst agents embedded in developing countries' NISs. This is in line with the idea that research in the field of innovation systems must go beyond a narrow focus based solely on science-based activities and tangible outputs, incorporating broader aspects of competence building in socioeconomic environments (Lundvallet al., 2002Lundvall, B., Johnson, B., Andersen, E., & Dalum, B. (2002). National systems of production, innovation and competence building. Research Policy, 31(2), 213-231. doi: 10.1016/s0048-7333(01)00137-8
https://doi.org/10.1016/s0048-7333(01)00...
).

With the intention of converting the proposition that impacts from KIBS' FDI are of a larger magnitude than those originated from manufacturing FDI (see sections The Role of KIBS within National Innovation Systems and Foreign Direct Investment in the Context of KIBS) into an operational research design, I have used the theoretical structure of an augmented production function structured in an endogenous growth fashion. This procedure is not particularly novel and it follows the basic composition outlined in Equation 1 (see De Mello, 1997):

Where Y is an indicator of economic output, A represents the residual, also referred to as Total Factor Productivity (TFP), K stands for physical capital, L is labor, FDI brings information for foreign direct investment as an element of growth in Y, and Ω is a representation of ancillary variables.

Research variables

In order to translate this rationale into an operational assessment of developing countries' innovation systems, the concept of aggregate outcomes deserves some further exploration. The production function outlined in Equation 1 is traditionally estimated via indicators of aggregate economic production as a proxy for Y (such as GDP or GNI). Nonetheless, economic growth per se is not a direct output indicator of innovation systems, but rather a dimension that is affected by overall innovative performance. Additionally, the relationship between economic spillovers and overall output happens via shocks in mediating activities, suggesting that traditional estimations found in literature may contain a significant amount of noise in statistical relationships.

Aiming at developing a comprehensive view of the impacts of KIBS' inward FDI on developing countries' NISs, the approach used in this research builds upon a more flexible perspective of economic output (see Table 1). This allows an investigation of FDI effects on: (a)Intellectual property generation: trademark applications at the national level; patents filed at the United States Patent and Trademark Office (USPTO); (b)Intellectual property revenues: international flows of royalty receipts (or charges for the use of intellectual property); (c)Productivity: value added in manufacturing and service industries; labor productivity; and (d)Trade capabilities: overall export flows; export flows in high-technology (R& D intensive) industries.

Table 1
Operational Indicators of the Analytical Framework - Dependent Variables

This set of indicators represents an adaptation of indicators used by the European Commission in the Innovation Union Scoreboard (see European Commission, 2014European Commission. (2014). Innovation union scoreboard 2014. Retrieved from http://ec.europa.eu/enterprise/policies/innovation/files/ius/ius-2014_en.pdf
ec.europa.eu/enterprise/policies/innovat...
), a document of reference in the field of innovation output assessment. Further aspects were gathered from Archibugi, Denni and Filipetti (2009)Archibugi, D., Denni, M., & Filippetti, A. (2009). The technological capabilities of nations: the state of the art of synthetic indicators. Technological Forecasting and Social Change, 76(7), 917-931. doi: 10.1016/j.techfore.2009.01.002
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.techfore.2009....
, thus providing a comprehensive view on indicators of interest.

Many choices were made to define this particular group of indicators of aggregate outcomes in National Innovation Systems, leaving further dimensions of potential interest aside. Adaptations of indicators mainly involved not limiting value-added indicators (in Services and in Manufacturing industries) to high-tech sectors because of the economic composition of developing countries, where medium-tech (and even low-tech) activities may provide a better grasp on the dynamics of NISs. Also, from an operational perspective, these data are not consistently available for country-level analyses when such decomposition is intended. The same logic guided the inclusion of aggregate exports, though in this case a comparison with the specific behavior of high-tech goods was available.

