Skip to main content
Log in

Political Economy Determinants of Public Spending Allocations: A Review of Theories, and Implications for Agricultural Public Investment

  • Original Article
  • Published:
The European Journal of Development Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Agricultural public investments in developing countries can have substantial effects on performance in the sector and beyond. In the examination of actual resource allocation decisions by governments and donors, it is striking that strong evidence of the high economic contributions of particular types of public investments seems to coexist with a relative neglect of these public goods provisions in budget portfolios, and vice versa. This article sets out to understand this incongruence, by examining the political economy drivers of public expenditure allocation and composition. It reviews theories and empirical investigations on how (i) the incentives and constraints of key actors – including politicians, bureaucrats, interest groups and donors, (ii) the characteristics of publicly provided goods and services and (iii) country-wide political governance environments affect the prioritisation of public investments.

Abstract

Dans les pays en développement, les dépenses publiques dans le secteur de l’agriculture ont des effets substantiels sur la performance du secteur, et au-delà du secteur même. En examinant les décisions d’allocation des ressources par les gouvernements et les donneurs, on découvre que des investissements publics qui apportent évidemment des fortes contributions économiques coexistent avec un état d’abandon relatif de ces mêmes provisions de biens publiques dans les portefeuilles budgétaires, et vice versa. Le but de cette étude c’est de comprendre cette incongruence, en examinant les effets des leviers de politique économique dans la composition et allocation des dépenses publiques. On examine théories et études empiriques sur comment la priorisation des investissements publiques est affecté par: (i) les motivations et les contraintes des acteurs principaux – y inclus les politiciens, les bureaucrates, les groups d’intérêt, et les donneurs; (II) Les caractéristiques des biens et services de provision publique; (iii) la gouvernance politique au niveau du pays.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Figure 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The principles discussed in Mogues et al (2015) include allocating resources to address positive and negative externalities in agricultural activity, the public goods nature in some agricultural investments, equity considerations, and the balance between market and government failures in agricultural interventions.

  2. The term ‘agent’ here – as well as elsewhere unless stated otherwise – is meant in terms of ‘actor’ in general, and is not necessarily limited to the notion of ‘agent’ in the principal-agent sense of the term.

  3. The survey in this article (from the second to the fourth section) considers only the academic peer-reviewed literature across various disciplines in political science, economics and so on, although interesting working papers and institutional papers also exist on the topic.

  4. The extent to which private and public investment in agriculture act as complements or substitutes is discussed in Mogues et al (2015).

  5. This study does not capture actual public expenditures, but creates a composite index from information about the presence or absence of various public goods/services outputs such as electricity and irrigation facilities.

  6. The attribution meant here is that agents such as farmers, other rural residents and organised rural groups may rightly or wrongly make a connection between improvements they experience and investments or policies the government undertook. That is, this discussion of attribution is not referring to analytical attribution problems by the empirical researcher. However, for readers interested in the challenges that long lag times impose on analytical attribution of agricultural research and development investments, see Alston and Pardey (2001).

  7. Harstad and Svensson (2011) uniquely study lobbying activities (discussed above) and corruptive activities in a joint framework. They distinguish these two in that corruptive behaviour seeks to bend the rules, while lobbying behaviour seeks to change the rules. Both types of activities are subsumed under rent-seeking activities.

  8. All these studies normalize spending, by considering spending categories as either a share of total spending or a ratio to GDP. Details on how the effect of interest is identified, including how potential simultaneity and other biases are addressed, are not discussed here but can be found by consulting the respective studies.

  9. The larger effects of corruption on development outcomes, including on agricultural growth, have been widely researched, and this question goes beyond the scope of the discussion in this review. Clearly, countries such as India and Indonesia have been able to record impressive and sustained agricultural growth, while also suffering from the ubiquitous presence of corruption in the agricultural and wider economy. Correlation, however, obviously does not imply causality, and in fact the question of whether the size, composition and distribution of growth would have been better had corruption been lower in these and other countries is an empirical matter.

  10. This study, covering the 1960–1990 period, does not include the post-Cold War period. A re-analysis including time periods after the critical structural break in world politics after 1990 might yield interesting and different results.

  11. The analysis includes a dummy for medium political rights and high political rights, with the non-included dummy being that of low political rights. The medium rights coefficient is statistically significant and negative in the model of agricultural research spending, and the high rights coefficient is not statistically significant.

