Skip to main content
Log in

How Has China's Economic Emergence Contributed to the Field of Economics?

  • 50th Anniversary Essay
  • Published:
Comparative Economic Studies Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

China’s economic transformation demonstrates that the paths of transition and development are broader and more varied than generally predicted by economic research relating to other countries. Research focused on China’s experience contributes to the scope and richness of the economics literature in notable ways. The China literature illustrates and makes more vivid established insights and paradigms, including those of Nobel laureates whose work relates to development and institutions. Furthermore, China is inspiring new insights and understanding regarding the central role of institutions. This paper, in particular, focuses its review on the literature that expands our understanding of the process of induced institutional change.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In its recent revision of relative purchasing power parity measures of GDP, the World Bank estimates that China's GDP is 40% less than previously reported by the Bank. http://web.worldbank.org/WBSITE/EXTERNAL/NEWS/0,,contentMDK:21589281~pagePK:34370~piPK:34424~theSitePK:4607,00.html. This revision adjusts China's PPP measure of GDP to somewhat less than one-half that of the US. However, at the time of the writing of this paper, China's exchange rate is widely believed to be substantially undervalued in relation to the US dollar.

  2. I believe that the last comprehensive review of the literature relating to China economic reforms was conducted by Perkins (1988).

  3. While these data sets are unusually detailed, significant aspects of these data have yet to be fully reconciled with those of other nations. Also, see the NBER website http://www.nber.org/~confer/2007/cwt07/cwt07prg.html for a workshop on this topic as well as the websites of Robert Feenstra and Chad Bown for information on current data and recent research using these trade data.

  4. See, for example, Brandt and Rawski (2008), a compilation of research papers resulting from a broad effort to match specialists in functional areas, such as economic transition, agriculture, and industrial organisation with their counterparts who specialise in China.

  5. These include journals published in Japan, such as the Journal of Chinese Economic Studies and the Journal of Econometric Study of Northeast Asia.

  6. The count of economists with Chinese surnames cannot distinguish among the country or region of origin, for example, Mainland China, Taiwan, Hong Kong, the US.

  7. According to Williamson (2002), who is generally viewed as the author of the Washington Consensus (Williamson and Miller, 1987), the doctrine consists of ‘ten reforms that I originally presented as a summary of what most people in Washington believe Latin America (not all countries) ought to be undertaking as of 1988 (not all times).’ Subsequently, the Washington Consensus became widely viewed as the intellectual foundation for the shock therapy proposed by economist for the transitional economies of Eastern Europe and the former Soviet Union.

  8. Also see Fischer and Gelb (1991) and the World Bank (1996) for accounts of blueprints and sequencing across key dimensions of the orthodox reform agenda.

  9. According to the China Statistical Yearbook 2006 (NBS, 2006, Ch. 15, Industry, Explanatory Notes on Main Statistical Indicators), ‘Collective enterprises constitute an integral part of the socialist economy with public ownership.’ Political sub-jurisdications, such as municipalities, towns, and villages, generally own a substantial share of such collective-owned enterprises.

  10. John Williamson, ‘The Washington Consensus as Policy Prescription for Development’ (http://info.worldbank.org/etools/bspan/PresentationView.asp?PID=520&EID=257).

  11. Perkins and Rawski acknowledge the fundamental role of productivity growth in driving the measured contribution of capital: ‘The rise in the contribution of capital did not occur independently of the rise in productivity… . Thus it was the jump in productivity growth (after 1978) that led to a higher GDP growth rate that made possible the greater contribution of capital’ (p. 19).

  12. In the spirit of endogenous growth theory, the emphasis on productivity growth does not preclude the possibility that China's high rates of savings and low population growth have themselves contributed to productivity growth. Specifically, they may have affected productivity by promoting human capital investment, which may increase returns to scale at the firm level or facilitate technology spillovers from the broad economy to individual firms (see Romer, 1986). The point is that to the extent that high savings rates and limited population growth have contributed to the sustained growth of living standards, they have done so through their indirect contributions to productivity growth.

  13. See Zhang et al. (2005) for an account of the sources of China's rising returns to education.

  14. Naughton (2007, Figure 9.1) shows two substantially different estimates of the decline in poverty – an official Chinese estimate and a World Bank estimate. However, both involve more than 25% of China’s rural population escaping poverty status.

