Skip to main content
Log in

An Empirical Example of the Condorcet Paradox of Voting in a Large Electorate

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Social choice theory suggests that the occurrence of cyclical collective preferences should be a widespread phenomenon, especially in large groups of decision-makers. However, empirical research has so far failed to produce evidence of the existence of many real-world examples of such, and none in large electorates. This paper demonstrates the existence of a real cyclical majority in a poll of Danish voters' preferred prime minister, using pair-wise comparisons. This result is compared with those of a similar poll, but by using different voting methods, each resulting in different choices. The example demonstrates the empirical reality of cyclical collective preferences and the importance of the choice of institutions.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Arrow, K.J. (1951). Social choice and individual values, 2nd rev. edn. New Haven: Yale University Press, 1963.

    Google Scholar 

  • Black, D. (1958). The theory of committees and elections, 2nd rev. edn. Dordrecht: Kluwer, 1998.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blydenburgh, J.C. (1971). The closed rule and the paradox of voting. Journal of Politics 33: 57-71.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borre, O., and Andersen, J.G. (1997). Voting and political attitudes in Denmark: A study of the 1994 election. Aarhus: Aarhus University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Campbell, C. and Tullock, G. (1965). A measure of the importance of cyclical majorities. Economic Journal 75: 853-857.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chamberlain, J.R., Cohen, J.L. and Coombs, C.H. (1984). Social choice observed: Five presidential elections of the American Psychological Association. Journal of Politics 46: 479-502.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DeMeyer, F. and Plott, C.R. (1970). The probability of a cyclical majority. Econometrica 38: 345-354.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dobra, J.L. (1983). An approach to empirical studies of voting paradoxes: An update and extension. Public Choice 41: 241-250.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Downs, A. (1957). An economic theory of democracy. New York: Harper and Row.

    Google Scholar 

  • Feld, S.L. and Grofman, B. (1992): Who's afraid of the Big Bad Cycle? Evidence from 36 elections. Journal of Theoretical Politics 4: 231-237.

    Google Scholar 

  • Garman, M.B. and Kamien, M.I. (1968). The paradox of voting: Probability calculations. Behavioral Science 13: 306-316.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gehrlein, W.V. (1983). Condorcet's paradox. Theory and Decision 15: 161-197.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gehrlein, W.V. and Fishburn, P.C. (1976). The probability of the paradox of voting: A computable solution. Journal of Economic Theory 13: 14-25.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jamison, D.T. (1975). The probability of intransitive majority rule: An empirical study. Public Choice 23: 87-94.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jones, B., Radcliff, B., Taber, C. and Timpone, R. (1995). Condorcet winners and the paradox of voting: Probability calculations for weak preference orders. American Political Science Review 89: 137-147.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klahr, D. (1966). A computer simulation of the paradox of voting. American Political Science Review 60: 384-390.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kurrild-Klitgaard, P. (1996). Magt, demokrati og kollektive valgs rationalitet, AP 1996/4. København: Institut for Statskundskab. In U. Jakobsen and M. Kelstrup (Eds.), Demokrati: Teorier og Begreber. Copenhagen: Political Studies Press, forthcoming 1999.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lagerspaetz, E. (1993). Social choice in the real world. Scandinavian Political Studies 16: 1-23.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lagerspaetz, E. (1997). Social choice in the real world II: Cyclical preferences and strategic voting in the Finnish presidential elections. Scandinavian Political Studies 20: 53-67.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lewin, L. (1996). Votera eller Förhandla? Om Den Svenska Parlamentarismen. Stockholm: Fritzes.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lewin, L. (1998). Majoritarian and consensus democracy: The Swedish experience. Scandinavian Political Studies 21: 195-206.

    Google Scholar 

  • Niemi, R.G. (1970). The occurrence of the paradox of voting in university elections. Public Choice 8: 91-100.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Niemi, R.G. and Weisberg, H.F. (1968). A mathematical solution for the probability of the paradox of voting. Behavioral Science 13: 317-323

    Google Scholar 

  • Niemi, R.G. and Wright, S. (1987). Voting cycles and the structure of individual preferences. Social Choice and Welfare 4: 173-183.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Plott, C.R. (1976). Axiomatic social choice theory: An overview and interpretation. American Journal of Political Science 20: 511-596.

    Google Scholar 

  • Radcliff, B. (1994). Collective preferences in presidential elections. Electoral Studies 13: 50-57.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Riker, W.H. (1958). The paradox of voting and congressional rules for voting on amendments. American Political Science Review 52: 349-366.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Riker, W.H. (1965). Arrow's Theorem and some examples of the paradox of voting. In J.M. Claunch (Ed.), Mathematical applications in political science, Vol. I. Dallas: Southern Methodist University Press: 41-60.

    Google Scholar 

  • Riker, W.H. (1982). Liberalism against populism: A confrontation between the theory of democracy and the theory of social choice. Prospect Heights: Waveland Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Riker, W.H. (1986). The art of manipulation. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shepsle, K.A. (1979). Institutional arrangements and equilibrium in multidimensional voting models. American Journal of Political Science 23: 27-59.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shepsle, K.A. and Weingast, B.R. (1981). Structure-induced equilibrium and legislative choice. Public Choice 37: 503-519.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1967). Toward a mathematics of politics. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1981). Why so much stability? Public Choice 37: 189-202.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van Deemen., A.M.A. (1998a). The probability of the paradox of voting for weak preference orderings. Social Choice and Welfare forthcoming.

  • Van Deemen, A.M.A. (1998b). The Condorcet paradox: A review of research results. Paper presented at the Workshop on Empirical Social Choice, ECPR Joint Sessions, Warwick, March 23-28, 1998.

  • Van Deemen, A.M.A. and Vergunst, N.P. (1998). Empirical evidence of paradoxes of voting in Dutch elections. Public Choice 97: 475-490.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van den Doel, H. (1979). Democracy and welfare economics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vergunst, N.P. (1996). Besluitvorming over kerncentrale Borssele: Een analyse van de stemparadox in de Nederlandse politiek. Acta Politica 31: 209-228.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Kurrild-Klitgaard, P. An Empirical Example of the Condorcet Paradox of Voting in a Large Electorate. Public Choice 107, 135–145 (2001). https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1010304729545

Download citation

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1010304729545

Keywords

Navigation