Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-c4f8m Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-20T03:21:34.876Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Institutional complementarities, intellectual property rights and technology in the knowledge economy

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  28 December 2015

ERKAN GÜRPINAR*
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, Social Sciences University of Ankara, Ankara, Turkey

Abstract

This essay explores the trade-off between strong and weak intellectual property rights inside firms with reference to the importance of job termination. The probability of job termination has an effect on the relative profitability of different intellectual property rights regimes. Weak intellectual property rights may make it more attractive for skilled workers to join the firm, which will increase its profits while employing workers. However, when a job match is terminated the firm is left with the ownership of intellectual property only under a strong intellectual property rights regime. Based on the institutional complementarities approach we develop a simple model that analyses this trade-off, in which multiple organisational equilibria exist. We show that when intellectual property rights are taken into account, expectations such as increase in the skill and knowledge content of work are not inevitable in the knowledge economy.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Millennium Economics Ltd 2015 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Adler, P. and Borys, B. (1996), ‘Two Types of Bureaucracy: Enabling and Coercive’, Administrative Science Quarterly, 41 (1): 6189.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aoki, M. (2001), Toward a Comparative Institutional Analysis, Cambridge: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Archer, R. (1996), ‘The Philosophical Case for Economic Democracy’, in Pagano, U. and Rowthorn, R. (eds.), Democracy and Efficiency in the Economic Enterprise, London: Routledge, pp. 1335.Google Scholar
Arrow, K. (1962), ‘Economic Welfare and the Allocation of Resources for Invention’, reprinted in Lamberton, D. M. (1971) (ed.), The Economics of Information and Knowledge, Harmondsworth: Penguin, pp. 141159.Google Scholar
Besen, S. M. and Raskind, L. J. (1991), ‘An Introduction to the Law and Economics of Intellectual Property’, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 5 (1): 327.Google Scholar
Bok, D. (2003), Universities in the Marketplace: The Commercialization of Higher Education, Princeton: Princeton Univ. Press.Google Scholar
Boldrin, M. and Levine, D. (2008), Against Intellectual Monopoly, Available online at http://www.dklevine.com/general/intellectual/againstfinal.htm.Google Scholar
Bowles, S. and Gintis, H. (1996), ‘Is the Demand for Workplace Democracy Redundant in a Liberal Economy?’ in Pagano, U. and Rowthorn, R. (eds.), Democracy and Efficiency in the Economic Enterprise, London: Routledge, pp. 6481.Google Scholar
Braverman, H. (1974), Labor and Monopoly Capital, New York: Monthly Review Press.Google Scholar
Chang, H.-J. (2001), ‘Intellectual Property Rights and Economic Development: Historical Lessons and Emerging Issues’, Journal of Human Development and Capabilities, 2 (2): 287309.Google Scholar
Chang, H.-J. (2002), Kicking Away the Ladder, London: Anthem.Google Scholar
Coriat, B. and Weinstein, O. (2011), ‘Patent Regimes and the Commodification of Knowledge’, LEM Working Paper Series, 2011/17.Google Scholar
Fisk, C. (1998), ‘Removing the Fuel of Interest from the Fire of Genius: Law and the Employee-Inventor, 1830–1930’, University of Chicago Law Review, 65 (4): 11271198.Google Scholar
Fisk, C. (2001), ‘Working Knowledge: Trade Secrets, Restrictive Covenants in Employment, and the Rise of Corporate Intellectual Property, 1800–1920’, Hastings Law Journal, 52: 441535.Google Scholar
Gagliardi, F. (2014), ‘A Bibliometric Analysis of the Literature on Institutional Complementarities’, Mimeo.Google Scholar
Hall, P. and Soskice, D. (2001), Varieties of Capitalism, Oxford: Oxford Univ. Press.Google Scholar
Hodgson, G. (1999), Economics and Utopia, London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Jaffe, A. and Lerner, J. (2004), Innovation and Its Discontents, Princeton: Princeton Univ. Press.Google Scholar
Landini, F. (2012), ‘Technology, Property Rights and Organizational Diversity in the Software Industry’, Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 23 (2): 137150.Google Scholar
Lessig, L. (2004), Free Culture, USA: Penguin Press.Google Scholar
Machlup, F. and Penrose, E. (1950), ‘The Patent Controversy in the Nineteenth Century’, Journal of Economic History, 10 (1): 129.Google Scholar
Merges, R. P. (1999), ‘The Law and Economics of Employee Invention’, Harvard Journal of Law and Technology, 13 (1): 154.Google Scholar
Milgrom, P. and Roberts, J. (1990), ‘The Economics of Modern Manufacturing: Technology, Strategy and Organization’, American Economic Review, 80 (3): 511528.Google Scholar
Moody, G. (2001), Rebel Code: Inside Linux and the Open Source Revolution, New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Nelson, R. (1959), ‘The Simple Economics of Basic Scientific Research’, Journal of Political Economy, 67 (3): 297306.Google Scholar
Orsi, F. and Coriat, B. (2006), ‘The New Role and Status of Intellectual Property Rights in Contemporary Capitalism’, Competition and Change, 10 (2): 162179.Google Scholar
Pagano, U. (1993), ‘Organizational Equilibria and Institutional Stability,’ in Bowles, S., Gintis, H. and Gustafson, B. (eds.), Markets and Democracy: Participation, Accountability and Efficiency, Cambridge: Cambridge Univ. Press, pp. 86115.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pagano, U. (2007a), ‘Positional Goods and Asymmetric Development’, in Yotopolus, P. and Romano, D. (eds.), The Asymmetries of Globalization, Oxford, UK and New York: Routledge, pp. 2847.Google Scholar
Pagano, U. (2007b), ‘Cultural Globalization, Institutional Diversity and the Unequal Accumulation of Intellectual Capital’, Cambridge Journal of Economics, 31 (5): 649667.Google Scholar
Pagano, U. and Nicita, A. (2002), ‘Finance and Technology: A Comparative Institutional Analysis of the Firm’, Quaderni del Dipartimento di Economia Politica e Statistica, Universita di Siena, Working Paper No. 361.Google Scholar
Pagano, U. and Rossi, M. A. (2004), ‘Incomplete Contracts, Intellectual Property and Institutional Complementarities’, European Journal of Law and Economics, 18 (1): 5576.Google Scholar
Pagano, U. and Rossi, M. A. (2011), ‘Property Rights in the Knowledge Economy: An Explanation of the Crisis’, Quaderni del Dipartimento di Economia Politica e Statistica, Universita di Siena, Working Paper No. 586.Google Scholar
Pagano, U. and Rowthorn, R. (1994), ‘Ownership, Technology and Institutional Stability’, Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 5 (2): 221242.Google Scholar
Rowthorn, R. (1974), ‘Neo-Classicism, Neo-Ricardianism and Marxism’, New Left Review, I/86: 6387.Google Scholar
Salzberger, E. M. (2011), ‘The Dominant Law and Economics Paradigm Regarding “Intellectual Property” – a Vehicle or an Obstacle for Innovation, Growth and Progress?’, The Ratio Institute, Working Paper No. 177.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, J. A. [1942] (1954), Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy, London: Allen & Unwin.Google Scholar
Screpanti, E. (2001), The Fundamental Institutions of Capitalism, London and New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Taylor, F. W. (1911), The Principles of Scientific Management, New York and London: Harper & Brothers.Google Scholar
Zuboff, S. (1989), In the Age of the Smart Machine, New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar