Skip to main content
Log in

The Costs of Control-enhancing Mechanisms: How Regulatory Dualism Can Create Value in the Privatisation of State-owned Firms in Europe

  • Articles
  • Published:
European Business Organization Law Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Empirical studies show that ownership structures that separate control and cash flow rights create agency problems and are associated with reduced value for minority shareholders. Institutional investors recognise these inefficiencies and expect a discount on the share price of companies with control-enhancing mechanisms like multiple voting rights shares or pyramidal ownership structures.

In the US, corporate pyramids are discouraged through the taxation of intercompany dividends, whereas multiple voting rights shares are allowed but have to be issued before the firm goes public. Therefore, controlling shareholders who want to entrench themselves in control by retaining multiple voting rights shares pay the costs of this inefficient capital structure when the firm initially goes public at a discounted price.

Some European countries — including Spain, Portugal, Greece and, until very recently, Italy — have adopted a diametrically opposite solution. Multiple voting rights shares have been expressly prohibited by the legislator, but corporate pyramids are commonly used by listed companies and can be created following the IPO of the firm without approval from the shareholders. In this situation, if institutional investors expect that a pyramidal ownership structure will be created in the future, they will discount the price of the shares when the firm goes public. Therefore, if Italy, Spain, Portugal and Greece are willing to privatise some of their state-owned companies and want to maximise the price of their stocks, they should create the conditions to assure the market that these companies will not be controlled through pyramids in the future.

Because of strong opposition from national business elites which control the largest corporate groups, it is very difficult to adopt strict regulations aimed at prohibiting — or at least limiting — the use of pyramidal ownership structures in a relatively short period of time. In order to solve this Olson problem, I suggest that Italy, Spain, Portugal and Greece should use regulatory dualism to create new markets with enhanced corporate governance rules that prevent shareholders’ control through pyramids.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  1. Rafael La Porta, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, Andrei Shleifer and Robert Vishny, ‘Investor Protection and Corporate Valuation’, 57 Journal of Finance (2002) p. 1147.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  2. Lucian A. Bebchuk and Assaf Hamdani, ‘The Elusive Quest for Global Governance Standards’, 157 University of Pennsylvania Law Review (2009) p. 1269.

    Google Scholar 

  3. See Ford Motor Company, Notice of 2014 Annual Meeting of Shareholders and Proxy Statement, available at: <http://corporate.ford.com/doc/457/143/ir_2014_proxy.pdf>.

  4. Google Inc., Notice of 2014 Annual Meeting of Stockholders, available at: <http://investor.google.com/pdf/2014_google_proxy_statement.pdf>.

  5. Facebook Inc., 2014 Proxy Statement, available at: <http://investor.fb.com/annual-proxy.cfm>.

  6. Berkshire Hathaway Inc., 2013 Annual Report, available at: <http://www.berkshirehathaway.com/2013ar/2013ar.pdf>.

  7. Only very recently, through Law Decree No. 91, dated 24 June 2014, converted into Law No. 116, dated 11 August 2014, did Italy remove the prohibition to issue multiple voting rights shares.

  8. According to the theory elaborated by Mancur Olson, small groups can act to advance their common interest more easily than large ones. Large groups face collective action problems that reduce their ability to act in furtherance of their interest. On the other hand, members of small groups receive a higher per capita participation in the benefits of their common action and therefore have lower cost in organising their efforts. Therefore, in some situations, special interest lobbies are able to advance their benefits even if the measures advocated are inefficient for the market and the economy. See Mancur Olson, The Rise and Decline of Nations (Yale University Press 1982); Jac C. Heckelman, ‘Explaining the Rain: The Rise and Decline of Nations After 25 Years’, 74 Southern Economic Journal (2007) p. 18, at pp. 30–31 (reporting that a quarter century after ‘publication of The Rise and Decline of Nations, a large literature has evolved debating many of the ideas and issues initially developed in Olson’s book. Overall, the bulk of the evidence from over 50 separate studies favors Olson’s theory of institutional sclerosis’).

    Google Scholar 

  9. Lucian A. Bebchuk, Reinier Kraakman and George Triantis, ‘Stock Pyramids, Cross-ownership, and Dual Class Equity: The Creation and Agency Costs of Separating Control from Cash Flow Rights’, in Randall K. Morck, ed., Concentrated Corporate Ownership (University of Chicago Press 2000) p. 295, at p. 301.