  15. For China, Hsieh and Klenow (2007) estimate potential gains from allocative efficiency to be in the vicinity of 40%; for India, the potential gains are close to 60%.

  16. Another example analyses the implications of alternative assignments of property rights, such as the right of the lender to monitor for the purpose of mitigating problems associated with asymmetric information in credit allocation, for example Dewatripont and Maskin (1995).

  17. Ruttan particularly focuses on a case study of institutional innovation conducted by Hayami and Kikuchi (1981) in a Philippine village involving changes in technology and resource endowments associated with the introduction of high yielding varieties of rice and a national irrigation system. These changes led during 1966–1976 to a shift from share tenure to lease tenure and to a dramatic increase in sub-tenancy arrangements (p. 362).

  18. Guo (2005) provides a broad context for understanding the certain advantages associated with the relative ‘backwardness’ of China's institutions.

  19. Bowlus and Sicular (2003) also show that the absence of land markets that function across villages contribute to both labour shortages and surpluses.

  20. See Jefferson's (1998) characterisation of the state-owned enterprise as a public good.

  21. See Jefferson's account of the problem of markets in labour quality within China's SOEs, ‘Missing Markets in Labor Quality: The Role of Quality Markets in Transition,’ http://people.brandeis.edu/~jefferso/res.html.

  22. During the academic year 1986–1987 when the author was teaching in the School of Economics at Wuhan University, he observed that the graduate students were not quite as diligent as he had anticipated. They explained that this was due to the fact they anticipated assignments under the labour allocation system that were not likely to require them to use their advanced economics training.

  23. In 1985, the average wage of staff and workers in SOEs was 0.845 that of the firms operating under other types of ownership. From 1985, the relative SOE wage fell year-on-year until 1993 when it stood at 0.712, a 16% decline over 8 years. Thereafter, as managers acquired greater rights to set compensation and furlough workers (ie xiagang), the relative wage of SOE workers began to rise. Jefferson et al. (forthcoming) document a rapid rise in the relative productivity levels of SOEs from 1998 to 2005.

  24. See the survey of Jefferson et al. (1999) of differential assignments of managerial control rights in samples of SOEs and TVEs.

  25. Bai et al. (2000) argue that in the absence of an umbrella safety net, such as unemployment insurance, SOEs continue to play a critical transition. Because independent institutions for social safety are lacking and firms with strong profit incentives have little incentives to promote social stability due to its public good nature, SOEs are needed to continue their role in providing social welfare. Charged with the multi-tasks of efficient production as well as social welfare provision, SOEs continue to be given low-profit incentives and consequently, their financial performance continues to be poor.

  26. Cao et al. (1999), Li et al. (2000) and Li (1997) all find empirical evidence to support this view.

  27. Lardy (1998, 2002) documents these losses, chronicles the government's attempts to reform the banking system, and describes the rule changes associated with China's accession to the WTO.

  28. See recent estimate of returns to investment by Bai et al. (2006) and Jefferson et al. (2006). Both find increasing return to capital in the China’s secondary (industrial) sectors.

  29. Mao’s decentralisation movement accompanied the Great Leap. In 1958, the number of SOEs subordinated to the central government was reduced from 9,300 in 1957 to 1,200 in 1958 (Qian, 2002, p. 25). Recentralisation followed the Great Leap disaster. The second wave of decentralisation (1970) shared many features of the 1958 decentralisation but went even further. Qian (p. 27). The number of SOEs under central government supervision fell from 10,533 in 1965 to just 142 in 1970.

  30. These bundles of regional production capabilities are documented in Naughton (2007).

  31. Young (2000) argues that substantial barriers to trade exist between Chinese provinces. Other research (eg Bai (2004) and Long and Zhang (2008)) since 1990 find a clear trend toward greater regional specialisation.

  32. Chinese policy makers refer facetiously to the ‘10+1’ policy paradigm, that is, ‘If province X will give you those 10 incentives, then our province will give you those 10 plus this one more.’