  12. Most of the analyses discussed in this article are, however, better contextualised by probabilistic voter theories than by the median voter theory, as the analyses for the most part imply that citizens – for a range of reasons – prefer policy outcomes in a non-deterministic way. ‘Better’, however, does not mean ‘perfectly’: Both the probabilistic voting and the median voter theory presuppose the existence of functional democracies with competitive electoral systems, and these are not the relevant context in the case of agricultural (and other) public expenditure choices in many developing countries.

  13. A recent excellent example is Svolik (2012).

References

  • Abler, D.G. and Sukhatme, V. (1998) The determinants of wheat and rice policies: A political economy model for India. Journal of Economic Development 23 (1): 195–215.

    Google Scholar 

  • Acemoğlu, D. and Robinson, J. (2001) Inefficient redistribution. American Political Science Review 95 (3): 649–661.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alston, J., Marra, M., Pardey, P. and Wyatt, T. (2000) Research returns redux: A meta-analysis of the returns to agricultural R&D. Australian Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics 44 (2): 185–215.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alston, J.M. and Pardey, P.G. (2001) Attribution and other problems in assessing the returns to agricultural R&D. Agricultural Economics 25 (2–3): 141–152.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, K. and Hayami, Y. (eds.) (1986) The Political Economy of Agricultural Protection: East Asia in International Perspective. Sydney, Australia: Allen and Unwin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Austen-Smith, D. (1997) Interest groups: Money, information and influence. In: D.C. Mueller (ed.) Perspectives on Public Choice: A Handbook. Cambridge, UK: University of Cambridge Press, pp. 296–321.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bale, M.D. and Lutz, E. (1981) Price distortions in agriculture and their effects: An international comparison. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 63 (1): 8–22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bates, R.H. (1987) Essays on the Political Economy of Rural Africa. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. (1983) A theory of competition among pressure groups for political influence. Quarterly Journal of Economics 98 (3): 371–400.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beghin, J.C. and Kherallah, M. (1994) Political institutions and international patterns of agricultural protection. Review of Economics and Statistics 76 (3): 482–489.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beintema, N., Stads, G.-J., Fuglie, K. and Heisey, P. (2012) ASTI Global Assessment of Agricultural R&D Spending. Washington DC: International Food Policy Research Institute, Rome, Italy: Agricultural Science and Technology Indicators, Global Forum on Agricultural Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • Benin, S. and Yu, B. (2013) Complying with the Maputo Declaration Target Trends in Public Agricultural Expenditures and Implications for Pursuit of Optimal Allocation of Public Agricultural Spending. International Food Policy Research Institute, Washington DC: ReSAKSS Annual Trends and Outlook Report.

  • Besley, T., Pande, R. and Rao, V. (2012) Just rewards? Local politics and public resource allocation in South India. World Bank Economic Review 26 (2): 191–216.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Binswanger, H. and Deininger, K. (1997) Explaining agricultural and Agrarian policies in developing countries. Journal of Economic Literature 35 (4): 1958–2005.

    Google Scholar 

  • Birner, R. and Resnick, D. (2010) The political economy of policies for smallholder agriculture. World Development 38 (10): 1442–1452.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blackburn, K., Bose, N. and Haque, M.E. (2011) Public expenditures, bureaucratic corruption and economic development. Manchester School 79 (3): 405–428.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bräutigam, D. (2004) The people’s budget? Politics, participation, and pro-poor policy. Development Policy Review 22 (6): 653–668.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bullock, D.S. (1994) In search of rational government: What political preference function studies measure and assume. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 76 (3): 347–361.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carlin, A. (1967) Project versus program aid: From the donor’s viewpoint. Economic Journal 77 (305): 48–58.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coate, S. and Morris, S. (1999) Policy persistence. American Economic Review 89 (5): 1327–1336.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Collier, C. and Gunning, J.W. (1999) The IMF’s role in structural adjustment. Economic Journal 109 (459): 634–651.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Deacon, R.T. (1978) A demand model for the local public sector. Review of Economics and Statistics 60 (2): 180–202.

    Google Scholar 

  • De Gorter, H. and Swinnen, J.F.M. ((1998) Impact of economic development on commodity and public research policies in agriculture. Review of Development Economics 2 (1): 41–60.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Gorter, H. and Swinnen, J.F.M. (2002) Political economy of agricultural policy. In: B. Gardner and G. Rausser (eds.) Handbook of Agricultural Economics. Vol. 2. Amsterdam: Elsevier, pp. 1893–1943.