  10. Ibid., at pp. 301–302.

  11. Ibid., at pp. 302–303; Rafael La Porta, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, Andrei Shleifer and Robert W. Vishny, ‘Agency Problems and Dividend Policies Around the World’, 55 Journal of Finance (2000) p. 1.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  12. Lucian A. Bebchuk, ‘Efficient and Inefficient Sales of Corporate Control’, 109 Quarterly Journal of Economics (1994) p. 957.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  13. In freezeout transactions — also known as ‘going-private transactions’ or ‘squeeze-outs’ — the controlling shareholder buys out the shares of the minority by means of cash compensation. See Guhan Subramanian, ‘Fixing Freezeouts’, 115 Yale Law Journal (2005) p. 2.

    Google Scholar 

  14. See Bebchuk, supra n. 14, at pp. 983–984 (noting that if freezeouts are not allowed some efficient transfers ‘may well fail due to the free-rider problem’ even in legal regimes governed by the market rule).

  15. For an example showing the interests misalignment between a controlling shareholder and the minority investors in negotiating the sale of the company to a third party when CEMs are in place, see In re Delphi Financial Group Shareholder Litigation, 2012 WL 729232 (Del. Ch. Mar. 6, 2012). The litigation arose in a merger context where the controller of the company tried to negotiate a higher price for his multiple voting rights shares (the Class B Common Stock) despite a charter provision which provided for a mechanism aimed at granting all shareholders the right to sell their common shares (the Class A Common Stock) at the same price offered to the controller for its Class B Common Stock.

  16. Bebchuk, Kraakman and Triantis, supra n. 11, at p. 301 (‘Unlike in [dispersed ownership] structures, where controlling management may have little equity but can be displaced, the controllers of … companies [adopting CEMs] face neither proxy contests nor hostile takeovers’).

  17. Ibid. at p. 305: ‘The fact that CMS structures [i.e., controlling-minority structures or CEMs] can impose significant agency costs is well known, even if the magnitude of these costs is not. It follows that CMS controllers who return to the equity market must pay a price for the expected agency cost of CMS structures unless they can establish a reputation for sound management.’ See also Ronald J. Gilson, ‘Controlling Family Shareholders in Developing Countries: Anchoring Relational Exchanges’, 60 Stanford Law Review (2007) p. 633, at p. 648.

    Google Scholar 

  18. Ronald J. Gilson and Alan Schwartz, ‘Constraints on Private Benefits of Control: Ex Ante Control Mechanisms Versus Ex Post Transaction Review’, 169 Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics (2013) p. 160.

  19. Ibid., at p. 162. See also Ronald J. Gilson and Alan Schwartz, Report Concerning Recommendations of the Committee on Enhancing Competitiveness, at pp. 7–8 (1 December 2011), available at: <http://mof.gov.il/Lists/CompetitivenessCommittee_2/Attachments/96/Gilson.pdf>: [C]ontrolling shareholders are an effective alternative to market policing of the agency cost of managerial lack of diligence and poor performance that result from the specialization of risk bearing and management. Pyramids, and other means of expanding the reach of a controlling shareholder’s authority, thus capture economies of scale associated with monitoring management’s diligence and performance.

  20. See Suman Banerjee and Ronald Masulis, ‘Ownership, Investment and Governance: The Costs and Benefits of Dual Class Shares’ (2013), at p. 38, available at: <http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2182849> (‘[I]f a firm requires outside financing to undertake profitable investment projects, then in some cases managers will find separation of the voting and dividend claim optimal’).

  21. Alessio M. Pacces, ‘Featuring Control Power: Corporate Law and Economics Revisited’ (2008), at p. 13, available at: <http://ssrn.com/abstract=1089406> (‘Entrepreneurs concerned with idiosyncratic private benefits may only go public with an ownership structure that supports ongoing exercise of corporate control and its protection from hostile takeover.’); John C. Coates IV, ‘Ownership, Takeovers and EU Law: How Contestable Should EU Corporation Be?’, in Guido Ferrarini, et al., eds., Reforming Company Law and Takeover Law in Europe (Oxford University Press 2004) p. 677, at p. 690, arguing that in situations where the ‘break-through’ rule applies and the board cannot take defensive measures against hostile takeovers, ‘both existing or new public firms that have both a conventional one-share/one-vote structure and a single (or small group) of controlling shareholders may simply turn down net present value projects if they would require the shareholders to put their control at risk.’

