Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-wzw2p Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-05-31T21:41:36.752Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

On fuzzy frontiers and fragmented foundations: some reflections on the original and new institutional economics

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  17 July 2014

GEOFFREY M. HODGSON*
Affiliation:
Hertfordshire Business School, University of Hertfordshire, Hatfield, Hertfordshire AL10 9AB, UK

Abstract

These reflections are prompted by the papers by Ménard (2014) and Ménard and Shirley (2014). Their essays centre on the path-breaking contributions to the ‘new institutional economics’ (NIE) by Ronald Coase, Douglass North and Oliver Williamson. In response, while recognising their substantial achievements, it is pointed out that these three thinkers had contrasting views on key points. Furthermore, Ménard's and Shirley's three ‘golden triangle’ NIE concepts – transaction costs, property rights and contracts – are themselves disputed. Once all this is acknowledged, differences of view appear within the NIE, raising interesting questions concerning its identity and boundaries, including its differences with the original institutionalism. There are sizeable overlaps between the two traditions. It is argued here that the NIE can learn from the original institutionalism, particularly when elaborating more dynamic analyses, and developing more nuanced, psychologically-grounded and empirically viable theories of human motivation.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Millennium Economics Ltd 2014 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Alchian, A. A. (1965), ‘Some Economics of Property Rights’, Il Politico, 30, pp. 816829; Alchian, A. A. (1977) Economic Forces at Work [Reprint], Indianapolis: Liberty Press.Google Scholar
Alchian, A. A. (1977), ‘Some Implications of Recognition of Property Right Transaction Costs’, in Brunner, K. (ed.), Economics and Social Institutions: Insights from the Conferences on Analysis and Ideology, Boston, MA: Martinus Nijhoff, pp. 234255.Google Scholar
Aldrich, H. E., Hodgson, G. M., Hull, D. L., Knudsen, T., Mokyr, J., and Vanberg, V. J. (2008), ‘In Defence of Generalized Darwinism’, Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 18 (5): 577596.Google Scholar
Allen, D. W. (1991), ‘What are Transaction Costs?’, Research in Law and Economics, 14, pp. 118.Google Scholar
Allen, D. W. (2000), ‘Transaction Costs’, in Bouckaert, B. and De Geest, G. (eds.), Encyclopedia of Law and Economics, Cheltenham and Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar, pp. 893926.Google Scholar
Allen, D. W. (2014), ‘The Coase Theorem: Coherent, Logical, and Not Disproved’, Journal of Institutional Economics, 112, doi: 10.1017/S1744137414000083, published online: 28 February 2014.Google Scholar
Aoki, M. (2001), Toward a Comparative Institutional Analysis, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arruñada, B. (2012), Institutional Foundations of Impersonal Exchange: Theory and Policy of Contractual Registries, Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Barzel, Y. (1985), ‘Transaction Costs: Are they Just Costs?’, Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 141 (1): 416.Google Scholar
Barzel, Y. (1994), ‘The Capture of Wealth by Monopolists and the Protection of Property Rights’, International Review of Law and Economics, 14 (4): 393409.Google Scholar
Barzel, Y. (1997), ‘Economic Analysis of Property Rights, 2nd edn., Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Biddle, J. E. and Samuels, W. J. (1998), ‘John R. Commons and the Compatibility of Neoclassical and Institutional Economics’, in Holt, R. P. F. and Pressman, S. (eds.), Economics and its Discontents: Twentieth Century Dissenting Economists, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, pp. 4055.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bowles, S. and Gintis, H. (2011), A Cooperative Species: Human Reciprocity and its Evolution, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Burns, E. M. (1931), ‘Does Institutionalism Complement or Compete with “Orthodox Economics”?’, American Economic Review, 21 (1): 8087.Google Scholar