  33. The trade ration is defined conventionally as (imports+exports)/GDP.

  34. See Naughton (2007), Ch. 1, ‘Legacies and Settings.’

  35. Wu (2000) describes the transformation of a mental model associated with the Fourth Plenum of the 15 CCP National Congress (1989). According to Wu, that Congress ‘rejected the Soviet-style view that the quality of the socialist state was proportional to the size of the state sector..(The Congress called for) an economic system based on the principle of “Three Benefits”: …the domain of the state system shall be narrowed; develop multiple forms of public ownership; encourage the development of the non-public sector such as private enterprises.’

  36. Consistent with the Bromley-Yao imagery, Wei (1997) assigns to his reform agents the responsibility of delegating ‘different parts of a reform program into groups. Within each group, there is strong interdependence. Across groups there is no strong interdependence’ (p. 1,236). The gradual reform process entails the implementation of rapid, simultaneous reform within interdependent groups, while coordination across groups may proceed more slowly.

  37. Josef Brada inquires how China ‘evolved from a government that gave us the Great Leap Forward, the Great Famine, and other economic and social disasters…to one that seems almost Socratic in its steering of economic reform.’ Brada continues, ‘…this is not the message of the classical public choice school of thought like Tullock and Olsen.’ Brada's question goes to the heart of the question concerning the nature of the Chinese leadership's objective function that underlies the ‘generally stable, pragmatic political environment,’ which is the focus of this section. I leave it to another to identify the objective function of the Chinese leadership and CCP that answers Brada's question.

  38. Elements of this argument are set forth in Jefferson and Zhang (2007).

  39. In spite of this assessment that a process of political transition or blowback is underway, the view of Wu (2000) is not atypical: ‘The key feature of the old system is the unification of the three entities – the party, the government, and the economy…. The interrelationship that arises from this unification is deep and complicated….(Soviet) people, particularly the social and political elites, have tremendous interest in maintaining the old system….As such the reforms face enormous resistance.’

  40. See, for example, Rawski (forthcoming) regarding China's culture, market, and entrepreneurial legacies. Roland (2004) notes that Sachs and Woo (1994) attribute China's recent high growth rates to the country's ‘backwardness’ in the immediately preceding period. Seen in a long-run historical perspective, however, Roland argues that China has been anything but backward. For example, Chinese agriculture, which was the initial engine of growth early in the transition, has always been among the most productive in the world. I therefore suggest that one of the clues to the success of China's transition is not its ‘backwardness’ at the onset of the transition but the inherited high level of knowledge and culture relative to its economic performance.

  41. Likewise Sala-i-Martin (2002) shows that as China’s middle class grows and graduates into the ranks of the world’s relatively high income population, China, by itself, has the capacity to reverse this convergence trend and become a key source of an increasing maldistribution of global income.

  42. Japan provides an interesting case of a country having received accolades for its special economic, institutions, culture, and achievements. While this admiration diminished as a result of the nation's apparent shift to a low-growth trajectory, Japan does retain its distinctiveness with respect to the Toyota system, involving just-in-time inventory, industrial policy, and close ties with suppliers (see Ezra Vogel, Japan as Number One , 1979).

  43. See Jefferson et al. (2006) who document distances between the technology frontiers of China and the US–Japan and internal patterns of productivity differences.

  44. Of course, as in the US, certain pollutants, such as sulphur dioxide and nitrous oxides, may exhibit a turning point, while others, such as carbon emissions, do (have) not. As Naughton reports (2007, p. 490), ambient air quality has improved in many Chinese cities as gas and electricity use has substituted for coal for cooking and heating in many homes; also, leaded gasoline has been omitted. At the same time, as automobile use surges, concentrations of nitrous oxides have increased.

References

  • Aghion, P, Blundell, R, Griffith, R, Howitt, P and Pranti, S . 2006: The effects of entry on incumbent innovation and productivity. NBER Working Paper, w12027.