  22. Institutional Shareholder Services, Sherman & Sterling and the European Corporate Governance Institute, Report on the Proportionality Principle in the European Union (2008), at p. 6, available at: <http://ec.europa.eu/internal_market/company/docs/shareholders/study/final_report_en.pdf>.

  23. Lucian A. Bebchuk, Corporate Pyramids in the Israeli Economy: Problems and Policies: A Report Prepared for the Committee on Increasing Competitiveness in the Economy (March 2012), at p. 4, available at: <http://www.financeisrael.mof.gov.il/financeisrael/Docs/En/ublica-tions/opinion_2.pdf> (‘Final Report’): Corporate pyramids are closely related to dual-class stock companies. They are both mechanisms which separate cash flow rights and voting rights, and which enable a party to control corporate assets while contributing only a minority (and sometimes a small minority) of the equity capital funding these assets. Indeed, in some situations, a pyramid and a dual-class stock structure would produce an economically identical result.

  24. Rafael La Porta, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes and Andrei Shleifer, ‘Corporate Ownership Around the World’, 54 Journal of Finance (1999) p. 471, at p. 501; Belén Villalonga and Raphael Amit, ‘How Are U.S. Family Firms Controlled?’, 22 Review of Financial Studies (2009) p. 3047, at pp. 3075–3076 (using as a sample all the firms that were listed in the Fortune 500 in the period 1994–2000, they found that only eleven firms exhibited pyramidal ownership); Ronald W. Masulis, Peter Kien Pham and Jason Zein, ‘Family Business Groups Around the World: Financing Advantages, Control Motivations, and Organizational Choices’, 24 Review of Financial Studies (2011) p. 3556, at p. 3570 (Table 2) (in 2002, only 1.03 percent of all US public companies were controlled through a pyramidal structure).

    Article  Google Scholar 

  25. Mark J. Roe, Strong Managers, Weak Owners: A Political Theory of American Corporate Finance (Princeton Univerity Press 1994), at p. 107 (reporting that ‘the New Deal Congress taxed dividends to dismantle complex corporate structures. It is a part of a pattern from antitrust and financial regulation that seeks fragmentation and arm’s-length dealing and has continuing effects today’); Randall Morck, ‘How to Eliminate Pyramidal Business Groups — The Double Taxation of Inter-Corporate Dividends and Other Incisive Uses of Tax Policy’, 19 Tax Policy and the Economy (2005) p. 135; Randall Morck and Bernard Yeung, ‘Dividend Taxation and Corporate Governance’, 19 Journal of Economic Perspectives (2005) p. 163; see also Randall Morck, ‘The Riddle of the Great Pyramids’, in Asli M. Colpan and Takashi Hikino, eds., The Oxford Handbook of Business Groups (Oxford University Press 2009).

    Google Scholar 

  26. See Steven Bank and Brian R. Cheffins, ‘The Corporate Pyramid Fable’, 84 Business History Review (2010) p. 435, at p. 458 (finding evidence that ‘in the case of utilities, the one sector where pyramids were commonplace, regulation, namely the Public Utility Holding Company Act of 1935, was pivotal’); Paul G. Mahoney, ‘The Public Utility Pyramid’, 41 Journal of Legal Studies (2012) p. 37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  27. Eugene Kandel, Konstantin Kosenko, Randall Morck and Yishay Yafeh, ‘Business Groups in the United States: A Revised History of Corporate Ownership, Pyramids and Regulation, 1930–1950’ (14 November 2013), available at: <http://www.nber.org/papers/w1969>.

  28. Paul A. Gompers, Joy Ishii and Andrew Metrick, ‘Extreme Governance: An Analysis of Dual-Class Firms in the United States’, 23 Review of Financial Studies (2010) p. 1051, at p. 1057.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  29. See Villalonga and Amit, supra n. 26, at p. 3066; Gompers, Ishii and Metrick, supra n. 30, at p. 1056: ‘On average, the insiders of dual-class firms own a majority of the voting rights (about 60%) and a significant minority of the cash-flow rights (about 40%). Nearly all of these voting rights come from the superior voting class stock: less than 15% of the insiders’ voting rights come from the inferior voting class.’