In turn, the specification of predictors follows the rationale of the augmented production depicted in Equation 1; i.e., making FDI an endogenous parameter in the dynamics of output evolution in National Innovation Systems (see Table 2). POP stands for a proxy regarding labor force within countries, and CAPFORM is an indicator of capital formation (public and private). ΔGDP (GDPGRT) is introduced as an ancillary variable in statistical estimations as a proxy for macroeconomic stability over time. GERD (Gross Expenditure in R& D) is also included as an ancillary term to provide a control for indigenous innovative efforts.

Table 2
Operational Predictors of the Analytical Framework (Equation 1)

Bearing in mind the objective of verifying differential contributions between inward FDI in KIBS (a list of KIBS' subsectors can be found in Appendix A Appendix A KIBS Sectors Used in the Analysis ) and in manufacturing, I have decomposed FDI into two vectors: FDIKIBS and FDIMAN. This procedure allows comparing investments' contributions to host economies according to their sectoral characteristics, an aspect that has received scarce attention in literature (Narula & Dunning, 2010Narula, R., & Dunning, J. H. (2010). Multinational enterprises, development and globalization: some clarifications and a research agenda. Oxford Development Studies, 38(3), 263-287. doi: 10.1080/13600818.2010.505684
https://doi.org/10.1080/13600818.2010.50...
). This data is provided by the International Trade Centre (ITC) and comprises information from The United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD),The United Nations International Trade Statistics Database(COMTRADE), among other primary sources. Industrial definitions are based on ISIC (Revision 3) nomenclature. A core limitation of this source is related to the combination of data gathered from several sources and grouped in the above mentioned industrial classification, which can generate cases of inaccurate categorization. Consequently, although the dataset available in ITC provides a detailed and comprehensive amount of information on FDI flows at the industrial level, overall results should be regarded as approximations of the real picture (a common hindrance faced by analyses that deal with aggregate data).

Methodological Remarks: Sample and Estimation Procedures

The empirical analysis carried out in this research comprises information for 38 developing countries (see Appendix B Appendix B List of Developing Countries Included in the Panel Dataset for the list of countries) for the period 2001-2010. Due to missing data, the resulting dataset represents an unbalanced panel. The definition of countries as developing follows the classification provided by the World Bank in 2012 based on levels of income (World Bank, 2015World Bank. (2015). World Bank list of economies. Retrieved from http://siteresources.worldbank.org/DATASTATISTICS/Resources/CLASS.XLS
siteresources.worldbank.org/DATASTATISTI...
). To avoid further heterogeneity in the sample, only countries classified in the middle-income group were included (hence, low-income countries were not assessed). Although this classification can suffer modifications over time, these shifts are not representative of major structural changes in the short-run, indicating solely slight increases/decreases in per capita income.

Furthermore, for operational reasons, those countries that did not have available information on FDI flows and on the set of dependent variables throughout the period under scrutiny were suppressed from the sample. The lack of data for the analytical variables does not come as a surprise, as the research structure involves detailed information which is often scarce for developing nations (sectoral-level FDI for instance). Even though it can be claimed that some regions are over-represented in comparison to others, I do not believe that this can cause significant shortcomings in the analysis. First, because the intention is to develop an aggregate assessment of developing countries, recognizing that this is a heterogeneous group of nations (Álvarez & Marín, 2010Álvarez, I., & Marín, R. (2010). Entry modes and national systems of innovation. Journal of International Management, 16(4), 340-353. doi: 10.1016/j.intman.2010.09.005
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.intman.2010.09...
). Second, the statistical method used is bound to deal with this heterogeneity adequately (see remarks of fixed-effects regressions below).

For empirical estimations, FDI variables (FDIKIBS and FDIMAN) are approached with a 1-year lag (t-1), since investment impacts are not expected to yield structural effects upon economic systems in a simultaneous manner. Nonetheless, as FDI effects on host countries' economic growth are likely to take place within the year of initial investment (Aleksynska, Gaisford,& Kerr, 2003Aleksynska, M., Gaisford, J., & Kerr, W. (2003). Foreign direct investment and growth in transition economies [Working Paper nº 7668]. Munich Personal RePEc Archive. Retrieved from http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/7668/
mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/7668/...
), a 1-year lag is justifiable for empirical tests. To sum up these operational aspects of the method, the functional form of the production function applied in this research takes the following form (all variables are assessed via their natural logarithms for statistical efficiency purposes, except for GERD and GDPGRT which represent percentage variations):