Camerer, C. F. and Fehr, E. (2006), ‘When Does “Economic Man” Dominate Social Behavior?’, Science, 311: 4752.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Camic, C. and Hodgson, G. M. (eds.) (2011), Essential Writings of Thorstein Veblen, London and New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Carter, R. and Hodgson, G. M. (2006), ‘The Impact of Empirical Tests of Transaction Cost Economics on the Debate on the Nature of the Firm’, Strategic Management Journal, 27 (5): 461–76.Google Scholar
Clark, J. M. (1918), ‘Economics and Modern Psychology: Parts I and II’, Journal of Political Economy, 26 (1–2): 130, 136–166.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clark, J. M. (1923), Studies in the Economics of Overhead Costs, Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Coase, R. H. (1937), ‘The Nature of the Firm’, Economica, 4: 386405.Google Scholar
Coase, R. H. (1959), ‘The Federal Communications Commission’, Journal of Law and Economics, 2 (1): 140.Google Scholar
Coase, R. H. (1974), ‘The Market for Goods and the Market for Ideas’, American Economic Review (Papers and Proceedings), 64 (2): 384391.Google Scholar
Coase, R. H. (1984), ‘The New Institutional Economics’, Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 140: 229231.Google Scholar
Coase, R. H. (1988a), ‘The Nature of the Firm: Origin, Meaning, Influence’, Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 4 (1): 347.Google Scholar
Coase, R. H. (1988b), The Firm, the Market, and the Law, Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Coase, R. H. and Wang, N. (2012), How China Became Capitalist, London and New York: Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
Commons, J. R. (1924), Legal Foundations of Capitalism, New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Commons, J. R. (1931), ‘Institutional Economics’, American Economic Review, 21 (4): 648657.Google Scholar
Commons, J. R. (1934), Institutional Economics – Its Place in Political Economy, New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Cooley, C. H. (1902), Human Nature and the Social Order, New York: Scribner's.Google Scholar
Darwin, C. R. (1871), The Descent of Man, and Selection in Relation to Sex, 2 vols., London: Murray and New York: Hill.Google Scholar
David, R. J. and Han, S.-K. (2004), ‘A Systematic Assessment of the Empirical Support for Transaction Cost Economics’, Strategic Management Journal, 25 (1): 3958.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Deakin, S. (2012), ‘The Juridical Nature of the Firm’, in Thomas, C. and Douglas, B. (eds.), The Sage Handbook of Corporate Governance, London: Sage, pp. 113135.Google Scholar
Deakin, S., Gindis, D., Hodgson, G. M., Huang, K., and Pistor, K. (unpublished) ‘Legal Institutionalism: Capitalism and the Constitutive Role of Law’.Google Scholar
Dequech, D. (2002), ‘The Demarcation Between the “Old” and the “New” Institutional Economics: Recent Complications’, Journal of Economic Issues, 36 (2): 565572.Google Scholar
Director, A. (1964), ‘The Parity of the Economic Market Place’, Journal of Law and Economics, 7: 110.Google Scholar
Dosi, G., Freeman, C., Nelson, R., Silverberg, G., and Soete, L. L. G. (eds.) (1988), Technical Change and Economic Theory, London: Pinter.Google Scholar
Fischer, S. (1977), ‘Long-Term Contracting, Sticky Prices, and Monetary Policy: A Comment’, Journal of Monetary Economics, 3: 317323.Google Scholar
Fuller, L. L. (1964), The Morality of Law, New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Furubotn, E. G. and Richter, R. (1997), Institutions in Economic Theory: The Contribution of the New Institutional Economics, Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Gagliardi, F. (2009), ‘Financial Development and the Growth of Cooperative Firms’, Small Business Economics, 32 (4): 439464.Google Scholar
Gindis, D. (2009), ‘From Fictions and Aggregates to Real Entities in the Theory of the Firm’, Journal of Institutional Economics, 5 (1): 2546.Google Scholar
Greif, A., Milgrom, P. and Weingast, B. R. (1994), ‘Coordination, Commitment, and Enforcement: The Case of the Merchant Guild’, Journal of Political Economy, 102 (4): 745776.Google Scholar
Groenewegen, J., Kerstholt, F. and Nagelkerke, A. (1995), ‘On Integrating the New and Old Institutionalisms: Douglass North Building Bridges’, Journal of Economic Issues, 29 (2): 467475.Google Scholar
Hall, P. A. and Soskice, D. (eds.) (2001), Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Hamilton, W. H. (1918), ‘The Requisites of a National Food Policy’, Journal of Political Economy, 26 (6): 612637.Google Scholar
Hamilton, W. H. (1919), ‘The Institutional Approach to Economic Theory’, American Economic Review, 9: 309318.Google Scholar