    Google Scholar 

  • De la Croix, D. and Delavallade, C. (2009) Growth, public investment and corruption with failing institutions. Economics of Governance 10 (3): 187–219.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Delavallade, C. (2006) Corruption and distribution of public spending in developing countries. Journal of Economics and Finance 30 (2): 222–239.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Doner, R.F., Ritchie, B.K. and Slater, D. (2005) Systemic vulnerability and the origins of developmental states: Northeast and Southeast Asia in comparative perspective. International Organisation 59 (2): 327–361.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Drazen, A. and Limão, N. (2008) A bargaining theory of inefficient redistribution policies. International Economic Review 49 (2): 621–657.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dunne, J.P. and Smith, R.P. (1984) The allocative efficiency of government expenditure: Some comparative tests. European Economic Review 20 (1–3): 381–394.

    Google Scholar 

  • Evenson, R. (2001) Economic impacts of agricultural research and extension. In: B. Gardner and G. Rausser (eds.) Handbook of Agricultural Economics. Vol. 1A. Amsterdam: Elsevier Science, pp. 573–628.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fan, S., Yu, B. and Saurkar, A. (2008) Public spending in developing countries: Trends, determination and impact. In: S. Fan (ed.) Public Expenditures, Growth, and Poverty. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press, pp. 20–55.

    Google Scholar 

  • Feeny, S. and McGillivray, M. (2010) Aid and public sector fiscal behaviour in failing states. Economic Modelling 27 (5): 1006–1016.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fernandez, R. and Rodrik, D. (1991) Resistance to reform: Status quo bias in the presence of individual-specific uncertainty. American Economic Review 81 (5): 1146–1155.