Where Y represents each of the eight dependent dimensions of this research, α is the constant of the model, βk stands for each parameter of the kth independent variable, t is an identifier of each time-period, αi represents the time-invariant error term, and εit is the observation-specific error term (it must be noticed that the error term is decomposed into two components, thus accounting for country-specific heterogeneity). The estimation method is that of fixed-effects for panel data. The use of this particular strategy represents a fundamental tool in the verification of FDI effects upon innovation systems' dynamics, since it allows consistent estimates of time-constant omitted variables upon dependent constructs (Wooldridge, 2000Wooldridge, J. (2000). Econometric analysis of cross section and panel data(2nd. ed.). Cambridge: The MIT Press.). This strategy satisfactorily deals with any potential problems caused by the diversity of country profiles included in this sample.

Empirical Evidence

Results from fixed-effects estimations for the eight selected dimensions of developing countries' innovation systems are reported in Table 3. Overall adequacy of models is supported by estimations' R2 statistics (see Table 3). Positive effects of KIBS' FDI regarding the sample under scrutiny seem to spread across four dimensions of developing countries' innovation systems. Besides expected contributions concentrated in SRVADD (Value added in services), KIBS' investment flows seem to positively affect MANADD (Value added in manufacturing industries), EXP (Total exports in goods and services), and PATS (Patents filed at the USPTO).

Table 3
Estimations of Fixed-Effects Regressions

Another relevant point is related to the comparison between the contributions from KIBS and manufacturing multinationals: KIBS' effects widely surmount those from their manufacturing counterparts. The absence of relevance in FDIMAN is not a particularly novel finding in assessments of manufacturing MNCs' contributions to host economic systems (see Aitken & Harrison, 1999Aitken, B., & Harrison, A. (1999). Do domestic firms benefit from foreign direct investment? Evidence from Venezuela. American Economic Review, 89(3), 605-618. doi: 10.1257/aer.89.3.605
https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.89.3.605...
; Bruhn & Calegario, 2014Bruhn, N., & Calegario, C. (2014). Productivity spillovers from foreign direct investment in the Brazilian processing industry. Brazilian Administration Review, 11(1), 22-46. Retrieved from http://www.scielo.br/pdf/bar/v11n1/v11n1a03.pdf. doi: 10.1590/s1807-76922014000100003
//www.scielo.br/pdf/bar/v11n1/v11n1a03.p...
; Wooster & Diebel, 2010Wooster, R., & Diebel, D. (2010). Productivity spillovers from foreign direct investment in developing countries: a meta-regression analysis. Review of Development Economics, 14(3), 640-655. doi: 10.1111/j.1467-9361.2010.00579.x
https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9361.2010...
), but this direct comparison with KIBS represents new information for specialized research. Hence, it is possible to confirm the theoretical proposition that guides this approach, adding novel and valuable evidence to the contributions of KIBS' FDI towards National Innovation Systems' performance. This exploratory finding also functions as a call for future empirical and theoretical research. The development of more detailed comparative assessments concerning differential levels of embeddedness/impacts arising from the presence of KIBS and manufacturing MNCs in host innovation systems represents a promising field of investigation.

Furthermore, it is interesting to verify that KIBS contributions to value added in manufacturing industries is positive and significant, while these effects do not hold for FDIMAN. This finding gives a strong hint as to the importance of KIBS forward linkages with clients as a source of beneficial shocks upon aggregate economic outcomes. Similar explanations are consistent with KIBS' FDI effects on export and patenting activities, suggesting the importance of further investigations on the nature of KIBS embeddedness within NISs.

I remind the reader about this differential characteristic of business services, while manufacturing firms rely heavily on the flow of unintended spillovers (externalities) to positively affect their surrounding environment. In a context of low or intermediate absorptive capacities (as is often the case for developing countries with weak innovation systems), such externalities have a hard time finding their way into indigenous players.