  30. See Ford Motor Company, supra n. 3, at p. 3.

  31. The ‘one share-one vote’ principle was not absolute and without exceptions in these countries. In Italy and Spain, for example, multiple voting rights shares were expressly prohibited, but companies were allowed to issue non-voting shares having a par value up to half of their nominal share’s capital. See Article 2351 of the Italian Civil Code before the amendment provided by Law Decree No. 91, dated 24 June 2014, converted into Law No. 116, dated 11 August 2014; Mara Faccio and Larry H. P. Lang, ‘The Ultimate Ownership in Western European Corporations’, 65 Journal of Financial Economics (2002) p. 365, at pp. 386–387; Marcello Bianchi and Magda Bianco, ‘Italian Corporate Governance in the Last 15 Years: From Pyramids to Coalitions?’, ECGI Finance Working Paper No. 144. (2006), at pp. 10–12, available at: <http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=952147> (‘In 2005 only 14% of the [Italian] companies issued non voting shares; their value was 4% of total shares on the market’).

    Article  Google Scholar 

  32. See Institutional Shareholder Services, Sherman & Sterling and the European Corporate Governance Institute, supra n. 24; OECD Steering Group on Corporate Governance, ‘Lack of Proportionality Between Ownership and Control: Overview and Issues for Discussion’ (2007), at p. 21, available at: <http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/21/32/40038351.pdf>; Deminor Rating, ‘Application of the One Share-One Vote Principle in Europe’ (2005), survey commissioned by the Association of British Insurers, available at: <http://va.issproxy.com/resourcecenter/publications/European_General_Reports/ABI_DEMINOR_full%20report.pdf>.

  33. See Article 2351 of the Italian Civil Code as amended by Law Decree No. 91, dated 24 June 2014, converted into Law No. 116, dated 11 August 2014.

  34. Three major reforms have mainly contributed to the improvement of Italian corporate governance regulation. The Financial Markets Consolidated Act (also called Legge Draghi) of 1998 provided for an extensive reform of listed companies’ corporate governance and disclosure requirements. The reform of companies’ law (Riforma del diritto societario) of 2003 implemented an organic reorganisation and improvement of the rules applicable to Italian companies. The Investor Protection Act (Legge sul Risparmio) of 2005 has generally enhanced minority shareholder protection. See Luca Enriques, ‘Corporate Governance Reforms in Italy: What Has Been Done and What Is Left To Do’, 10 European Business Organization Law Review (2009) p. 477; Marcello Bianchi, Magda Bianco and Luca Enriques, ‘Pyramidal Groups and the Separation Between Ownership and Control in Italy’, in Fabrizio Barca and Marco Becht, eds., The Control of Corporate Europe (Oxford University Press 2001) p. 154, at pp. 183–184; Guido Ferrarini, ‘Corporate Governance Changes in the 20th Century: A View from Italy’, ECGI Law Working Paper No. 29 (2005); Francesca Cuomo, Alessandro Zattoni and Giovanni Valentini, ‘The Effects of Legal Reforms on the Ownership Structure of Listed Companies’, Industrial and Corporate Change (2012) p. 22 (their ‘results show that [in Italy, in 1985–2005,] an increase in the protection of investors’ rights is associated with a decrease in the use of CEMs and in the separation between control and cash flow rights’).

    Article  Google Scholar 

  35. Consob, 2013 Report on Corporate Governance of Italian Listed Companies (2013), at p. 9 (Table 1.16), available at: <http://www.consob.it/main/consob/pubblicazioni/report/rapporto_cg/index.html> (at the end of 2012, 16.2% of the Italian listed companies — representing 54.3% of the overall market capitalisation — were controlled through pyramids in which at least one listed company controlled another listed company). On the relevance of corporate pyramids in Italy, see also La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes and Shleifer, supra n. 26, at p. 501; Institutional Shareholder Services, Sherman & Sterling and the European Corporate Governance Institute, supra n. 24, at pp. 59–61 (in 2008, 9 of the 20 largest Italian listed companies feature a pyramid structure); Bianchi and Bianco, supra n. 34, at pp. 10–12 (noting that, even if they have decreased in number and in depth, ‘pyramidal groups are still a relevant feature of Italian listed companies ownership structure’); Faccio and Lang, supra n. 34, at pp. 389–391.