  • Bai, C-en . 2004: Local protectionism and regional specialization: Evidence from China's industries. Journal of International Economics 63 (2): 397–417.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bai, C-en, Hsieh, C-tai and Qian, Y . 2006: The returns to capital in China. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1: 60–102.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bai, C-en, Li, DD, Tao, Z and Wang, Y . 2000: The multitask theory of state enterprise reform. Journal of Comparative Economics 28 (2000): 716–738.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bowlus, A and Sicular, T . 2003: Moving toward markets? Labor allocation in rural China. Journal of Development Economics 71 (2): 561–583.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brandt, L, Hsieh, C-tai and Zhu, X . 2008: Accounting for growth and structural transformation in China, 1978–2004. In: Brandt, L. and Rawski, TG (eds). China’s great economic transformation. Cambridge University Press: New York.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Brandt, L and Rawski, TG . 2008: China’s great economic transformation. Cambridge University Press: New York.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Bromley, DW and Yao, Y . 2006: Understanding China's economic transformation: Are there lessons for the developing world? World Economics 7 (2): 73–96.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, JM . 1979: What should economists do? Liberty Press: Indianapolis.

    Google Scholar 

  • Byrd, WA . 1992: Chinese industrial firms under reform published for the World Bank, Oxford University Press: Washington, DC.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cao, Y, Qian, Y and Weingast, BR . 1999: From federalism, Chinese style to privatization, Chinese style. Economics of Transition 7 (1): 103–131.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R . 1960: The problem of social cost. Journal of Law and Economics 3: 1–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R . 1992: The institutional structure of production. American Economic Review 82 (4): 713–719.

    Google Scholar 

  • Decision. 1993: China’s central government decision on resolving several problems concerning the establishment of a socialist market economic system. Renmin ribao (People’s Daily), November 17, p. 1.

  • Deng, P and Jefferson, GH . 2008: Foreign entry and the heterogeneous growth of firms: Do we observe “creative destruction” in China? Working paper, Brandeis University.

  • Dewatripont, M and Maskin, E . 1995: Credit and efficiency in centralized and decentralized economies. Review of Economics and Statistics 62: 541–555.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Djankov, S, Glaeser, E, La Porta, R, Lopez-de-Silanes, F and Shliefer, A . 2003: The new comparative economics. Journal of Comparative Economics 31 (4): 595–619.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Easterly, W . 2001: The elusive quest for growth: economists’ adventures and misadventures in the tropics. MIT Press: Cambridge, MA.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fan, S . 1991: Effects of technological change and institutional reform on production and growth in Chinese agriculture. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 73: 266–275.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fei, JCH and Ranis, G . 1964: Development of the labor surplus economy: Theory and policy. Richard D. Irwin, Inc.: Homewood, IL.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fischer, S and Gelb, A . 1991: The process of socialist economic transformation. Journal of Economic Perspectives 5 (4): 91–105.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Girma, S, Gong, Y and Görg, H . (forthcoming): What determines innovation activity in Chinese state-owned enterprises? The role of foreign direct investment. World Development.

  • Groves, T, McMillan, J, Hong, Y and Naughton, B . 1994: Autonomy and incentives in Chinese state enterprises. Quarterly Journal of Economics 109 (1): 183–209.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guo, X . 2005: Houfa youshi xinlun – jianlun zhongguo jingji fazhan de dongli (A new theory of the advantages of backwardness – a concurrent theory of the strengths of China’s economic development). Development economics research: research topics on the advantages of backwardness, The Economic Development Research Center, Wuhan University, July 2005.

  • Hay, D, Morris, D, Liu, G and Yao, S . 1994: Economic reform and state-owned enterprises in China, 1979–1987. Clarendon Press: Oxford.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayami, Y and Kikuchi, M . 1981: Asian village economy at the crossroads: An economic approach to institutional change. University of Tokyo Press: Tokyo (and Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore, 1982).

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayami, Y and Ruttan, V . 1985: Agricultural development: An international perspective. Johns Hopkins Univesity Press: Baltimore, MD.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holz, C . 2003: “Fast, clear and accurate”: How reliable are Chinese output and economic growth statistics? China Quarterly 117: 122–163.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holz, C . 2004: Deconstructing China's GDP statistics. China Economic Review 15: 164–202.15.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hsieh, C-tai and Klenow, P . 2007: Misallocation and manufacturing productivity in China and India (unpublished manuscript).

  • Hu, AGZ and Jefferson, GH . 2008: A great wall of patents: What is behind China's recent patent explosion? unpublished manuscript. http://people.brandeis.edu/~jefferso/Great%20Wall,%20submitted%20manuscript,%20Jan.%202006.pdf.