Notwithstanding these arguments, the usual indicators for absorptive capacity can be regarded as partially adequate (at best) or even irrelevant (at worst) for the specific case of services. Because of their very nature, KIBS function as knowledge facilitators, carriers and sources, thus also creating absorptive capabilities in their forward linkages (clients). For this reason, these firms are likely to find lower levels of friction in their processes of transferring innovative capabilities, in direct contrast with their manufacturing counterparts. Additionally, the level of rivalry among agents tends to be negligible in this dynamic context of knowledge exchange, reducing potential transaction costs and other barriers that may hamper host markets' appropriation of MNCs intangible assets.

Nonetheless, effects of this particular subset of service providers on aggregate outcomes are somewhat limited. In this sense, no significant relationship arises between the inflow of KIBS' FDI and improvements in aggregate labor productivity (PROD). The same situation holds for high-tech exporting capacity (EXPHT), trademark applications (TRM), and royalty charges (ROY). These aspects put emphasis on the marginality of MNCs' contributions to the overall picture of productive structures in developing countries. A meta-analytical research conducted by Wooster and Diebel (2010)Wooster, R., & Diebel, D. (2010). Productivity spillovers from foreign direct investment in developing countries: a meta-regression analysis. Review of Development Economics, 14(3), 640-655. doi: 10.1111/j.1467-9361.2010.00579.x
https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9361.2010...
on FDI impacts upon developing countries also reaches similar conclusions for investments in general. In this case, more research is needed and fundamental effects from foreign-owned KIBS and manufacturing enterprises should not be taken for granted.

Alternatively, there may be a timing issue in the estimated models. The 1-year lag suggested by Aleksynska, Gaisford and Kerr (2003)Aleksynska, M., Gaisford, J., & Kerr, W. (2003). Foreign direct investment and growth in transition economies [Working Paper nº 7668]. Munich Personal RePEc Archive. Retrieved from http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/7668/
mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/7668/...
is a possible source of instability in results, since structural shifts in large and complex innovation systems can take longer periods to become noticeable. Nonetheless, there is not an optimal form of establishing the timing of externalities; i.e., how long they take to occur (assuming they take place at all) and when these impacts can be translated into aggregate gains for the economic system.

This timing issue is a potential source of bias in econometric models with aggregate data, especially taking into account that MNCs tend to follow progressive processes in terms of knowledge creation in host markets (Guimón, 2009Guimón, J. (2009). Government strategies to attract R& D intensive FDI. The Journal of Technology Transfer, 34(4), 364-379. doi: 10.1007/s10961-008-9091-1
https://doi.org/10.1007/s10961-008-9091-...
). This situation poses methodological problems to establish optimal lags for the evaluation of FDI impacts upon recipient innovation systems, since they ought to be firm-specific. Future empirical assessments comprehending microeconomic data are essential for providing in-depth knowledge in this realm. A distinct explanation can be related to a low intensity in knowledge creation in the case of developed nations' MNCs that have subsidiaries in developing countries, hampering effective generation and dissemination of knowledge within host economies.

As per control variables, some comments are noteworthy. First of all, it is interesting to identify that for SRVADD as dependent dimension, GERD is not statistically significant, providing support to the perspective that innovation in services per se may not be efficiently measured by this traditional, tangible, indicator. In a similar vein, it is surprising that for the LnPATS model, GERD turns out to have significantly negative effects on outcomes. It can be argued that this result suggests the vulnerability of innovation policies that tackle systemic challenges via linear ways of thinking. Nonetheless, when looking at the remaining models, the traditional logic holds (except for the case of LnTRM). Hence, it cannot be ruled out that effects on patenting activity may be highly sensible to small variations, as developing countries' patents filed at the USPTO represent small numbers (maximum=919; minimum=0; mean=68,16; std. dv.=129,53).