  36. Faccio and Lang, supra n. 34, at p. 389; María Sacristán-Navarro and Silvia Gómez-Ansón, ‘Family Ownership and Pyramids in the Spanish Market’, 20 Family Business Review (2007) p. 247, at pp. 256 (using a sample of 195 companies listed on Spanish stock markets at the end of 2002, they found that ‘for the total sample, 26.66% of the firms (36.6% of closely held firms) present pyramidal structures’).

    Article  Google Scholar 

  37. Institutional Shareholder Services, Sherman & Sterling and the European Corporate Governance Institute, supra n. 24, at pp. 71–72 (the four big listed companies controlled through pyramidal ownership structures are: Abertis (Industrials), ACS (Industrials), FCC (Industrials) and Gas Natural (Oil & Gas)); see also La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes and Shleifer, supra n. 26, at p. 501.

  38. Faccio and Lang, supra n. 34, at p. 389.

  39. Institutional Shareholder Services, Sherman & Sterling and the European Corporate Governance Institute, supra n. 24, at pp. 49–50 (‘Pyramid structures were identified in 15% of large companies and 64% of recently listed companies’).

  40. Magnus Henrekson and Ulf Jakobsson, ‘The Swedish Corporate Control Model: Convergence, Persistence or Decline?’, 20 Corporate Governance: An International Review (2012) p. 212, at p. 213.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  41. Institutional Shareholder Services, Sherman & Sterling and the European Corporate Governance Institute, supra n. 24, at pp. 74–76; Clas Bergstrom and Kristian Rydqvist, ‘Ownership of Equity in Dual Class Firms’, 14 Journal of Banking and Finance (1990) p. 237, at p. 260 (in Sweden ‘the proportion listed dual-class firms has increased from 32% in 1968 to 74% of the listed firms in 1986’).

    Article  Google Scholar 

  42. Peter Högfeldt, ‘The History and Politics of Corporate Ownership in Sweden’, in Randall K. Morck, ed., A History of Corporate Governance Around the World: Family Business Groups to Professional Managers (University of Chicago Press 2005) p. 517, at p. 538. But see also Henrekson and Jakobsson, supra n. 43, at p. 220 (noting that even if ‘the traditional Swedish corporate control model based on “old capital” and a large wedge between control rights and cash-flow rights … is still dominant on the SSE [the Stockholm Stock Exchange] … [in the last years] there is far less pyramiding and use of dual-class shares’).

  43. Shmuel Hauser and Beni Lauterbach, ‘The Value of Voting Rights to Majority Shareholders: Evidence from Dual-class Stock Unifications’, 17 Review of Financial Studies (2004) p. 1167, at p. 1169.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  44. Ibid., at p. 1169; Beni Lauterbach and Yishay Yafeh, ‘Long Term Changes in Voting Power and Control Structure Following the Unification of Dual Class Shares’, 17 Journal of Corporate Finance (2011) p. 215.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  45. Lauterbach and Yafeh, supra n. 47, at p. 216: Following this regulatory change, by the year 2000, over 80 of the 109 dual class firms listed on the TASE in 1990 unified their shares. Most of the remaining dual class firms were delisted, merged or unified their shares in recent years, so that by the beginning of 2009 dual class stocks have become almost extinct. (Only seven dual class share firms still trade).

  46. Ibid., at p. 227 (‘Business groups, a common feature in Israel’s economic landscape, have not been used to replace dual class shares’).

  47. Bebchuk, supra n. 25, at p. 4. See also Konstantin Kosenko, ‘Evolution of Business Groups in Israel: Their Impact at the Level of the Firm and the Economy’, 5 Israel Economic Review (2007) p. 55: Using panel data on 650 public companies from 1995 to 2006, [he identifies] twenty major business groups controlling about 160 listed companies and close to a half of total stock market capitalization, while the 10 largest groups’ segment of the market capitalization is among the largest in the western world and amounts to 30 percent. These groups are family-controlled and highly diversified across different industries with common pyramidal structure of ownership: roughly 80 percent of all group-affiliated companies belong to business pyramids.

    Google Scholar 

  48. See Committee on Increasing Competitiveness in the Economy, Press Release of 18 February 2012, available at: <http://www.financeisrael.mof.gov.il/FinanceIsrael/Docs/En/publications/PressRelease.pdf>.