  • Hulton, CR . 1975: Technical change and the reproducibility of capital. American Economic Review 65 (5): 956–965.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jefferson, GH . 1998: China’s state enterprises: Public goods, externalities, and coase. American Economic Review (Papers and Proceedings), May 1998.

  • Jefferson, GH, Hu, AGZ and Su, J . 2006: The sustainability of China’s economic growth. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1: 1–60.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jefferson, GH and Rawski, TG . 1994: How industrial reform worked in China: The role of innovation, competition, and property rights. In: Bruno, M and Pleskovic, B (eds) Proceedings of the World Bank Annual Conference on Development Economics 1994. World Bank: Washington, DC pp. 129–156.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jefferson, GH and Rawski, TG . 2002: China's emerging market for property rights: Theoretical and empirical perspectives. Economics of Transition 10 (3): 585–617.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jefferson, GH, Rawski, TG and Zhang, Y . (forthcoming): Productivity growth and convergence across China's industrial economy. Journal of Chinese Economics and Business Studies.

  • Jefferson, GH, Mai, L and Zhao, JZQ . 1999: Reforming property rights in China’s industry. In: Jefferson, GH and Singh, IJ (eds) Enterprise Reform in China: Ownership, Transition, and Performance. A World Bank Research Publication, Oxford University Press: New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jefferson, GH and Zhang, J . 2007: China's political reform: A property rights interpretation. unpublished manuscript, May 15, 2007.

  • Jenson, MC and Meckling, WH . 1976: Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs, and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics 3: 305–360.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keidel, A . 2007: China’s financial sector: Contributions to growth and downside risks. Prepared for the Conference, “China’s Changing Financial System: Can it Catch Up With or Even Drive Economic Growth,” Networks Financial Institute, Indiana State University, January 25, 2007.

  • Kuznets, S . 1966: Modern economic growth: Rate, structure, and spread. Yale University Press: New Haven.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lardy, N . 1998: China’s unfinished economic revolution. Brookings Institution Press: Washington, DC.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lardy, N . 2002: Integrating China into the global economy. Brookings Institution Press: Washington, DC.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lau, L, Qian, Y and Roland, G . 2000: Reform without losers: An interpretation of China’s dual-track approach to transition. Journal of Political Economy 108 (1): 120–143.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee, K, Hahn, D and Lin, J . 2001: China and the East Asian model: A “comparative institutional analysis” perspective. Institute of Economic Research, Seoul National University, Working Paper Series, No. 41. January 2001.

  • Lewis, A . 1954: Economic development with unlimited supplies of labor. Manchester School of Economics and Social Studies 22: 139–191.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li, W . 1997: The impact of economic reforms on the performance of Chinese state-owned enterprises. Journal of Political Economy 105 (5): 1080–1106.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li, G, Xu, CL and Yao, Y . 2007: Health shocks, village elections, and long-term income evidence from rural China. November 2007, presented on the panel ‘Institutions and Economic Development,’ January 5, 2008, Allied Social Science Associations, New Orleans 2008.

  • Li, G, Xu, CL and Yao, Y . 2008: Governance, finance, and consumption insurance: Evidence from Chinese villages. undated, presented on the panel ‘Institutions and Economic Development,’ January 5, 2008, Allied Social Science Associations, New Orleans 2008.

  • Li, S, Li, S and Zhang, W . 2000: The road to capitalism: Competition and institutional change in China. Journal of Comparative Economics 28: 269–292.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lin, JY . 1987: The household responsibility system in China: A peasant's institutional choice. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 69 (2): 410–415.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lin, JY . 1992a: The household responsibility system in China's agricultural reform: A theoretical and empirical study. Economic Development and Cultural Change 36 (3): S199–S224.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lin, JY . 1992b: Rural reforms and agricultural growth in China. American Economic Review 82 (1): 34–51.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lin, JY . 1995: Endowments, technology, and factor markets: A natural experiment of induced institutional innovation from China's rural reform. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 77: 231–242.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lin, JY . 2005: Viability, economic transition and reflection on neoclassical economics. Kyklos 58 (2): 239–264.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lipton, D . 2007: Eastern Europe. The concise encyclopedia of economics, The Library of Economics and Liberty, http://www.econlib.org/library/Enc/EasternEurope.html (accessed 17 August 2007).