Impacts from capital investments (CAPFORM) are consistently positive for six of the analytical dimensions, suggesting its importance in the economic evolution of developing countries' innovation systems. On the other hand, the predominantly negative role played by GDPGRT can be explained by the volatility of this indicator in relatively short-term evaluations, as consistent rates of growth in a given decade may not be strictly related to enduring capabilities in National Innovation Systems. In orthodox economic jargon, this is referred to as proximity to the steady state, where countries in more advanced conditions often achieve slower GDP growth.

Concluding Remarks

This investigation has addressed a fundamental cornerstone of laggard National Innovation Systems: their capacity of absorbing knowledge flows from foreign sources and catalyzing them into aggregate outcomes generated by local agents. Particular emphasis was given to the role of knowledge-intensive business services. It should be emphasized that while most literature draws conclusions from manufacturing companies, more attention should be given to the service sector, given its increasing relevance in the composition and dynamics of economies worldwide (and its growing connection with innovative activities).

Empirical results of this assessment have been tested according to the proposition that contributions of KIBS' FDI surmount those arising from the presence of manufacturing MNCs in developing countries. Main findings underscore the relevance of KIBS MNCs' contributions to host innovation systems in developing countries in four particular dimensions, namely: (a) value added in services; (b) value added in manufacturing activities; (c) aggregate export capacity; and (d) international (USPTO) patenting activity. Such findings are in accordance with lines of thought that stress the systemic character of KIBS, whereas its impacts seem to be related to different scopes of NISs in developing countries.

More interestingly, these effects broadly surmount those of manufacturing FDI, casting severe criticisms on the widespread use of this latter construct as a robust indicator of multinational corporations' integration within National Innovation Systems. These outcomes stress the differential framework in which FDI contributions arise in KIBS and in manufacturing industries. While the latter is strongly associated with the generation of unintentional externalities, the former is likely to play a bridging role for knowledge generation and diffusion in a fundamentally systemic manner - mainly through forward linkages. Hence, hindrances caused by lower levels of absorptive capacity in local firms are likely to be diminished in the dynamics of innovation related to KIBS' multinationals.

Regarding the contributions for innovation management research and practice, it should be noticed that the aggregate pool of indigenous companies in developing countries is bound to have deficiencies in terms of Ownership Advantages (Narula & Dunning, 2010Narula, R., & Dunning, J. H. (2010). Multinational enterprises, development and globalization: some clarifications and a research agenda. Oxford Development Studies, 38(3), 263-287. doi: 10.1080/13600818.2010.505684
https://doi.org/10.1080/13600818.2010.50...
), a feature that compromises the innovative capabilities and competitiveness of entire industries. There are several ways out of this trap, and one of them has been traditionally related to the activity of multinational corporations. Results of this research provide an exploratory perspective that suggests that this is likely to be the case in the presence of KIBS. A theoretical implication of this finding for developing countries concerns the importance of knowledge diffusion, a central feature of KIBS, in laggard innovation systems. In this regard, the role of these services as innovation carriers and knowledge facilitators can help closing the gap with advanced economies (where the role of KIBS may be more strongly related to knowledge production per se). This represents a call to address in future research how these impacts take place. Perhaps a constructive path can be developed by studying the dynamics of relationships that KIBS establish with local firms in developing markets.

It must be remembered, however, that although this investigation represents a significant step forward in terms of theoretical and empirical aspects of the inherent interconnections between KIBS' FDI and innovation systems in developing countries, it does not go without limitations. First, results cannot be regarded as conclusive, since KIBS' contribution to innovation systems are hard to quantify by using traditional linear measures, as their impacts are of a systemic and complex nature.

Moreover, analytical models represent only a partial perspective of the complex structures involved in National Innovation Systems. Further research that includes different sets of explanatory variables (particularly those that can deal with institutional environments) is required in order to validate findings. This same criticism is applicable to dependent dimensions: overall analysis of NISs have been defined using a limited structure, and it is an interesting path of research to develop alternative empirical frameworks in this regard. Lastly, when dealing with economic systems, a 10-year time frame can restrict the evaluation of evolutionary trends. This aspect has to be taken into account in the appropriation of the results.