Hamilton, W. H. (1923), ‘Review of H. D. Henderson's Supply and Demand’, American Economic Review, 13 (1): 9295.Google Scholar
Hamilton, W. H. (1944), ‘The Control of Strategic Materials’, American Economic Review, 34 (2): 261279.Google Scholar
Hansmann, H., Kraakman, R. and Squire, R. (2006), ‘Law and the Rise of the Firm’, Harvard Law Review, 119 (5): 13331403.Google Scholar
Hart, H. L. A. (1958), ‘Positivism and the Separation of Law and Morals’, Harvard Law Review, 71 (4): 593629.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. A. (1937), ‘Economics and Knowledge’, Economica, 4 (1): 3354.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. A. (1945), ‘The Use of Knowledge in Society’, American Economic Review, 35 (4): 519530.Google Scholar
Heinsohn, G. and Steiger, O. (2013) Ownership Economics: On the Foundations of Interest, Money, Markets, Business Cycles and Economic Development, translated and edited by Decker, Frank, London and New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Hodgson, G. M. (2000), ‘What is the Essence of Institutional Economics?’, Journal of Economic Issues, 34 (2): 317329.Google Scholar
Hodgson, G. M. (2001), How Economics Forgot History: The Problem of Historical Specificity in Social Science, London and New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Hodgson, G. M. (2002), ‘The Legal Nature of the Firm and the Myth of the Firm-Market Hybrid’, International Journal of the Economics of Business, 9 (1): 3760.Google Scholar
Hodgson, G. M. (2004), The Evolution of Institutional Economics: Agency, Structure and Darwinism in American Institutionalism, London and New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Hodgson, G. M. (2005), ‘Alfred Marshall versus the Historical School?’, Journal of Economic Studies, 32 (4): 331348.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hodgson, G. M. (2006), ‘What Are Institutions?’, Journal of Economic Issues, 40 (1): 125.Google Scholar
Hodgson, G. M. (2008a), ‘Markets’, in Durlauf, S. N. and Blume, L. E. (eds.), The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd edn., Basingstoke: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Hodgson, G. M. (2008b), ‘Markets’, in Davis, J. B. and Dolfsma, W. (eds.), The Elgar Companion to Social Economics, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, pp. 251266.Google Scholar
Hodgson, G. M. (2013), From Pleasure Machines to Moral Communities: An Evolutionary Economics Without Homo Economicus, Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Hodgson, G. M. (2015; in press), Conceptualizing Capitalism: Institutions, Evolution, Future, Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Hodgson, G. M. and Huang, K. (2013), ‘Brakes on Chinese Economic Development: Institutional Causes of a Growth Slowdown’, Journal of Economic Issues, 47 (3): 599622.Google Scholar
Hodgson, G. M. and Knudsen, T. (2010), Darwin's Conjecture: The Search for General Principles of Social and Economic Evolution, Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Honoré, A. M. (1961), ‘Ownership’, in Guest, A. G. (ed.), Oxford Essays in Jurisprudence, Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 107147.Google Scholar
Honoré, A. M. (2013), ‘Ownership’, reprinted in the Journal of Institutional Economics, 9 (2): 227255.Google Scholar
Klaes, M. (2000a), ‘The History of the Concept of Transaction Costs: Neglected Aspects’, Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 22 (2): 191216.Google Scholar
Klaes, M. (2000b), ‘The Birth of the Concept of Transaction Costs: Neglected Aspects’, Industrial and Corporate Change, 9 (4): 567593.Google Scholar
Langlois, R. N. (ed.) (1986), Economics as a Process: Essays in the New Institutional Economics, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Langlois, R. N. (1992), ‘Transaction Cost Economics in Real Time’, Industrial and Corporate Change, 1 (1): 99127.Google Scholar
Langlois, R. N. (2007), ‘The Entrepreneurial Theory of the Firm and the Theory of the Entrepreneurial Firm’, Journal of Management Studies, 44 (7): 11071124.Google Scholar
Lueck, D. and Miceli, T. J. (2007), ‘Property Law’, in Polinsky, A. M. and Shavell, S. (eds.), Handbook of Law and Economics, vol. 1, Amsterdam: Elsevier, 183257.Google Scholar