    Google Scholar 

  • Feyzioglu, T., Swaroop, V. and Zhu, M. (1998) A panel data analysis of the fungibility of foreign aid. World Bank Economic Review 12 (1): 29–58.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ghafoor, A., Weiss, J. and Jalilian, H. (2000) The impact of structural adjustment reforms on public sector expenditures: Evidence from developing countries. METU Studies in Development 27 (1–2): 119–132.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, G.M. and Helpman, E. (2001) Special Interest Politics. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gupta, S., de Mello, L. and Sharan, R. (2001) Corruption and military spending. European Journal of Political Economy 17 (4): 749–777.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gyimah-Brempong, K. (1998) The political economy of budgeting in Africa 1971–1991. Journal of Public Budgeting, Accounting and Financial Management 9 (4): 590–616.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harstad, B. and Svensson, J. (2011) Bribes, lobbying and development. American Political Science Review 105 (1): 46–63.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hicks, W.W. (1963) Estimating the foreign exchange costs of United Aid. Southern Economic Journal 30 (2): 168–174.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ismahan, M. and Ozkan, F.G. (2011) The political economy of public spending decisions and macroeconomic performance. International Journal of Economic Perspectives 5 (2): 163–174.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jayne, T. and Rashid, S. (2013) Input subsidy programmes in sub-Saharan Africa: A synthesis of recent evidence. Agricultural Economics 44 (6): 547–562.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, R.W.M. (1995) Modelling government processes and policies in agriculture: A review. Review of Marketing and Agricultural Economics 63 (3): 383–393.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keefer, P. and Khemani, S. (2005) Democracy, public expenditures and the poor: Understanding political incentives for providing public services. World Bank Research Observer 20 (1): 1–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keefer, P. and Knack, S. (2007) Boondoggles, rent-seeking and political checks and balances: Public investment under unaccountable governments. Review of Economics and Statistics 89 (3): 566–572.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krueger, A. (1996) Political economy of agricultural policy. Public Choice 87 (1–2): 173–175.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krueger, A., Schiff, M. and Valdes, A. (1988) Agricultural incentives in developing countries: Measuring the effects of sectoral and economy-wide policies. World Bank Economic Review 2 (3): 255–272.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Le Maux, B., Rocaboy, Y. and Goodspeed, T. (2011) Political fragmentation, party ideology and public expenditures. Public Choice 147 (1–2): 43–67.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lindert, P.H. (1991) Historical patterns of agricultural polity. In: C. Timmer (ed.) Agriculture and the State: Growth, Employment and Poverty in Developing Countries. Food Systems and Agrarian Change Series Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lipton, M. (1977) Why Poor People Stay Poor: Urban Bias in World Development. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mani, A. and Mukand, S. (2007) Democracy, visibility, and public good provision. Journal of Development Economics 83 (2): 506–529.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mauro, P. (1998) Corruption and the consumption of government expenditure. Journal of Public Economics 69 (2): 263–279.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moehler, D.C. (2010) Democracy, governance, and randomised development assistance. Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science 628 (1): 30–46.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mogues, T. and do Rosario, D. (2015) The political economy of public expenditures in agriculture: Applications of concepts to Mozambique. South African Journal of Economics 27 (3): 452–473.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mogues, T., Fan, S. and Benin, S. (2015) Public investments in and for agriculture. European Journal of Development Research 27 (3): 337–352.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mosley, P., Hudson, J. and Verschoor, A. (2004) Aid, poverty reduction and the new conditionality. Economic Journal 114 (496): 217–243.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mulligan, C., Gil, R. and Sala-i-Martin, X. (2004) Do democracies have different public policies than nondemocracies? Journal of Economic Perspectives 18 (1): 51–74.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Niskanen, W. (1971) Bureaucracy and Representative Government. Piscataway, NJ: Transaction Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Olper, A. (2001) Determinants of agricultural protection: The role of democracy and institutional setting. Journal of Agricultural Economics 52 (2): 75–92.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olper, A., Falkowski, J. and Swinnen, J. (2014) Political reforms and public policy: Evidence from agricultural and food policies. World Bank Economic Review 28 (1): 21–47.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M. (1965) The Logic of Collective Action. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M. (1985) Space, agriculture and organisation. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 67 (5): 928–937.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Omuru, E. and Kingwell, R. (2006) Funding and managing agricultural research in a developing country: A Papua New Guinea case study. International Journal of Social Economics 33 (4): 316–330.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pack, H. and Pack, J.R. (1990) Is foreign aid fungible? The case of Indonesia. Economic Journal 100 (399): 188–194.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pack, H. and Pack, J.R. (1993) Foreign aid and the question of fungibility. Review of Economics and Statistics 75 (2): 258–265.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Persson, T. and Tabellini, G. (2000) Political Economics: Explaining Economic Policy. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Proost, S. and Zaporozhets, V. (2013) The political economy of fixed regional public expenditure shares with an illustration for Belgian railway investments. Regional Science and Urban Economics 43 (5): 808–815.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rangarajan, M. (2009) Striving for a balance: Nature, power, science and India’s Indira Gandhi 1917–1984. Conservation and Society 7 (4): 299–312.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rinaudo, J.-D. (2002) Corruption and allocation of water: The case of public irrigation in Pakistan. Water Policy 4 (5): 405–422.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Singer, H.W. (1965) External aid: For plans or projects? Economic Journal 75 (299): 539–545.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Song, Z., Storesletten, K. and Zilibotti, F. (2012) Rotten parents and disciplined children: A politico-economic theory of public expenditure and debt. Econometrica 80 (6): 2785–2803.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Svolik, M. (2012) The Politics of Authoritarian Rule. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Swaroop, V., Jha, S. and Rajkumar, A.S. (2000) Fiscal effects of foreign aid in a federal system of governance: The case of India. Journal of Public Economics 77 (3): 307–330.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Swinnen, J.F.M., de Gorter, H., Rausser, G.C. and Banerjee, A.N. ((2000) The political economy of public research investment and commodity policies in agriculture: An empirical study. Agricultural Economics 22 (2): 111–122.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ting, M.M. (2012) Legislatures, bureaucracies, and distributive spending. American Political Science Review 106 (2): 367–385.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tridimas, G. (1999) A demand-theoretic analysis of public consumption priorities in the UK. Public Finance Review 27 (6): 599–623.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tridimas, G. (2001) The economics and politics of the structure of public expenditure. Public Choice 106 (3–4): 299–316.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Von Cramon-Taubadel, S. (1992) A critical assessment of the political preference function approach in agricultural economics. Agricultural Economics 7 (3–4): 371–394.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wade, R. (1982) The system of administrative and political corruption: Canal irrigation in South India. Journal of Development Studies 18 (3): 287–328.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Walker, T., Ryan, J. and Kelley, T. (2010) Impact assessment of policy-oriented international agricultural research: Evidence and insights from case studies. World Development 38 (10): 1453–1461.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Walter, H. and Wolff, B. (2002) Principal-agent problems in irrigation: Inviting rent-seeking and corruption. Quarterly Journal of International Agriculture 41 (1–2): 99–118.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weinstein, L. (2011) The politics of government expenditures in Tanzania, 1999–2007. African Studies Review 54 (1): 33–57.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • World Bank (2011) World development indicators. Washington DC: World Bank. http://data.worldbank.org/data-catalog/world-development-indicators, accessed 5 July 2011.

  • Zhang, X., Fan, S., Zhang, L. and Huang, J. (2004) Local governance and public goods provision in rural China. Journal of Public Economics 88 (12): 2857–2851.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Mogues, T. Political Economy Determinants of Public Spending Allocations: A Review of Theories, and Implications for Agricultural Public Investment. Eur J Dev Res 27, 452–473 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1057/ejdr.2015.35

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/ejdr.2015.35

Keywords

Navigation