References

  • Aitken, B., & Harrison, A. (1999). Do domestic firms benefit from foreign direct investment? Evidence from Venezuela. American Economic Review, 89(3), 605-618. doi: 10.1257/aer.89.3.605
    » https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.89.3.605
  • Aleksynska, M., Gaisford, J., & Kerr, W. (2003). Foreign direct investment and growth in transition economies [Working Paper nº 7668]. Munich Personal RePEc Archive. Retrieved from http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/7668/
    » mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/7668/
  • Alfaro, L., Chanda, A., Kalemli-Ozcan, S., & Sayek, S. (2004). FDI and economic growth: the role of local financial markets. Journal of International Economics, 64(1), 89-112. doi: 10.1016/s0022-1996(03)00081-3
    » https://doi.org/10.1016/s0022-1996(03)00081-3
  • Álvarez, I., & Marín, R. (2010). Entry modes and national systems of innovation. Journal of International Management, 16(4), 340-353. doi: 10.1016/j.intman.2010.09.005
    » https://doi.org/10.1016/j.intman.2010.09.005
  • Archibugi, D., Denni, M., & Filippetti, A. (2009). The technological capabilities of nations: the state of the art of synthetic indicators. Technological Forecasting and Social Change, 76(7), 917-931. doi: 10.1016/j.techfore.2009.01.002
    » https://doi.org/10.1016/j.techfore.2009.01.002
  • Bruhn, N., & Calegario, C. (2014). Productivity spillovers from foreign direct investment in the Brazilian processing industry. Brazilian Administration Review, 11(1), 22-46. Retrieved from http://www.scielo.br/pdf/bar/v11n1/v11n1a03.pdf. doi: 10.1590/s1807-76922014000100003
    » //www.scielo.br/pdf/bar/v11n1/v11n1a03.pdf. doi: 10.1590/s1807-76922014000100003
  • De Mello, L. (1997). Foreign direct investment in developing countries and growth: a selective survey. Journal of Development Studies, 34(1), 1-34. doi: 10.1080/00220389708422501
    » https://doi.org/10.1080/00220389708422501
  • Doloreux, D., & Shearmur, R. (2013). Innovation strategies: are knowledge-intensive business services just another source of information? Industry and Innovation, 20(8), 719-738. doi: 10.1080/13662716.2013.856623
    » https://doi.org/10.1080/13662716.2013.856623
  • European Commission. (2014). Innovation union scoreboard 2014. Retrieved from http://ec.europa.eu/enterprise/policies/innovation/files/ius/ius-2014_en.pdf
    » ec.europa.eu/enterprise/policies/innovation/files/ius/ius-2014_en.pdf
  • Ghoshal, S., & Bartlett, C.A. (1990). The multinational corporation as an interorganizational network. Academy of Management Review, 15(4), 603-625. doi: 10.5465/amr.1990.4310825
    » https://doi.org/10.5465/amr.1990.4310825
  • Girma, S. (2005). Absorptive capacity and productivity spillovers from FDI: a threshold regression analysis. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 67(3), 281-306.doi: 10.1111/j.1468-0084.2005.00120.x
    » https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0084.2005.00120.x
  • Golub, S.S. (2009). Openness to foreign direct investment in services: an international comparative analysis. The World Economy, 32(8), 1245-1268. doi: 10.1111/j.1467-9701.2009.01201.x
    » https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9701.2009.01201.x
  • Guimón, J. (2009). Government strategies to attract R& D intensive FDI. The Journal of Technology Transfer, 34(4), 364-379. doi: 10.1007/s10961-008-9091-1
    » https://doi.org/10.1007/s10961-008-9091-1
  • Hansen, H., & Rand, J. (2006). On the causal links between FDI and growth in developing countries. The World Economy, 29(1), 21-41. doi: 10.1111/j.1467-9701.2006.00756.x
    » https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9701.2006.00756.x