  • Long, C and Zhang, X . 2008: Organization choice with credit constraint: Industrial clusters in China. Presented on the panel “Institutions and Economic Development,” January 5, 2008, Allied Social Science Associations, New Orleans 2008.

  • Maddison, A . 1998: Chinese economic performance in the long run. Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development: Paris.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Maddison, A . 2003: The world economy historical statistics. OECD Publishing: Paris.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Miles, MA, Reulner, EJ and O’Grady, MA . 2005: Index of economic freedom. The link between economic opportunity and prosperity. The Heritage Foundation: Washington, DC and The Wall Street Journal (New York).

    Google Scholar 

  • Murrell, P . 1991: Can neoclassical economics underpin the reform of centrally planned economies? Journal of Economic Perspectives 5: 59–76.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Naughton, B . 1995: Growing out of the plan. Cambridge University Press: Cambridge.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Naughton, B . 2006: Reframing China policy: The carnegie debates, debate 2: China’s economy (arguing against the motion) The Carnegie Endowment for International Peace.

  • Naughton, B . 2007: The Chinese economy: Transitions and growth. MIT Press: Cambridge.

    Google Scholar 

  • NBS (National Bureau of Statistics). 1994: China Statistical yearbook 1994. China Statistics Press: Beijing.

  • NBS (National Bureau of Statistics). 1995: China statistical yearbook 1995. China Statistics Press: Beijing.

  • NBS (National Bureau of Statistics). 2004: China statistical yearbook 2004. China Statistics Press: Beijing.

  • NBS (National Bureau of Statistics). 2006: China statistical yearbook 2006. China Statistics Press: Beijing.

  • North, DC . 1990: Institutions, institutional change, and economic performance. Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, New York.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • North, DC . 1994: Economic performance through time. American Economic Review 84 (3): 359–368.

    Google Scholar 

  • Perkins, DH . 1988: Reforming China’s economic system. Journal of Economic Literature 26: 601–645.

    Google Scholar 

  • Perkins, DH and Rawski, TG . 2008: Forecasting China's economic growth to 2025. In: Brandt, L and Rawski, TG (eds) China’s great economic transformation. Cambridge University Press: New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Popov, V . 2007: Shock therapy versus gradualism reconsidered: Lessons from transition economies after 15 years of reforms. Comparative Economic Studies 49 (1): 1–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Prescott, EC . 1998: Lawrence R. Klein Lecture 1997: A theory of total factor productivity. International Economic Review 39 (3): 525–551.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Putterman, L . 1995: The role of ownership and property rights in China's economic transition. The China Quarterly Vol. 144, (Special Issue: China's Transitional Economy) pp. 1047–1067.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Putterman, L . 2008: China’s encounter with market socialism: Approaching managed capitalism by indirect means. In: Kornai J and Qian Y (eds). Market and Socialism in the Light of the Experiences of China and Vietnam. Palgrave Macmillan: Basingstoke (forthcoming).

  • Qian, Y . 2000: The process of China's market transition (1978–98): The evolutionary, historical, and comparative perspective. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 156 (1): 151–171.

    Google Scholar 

  • Qian, Y . 2002: How reform worked in China? Mimeo, UC Berkeley.

  • Qian, Y, Roland, G and Xu, C . 2006: Coordination and experimentation in M-form and U-form organizations. Journal of Political Economy 114 (2): 366–402.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Qian, Y and Weingast, BR . 1997: Federalism as a commitment to preserving market incentives. Journal of Economic Perspectives 11 (4): 83–92.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Qian, Y and Xu, C . 1993: Why China’s economic reforms differ: The M-Form hierarchy and entry/expansion of the non-state sector. The Economics of Transition 1: 135–170.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ravallion, M and Chen, S . 1999: When economic reform is faster than statistical reform: Measuring and explaining income inequality in explaining income inequality in rural China. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 61: 75–102.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rawski, T . forthcoming: Social capabilities and Chinese economic growth. In: Tang W and Holzner B (eds). Social Transformation in Contemporary China. University of Pittsburgh Press: Pittsburgh.

  • Rodrik, D . August 2004: Growth strategies http://ksghome.harvard.edu/~drodrik/GrowthStrategies.pdf.