Marshall, A. (1920), Principles of Economics: An Introductory Volume, 8th edn., London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Marx, K. (1971), A Contribution to the Critique of Political Economy, translated from the German edition of 1859 London: Lawrence and Wishart.Google Scholar
Marx, K. (1975), Early Writings, London: Penguin.Google Scholar
Ménard, C. (1995), ‘Markets as Institutions versus Organizations as Markets? Disentangling Some Fundamental Concepts’, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 28 (2): 161182.Google Scholar
Ménard, C. (2014), ‘Embedding Organizational Arrangements: Towards a General ModelJournal of Institutional Economics, doi:10.1017/S1744137414000228, published online.Google Scholar
Ménard, C. and Shirley, M. M. (2005), ‘Introduction’, in Ménard, C. and Shirley, M. M. (eds.), Handbook of New Institutional Economics, Berlin: Springer, pp. 118.Google Scholar
Ménard, C. and Shirley, M. M. (2014), ‘The Future of new Institutional Economics: From Early Intuitions to a New Paradigm?’, Journal of Institutional Economics, doi:10.1017/S174413741400006X, published online.Google Scholar
Mitchell, W. C. (1969), Types of Economic Theory: From Mercantilism to Institutionalism, 2 vols., Dorfman, J. (ed.), New York: Augustus Kelley.Google Scholar
Mnookin, R. H. and Kornhauser, L. (1979), ‘Bargaining in the Shadow of the Law: The Case of Divorce’, Yale Law Journal, 88, 950997.Google Scholar
Nelson, R. R. (1996), Personal communication to G. Hodgson, dated 6 March 1996.Google Scholar
Nelson, R. R. and Winter, S. G. (1982), An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
North, D. C. (1977), ‘Markets and Other Allocation Systems in History: The Challenge of Karl Polanyi’, Journal of European Economic History, 6 (3): 703716.Google Scholar
North, D. C. (1990a), Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance, Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
North, D. C. (1990b), ‘A Transactions Cost Theory of Politics’, Journal of Theoretical Politics, 2 (4): 355367.Google Scholar
North, D. C. (1994), ‘Economic Performance through Time’, American Economic Review, 84 (3): 359367.Google Scholar
North, D. C., Wallis, J. J. and Weingast, B. R. (2009), Violence and Social Orders: A Conceptual Framework for Interpreting Recorded Human History, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Ostrom, E. (2004), ‘The Ten Most Important Books’, Tidsskriftet Politik, 4 (7): 3648.Google Scholar
Pipes, R. (1999), Property and Freedom, New York: Alfred A. Knopf.Google Scholar
Robé, J.-P. (2011), ‘The Legal Structure of the Firm’, Accounting, Economics, and Law, 1 (1): 186.Google Scholar
Rutherford, M. H. (2001), ‘Institutional Economics: Then and Now’, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 15 (3), 173194.Google Scholar
Rutherford, M. H. (2011), The Institutionalist Movement in American Economics, 1918–1947: Science and Social Control, Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Sent, E.-M. (1998) ‘Bounded Rationality’, in Davis, J., Hands, D. W. and Mäki, U. (eds.), The Handbook of Economic Methodology, Cheltenham and Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar, pp. 3640.Google Scholar
Stoelhorst, J. W. (2008), ‘The Explanatory Logic and Ontological Commitments of Generalized Darwinism’, Journal of Economic Methodology, 15 (4): 343363.Google Scholar
Stoelhorst, J. W. and Richerson, P. J. (2013), ‘A Naturalistic Theory of Economic Organization’, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 908: S45S56.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. E. (1975), Markets and Hierarchies: Analysis and Anti-Trust Implications: A Study in the Economics of Internal Organization, New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. E. (1980), ‘The Organization of Work: A Comparative Institutional Assessment’, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 1 (1): 538.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. E. (1985a), The Economic Institutions of Capitalism: Firms, Markets, Relational Contracting, London and New York: Free Press and Macmillan.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. E. (1985b), ‘Assessing Contract’, Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 1 (1): 177208.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. E. (1996), Review of Jack Vromen's Economic Evolution, Economic Journal, 106 (6): 17911793.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. E. (2000), ‘The New Institutional Economics: Taking Stock, Looking Ahead’, Journal of Economic Literature, 38 (3): 595613.Google Scholar