  • He, Z.,& Wong, P. (2009). Knowledge interaction with manufacturing clients and innovation of knowledge-intensive business services firms. Innovation: Management, Policy & Practice, 11(3), 264-278. doi: 10.5172/impp.11.3.264
    » https://doi.org/10.5172/impp.11.3.264
  • Hertog, P. D. (2000). Knowledge-intensive business services as co-producers of innovation. International Journal of Innovation Management, 4(4), 491-528. doi: 10.1142/s136391960000024x
    » https://doi.org/10.1142/s136391960000024x
  • International Trade Centre. (2014). Investment map [Database]. Retrieved from http://www.investmentmap.org/
    » //www.investmentmap.org/
  • Koch, A., & Stahlecker, T. (2006). Regional innovation systems and the foundation of knowledge intensive business services: a comparative study in Bremen, Munich, and Stuttgart, Germany. European Planning Studies, 14(2), 123-145. doi: 10.1080/09654310500417830
    » https://doi.org/10.1080/09654310500417830
  • Lundvall, B., Johnson, B., Andersen, E., & Dalum, B. (2002). National systems of production, innovation and competence building. Research Policy, 31(2), 213-231. doi: 10.1016/s0048-7333(01)00137-8
    » https://doi.org/10.1016/s0048-7333(01)00137-8
  • Markusen, J., Rutherford, T. F., & Tarr, D. (2005). Trade and direct investment in producer services and the domestic market for expertise. Canadian Journal of Economics, 38(3), 758-773. doi: 10.1111/j.0008-4085.2005.00301.x
    » https://doi.org/10.1111/j.0008-4085.2005.00301.x
  • Massini, S., & Miozzo, M. (2012). Outsourcing and offshoring of business services: challenges to theory, management and geography of innovation. Regional Studies, 46(9), 1219-1242. doi: 10.1080/00343404.2010.509128
    » https://doi.org/10.1080/00343404.2010.509128
  • Mas-Verdú, F., Wensley, A. K. P., Alba, M. F., & Álvarez-Coque, J. M. G. (2011). How much does KIBS contribute to the generation and diffusion of innovation? Service Business, 5(3), 195-212. doi: 10.1007/s11628-011-0110-1
    » https://doi.org/10.1007/s11628-011-0110-1
  • Mayer-Foulkes, D., & Nunnenkamp, P. (2009). Do multinational enterprises contribute to convergence or divergence? A disaggregated analysis of US FDI. Review of Development Economics, 13(2), 304-318. doi: 10.1111/j.1467-9361.2009.00510.x
    » https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9361.2009.00510.x
  • Miles, I. (2004). Innovation in services. In J. Fagerberg, D. C. Mowery,& R. R. Nelson (Eds.), The Oxford handbook of innovation(Chap. 5, pp. 433-458). New York: Oxford University Press
  • Miles, I. (2008). Patterns of innovation in service industries. IBM Systems Journal, 47(1), 115-128. doi: 10.1147/sj.471.0115
    » https://doi.org/10.1147/sj.471.0115
  • Miles, I., Kastrinos, N., Flanagan, K., Bilderbeek, R., Hertog, P., Huntink, W., & Bouman, M. (1995). Knowledge-intensive business services: their role as users, carriers and sources of innovation[Report].EC DG XIII Sprint EIMS Programme, Luxembourg. Retrieved from https://research.mbs.ac.uk/INNOVATION/Portals /0/docs/ KIBSEIMS1995shortreport.pdf
    » research.mbs.ac.uk/INNOVATION/Portals /0/docs/ KIBSEIMS1995shortreport.pdf
  • Miozzo, M., & Grimshaw, D. (2005). Modularity and innovation in knowledge-intensive business services: IT outsourcing in Germany and the UK. Research Policy, 34(9), 1419-1439. doi: 10.1016/j.respol.2005.06.005
    » https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2005.06.005
  • Miozzo, M., Lehrer, M., DeFillippi, R., Grimshaw, D., & Ordanini, A. (2010). Economies of scope through multi-unit skill systems: the organization of large design firms. British Journal of Management, 23(2), 145-164. doi: 10.1111/j.1467-8551.2010.00699.x
    » https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-8551.2010.00699.x
  • Miozzo, M., & Soete, L. (2001). Internationalization of services: a technological perspective. Technological Forecasting and Social Change, 67(2/3), 159-185. doi: 10.1016/s0040-1625(00)00091-3