  • Roland, G . 2004: Understanding institutional change: Fast-moving and slow-moving institutions. Studies in Comparative International Development 38 (4): 109–131.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Romer, P . 1986: Increasing returns and long-run growth. Journal of Political Economy 94: 1002–1037.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rozelle, S and Li, G . 1998: Village leaders and land-rights formation in China. American Economics Review (Papers and Proceedings) 88 (2): 433–438.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ruttan, VW . 2001: Technology, growth, and development: An induced innovation perspective. Oxford University Press: New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sachs, J and Woo, W . 1994: Structural factors in the economic reforms of China, Eastern Europe, and the former Soviet Union. Economic Policy 9 (18): 101–145.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sala-i-Martin, X . 2002: The disturbing “rise” in global income inequality. National Bureau of Economic Research Working paper, w8904, April, 2002.

  • Schumpeter, JA . 1942: Capitalism, socialism, and democracy. Harper: New York 1975 [originally published 1942].

    Google Scholar 

  • Sen, A . 1988: The concept of development. In: Chenery, H and Srinivasan, TN (eds). Handbook of Development Economics. Vol. 1, Chapter 1, pp. 9–26. Holland: Amsterdam.

    Google Scholar 

  • Solow, R . 1956: A contribution to the theory of economic growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics 70 (1): 65–94.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Solow, R . 1957: Technical change and the aggregate production function. Review of Economic and Statistics 39: 312–320.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G . 1989: Two notes on the coase theorem. Yale Law Journal 99 (3): 631–633.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vogel, E . 1979: Japan as number one. Harvard University Press: Cambridge.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Wei, S . 1997: Gradualism versus big bang: Speed and sustainability of reforms. The Canadian Journal of Economics 30 (4b): 1234–1237.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weitzman, M and Xu, C . 1994: Chinese township and village enterprises as vaguely defined cooperatives. Journal of Comparative Economics 1 (3): 276–308.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, J . 2002: Did the Washington consensus fail? Outline of speech at the Center for Strategic & International Studies, Washington, DC, 6 November 2002.

  • Williamson, J and Miller, MH . 1987: Targets and indicators: A blueprint for international coordination of economic policy. Policy Analyses in International Economics, No. 22, Institute for International Economics: Washington, DC.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wong, C . 2006: Can China change development paradigm for the 21st century? Fiscal policy options for Hu Jintao and Wen Jiabao after two decades of muddling through? Mimeo, University of Washington.

  • World Bank. 1996: From plan to market. The World bank: Washington, DC.

  • Wu, J . 2000: China's economic reform: Past, present and future. Perspectives 1 (5), April 30, 2000.

  • Xu, C . 2006: Chinese reform an Chinese regional decentralization. 29 November 2006, presented at the Macau Conference.

  • Young, A . 2000: The razor's edge: Distortions and incremental reform in the people's republic of China. Quarterly Journal of Economics 115: 1091–1136.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Young, A . 2003: Gold into base metals: Productivity growth in the people’s republic of China during the reform period. Journal of Political Economy 111 (6): 1220–1261.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhang, J . 1997: Economics of dual track system: Chinese economic reform (1978–1992). Shanghai United Press: Shanghai.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zhang, J, Zhao, Y, Park, A and Song, X . 2005: Economic returns to schooling in urban China. Journal of Comparative Economics 33 (4): 730–752.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

I appreciate the helpful discussions and insightful comments provided during visits to the Chinese Center for Economic Studies at Fudan University, the Chinese Center for Economic Research at Peking University, and the Center for Economic Development Research at Wuhan University. In addition, I was greatly assisted by comments and suggestions from Josef Brada, Loren Brandt, Albert Hu, Albert Keidel, Ma Ying, Dwight Perkins, Peter Petri, Louis Putterman, Thomas Rawski, Su Jian, Xu Chenggang, Yao Yang, Zhang Jun, and Zhang Yifan. Research support provided by the US National Science Foundation (award # SES-0519902) is also gratefully acknowledged.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Jefferson, G. How Has China's Economic Emergence Contributed to the Field of Economics?. Comp Econ Stud 50, 167–209 (2008). https://doi.org/10.1057/ces.2008.14

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/ces.2008.14

Keywords

JEL Classifications

Navigation