    » https://doi.org/10.1016/s0040-1625(00)00091-3
  • Miozzo, M., Yamin, M., & Ghauri, P. (2012). Strategy and structure of service multinationals and their impact on linkages with local firms. The Service Industries Journal, 32(7), 1171-1191. doi: 10.1080/02642069.2012.662492
    » https://doi.org/10.1080/02642069.2012.662492
  • Narula, R., & Dunning, J. H. (2010). Multinational enterprises, development and globalization: some clarifications and a research agenda. Oxford Development Studies, 38(3), 263-287. doi: 10.1080/13600818.2010.505684
    » https://doi.org/10.1080/13600818.2010.505684
  • Ramasamy, B., & Yeung, M. (2010). The determinants of foreign direct investment in services. The World Economy, 33(4), 573-596. doi: 10.1111/j.1467-9701.2009.01256.x
    » https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9701.2009.01256.x
  • Riedl, A. (2010). Location factors of FDI and the growing services economy: evidence from transition countries. Economics of Transition, 18(4), 741-761. doi: 10.1111/j.1468-0351.2010.00391.x
    » https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0351.2010.00391.x
  • Simmie, J., & Strambach, S. (2006). The contribution of KIBS to innovation in cities: an evolutionary and institutional perspective. Journal of Knowledge Management, 10(5), 26-40. doi: 10.1108/13673270610691152
    » https://doi.org/10.1108/13673270610691152
  • Teixeira, A. (2013). Evolution, roots and influence of the literature on National Systems of Innovation: a bibliometric account. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 38(1), 181-214. doi: 10.1093/cje/bet022
    » https://doi.org/10.1093/cje/bet022
  • The Conference Board. (2014). Total economy database [Database]. Retrieved from https://www.conference-board.org/data/economydatabase/
    » www.conference-board.org/data/economydatabase/
  • United States Patent and Trademark Office. (2014). Patent statistics [Database]. Retrieved from http://www.uspto.gov/web/offices/ac/ido/oeip/taf/reports.htm
    » www.uspto.gov/web/offices/ac/ido/oeip/taf/reports.htm
  • Waldkirch, A. (2011). Comparative advantage FDI? A host country perspective. Review of World Economics, 147(3), 485-505. doi: 10.1007/s10290-011-0096-8
    » https://doi.org/10.1007/s10290-011-0096-8
  • Wooldridge, J. (2000). Econometric analysis of cross section and panel data(2nd. ed.). Cambridge: The MIT Press.
  • Wooster, R., & Diebel, D. (2010). Productivity spillovers from foreign direct investment in developing countries: a meta-regression analysis. Review of Development Economics, 14(3), 640-655. doi: 10.1111/j.1467-9361.2010.00579.x
    » https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9361.2010.00579.x
  • World Bank. (2014). World development indicators [Database]. Retrieved from http://data.worldbank.org/indicator
    » data.worldbank.org/indicator
  • World Bank. (2015). World Bank list of economies. Retrieved from http://siteresources.worldbank.org/DATASTATISTICS/Resources/CLASS.XLS
    » siteresources.worldbank.org/DATASTATISTICS/Resources/CLASS.XLS
  • Yang, W., & Yan, M. (2010). The policy to promote the innovative development of knowledge-intensive business services. International Journal of Business and Management, 5(11), 190-194. doi: 10.5539/ijbm.v5n11p190
    » https://doi.org/10.5539/ijbm.v5n11p190

Appendix A KIBS Sectors Used in the Analysis

Appendix B List of Developing Countries Included in the Panel Dataset

Publication Dates

  • Publication in this collection
    Apr-Jun 2015
ANPAD - Associação Nacional de Pós-Graduação e Pesquisa em Administração Av. Pedro Taques, 294, 87030-008 - Maringá, PR, Brazil, Tel.: (+55) (44) 98826-2467 - Maringá - PR - Brazil
E-mail: bar@anpad.org.br