  49. Lucian A. Bebchuk and Mark J. Roe, ‘A Theory of Path Dependence in Corporate Ownership and Governance’, 52 Stanford Law Review (1999) p. 127; Ronald J. Gilson, ‘Controlling Shareholders and Corporate Governance: Complicating the Comparative Taxonomy’, 119 Harvard Law Review (2006) p. 1642, at pp. 1644–1645; Ronald J. Gilson, ‘Corporate Governance and Economic Efficiency: When Do Institutions Matter?’, 74 Washington University Law Quarterly (1996) p. 327, at p. 332: [T]he path dependent characteristics of a given national governance system confront the disciplining effects of the operative selection mechanisms. In the end, institutions are shaped by a form of corporate governance plate tectonics, in which the demands of current circumstances grind against the influence of initial conditions.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  50. Ronald W. Masulis, Cong Wang and Fei Xie, ‘Agency Problems at Dual-class Companies’, 64 Journal of Finance (2009) p. 1697, at p. 1722. See also IRRC Institute and Institutional Shareholder Services, Controlled Companies in the Standard & Poor’s 1500: A Ten Year Performance and Risk Review (2012), at p. 3, available at: <http://irrcinstitute.org/pdf/FINAL-Controlled-Company-ISS-Report.pdf> (using S&P 1500 firms as a sample, the study found that ‘[c]ontrolled firms with single-class capital structures outperformed those with multiclass capital structures and non-controlled firms over the three-, five-, and 10-year periods ended Aug. 31, 2012’); Gompers, Ishii and Metrick, supra n. 30, at p. 1084, ‘[i]n a series of single-stage regressions, find that firm value is positively associated with insiders’ cash-flow rights and negatively associated with insiders’ voting rights, and negatively associated with the wedge between the two’; Scott B. Smart, Ramabhadran S. Thirumalai and Chad J. Zutter, ‘What’s in a Vote? The Short- and Long-run Impact of Dual Class Equity on IPO Firm Values’, 45 Journal of Accounting and Economics (2008) p. 94, at p. 113 (their ‘results suggest that investors discount dual-class shares because the superior voting rights held by insiders make it difficult for outsiders to replace incumbents’); Vishaal Baulkaran, ‘Management Entrenchment and the Valuation Discount of Dual Class Firms’, 54 Quarterly Journal of Economics and Finance (2013) p. 70, at p. 80 (‘[T]the paper finds that investors are concerned with the negative effects of managerial entrenchment and therefore, attach a lower value to dual class companies’).

    Article  Google Scholar 

  51. Institutional Shareholders Services, ‘The Tragedy of the Dual Class Commons’ (13 February 2012), available at: <http://online.wsj.com/public/resources/documents/facebook0214.pdf>. For similar comments about Google’s IPO, see Simon London, ‘U.S. Pension Fund Criticizes Google’s IPO Structure’, Financial Times, 4 May 2004, available at: <http://www.nbcnews.com/id/4900355/#.UTuos6XT0jQ>: TIAA-Cref, the New York-based teachers’ pension fund with $300 billion under management, said that corporate governance weaknesses would be reflected in the price it was willing to pay for Google stock. ‘There should be a substantial discount for corporate governance deficiencies,’ said Peter Clapman, senior vice-president and chief counsel for corporate governance.

  52. See Ronald J. Gilson, ‘Evaluating Dual Class Common Stock: The Relevance of Substitutes’, 73 Virginia Law Review (1987) p. 807, at p. 828: Dominant shareholders of [companies in growing markets with large additional cash flow needs] are faced with a dilemma. If they finance growth by further sales of an existing single class of common stock, their control of the firm will be diluted. But if they avoid dilution by purchasing enough new shares themselves to retain the same percentage of ownership they will suffer an uncompensated increase in the unsystematic risk of their investment in the company. In either event, this form of financing growth imposes a cost on dominant shareholders that is not shared by public shareholders.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  53. See for similar considerations William T. Allen, Comments Respectfully Submitted to the Committee for Increasing Competitiveness of the Economy of the State of Israel (24 November 2011), at p. 5 (document on file with the author).

  54. Lucian A. Bebchuk, ‘A Rent-Protection Theory of Corporate Ownership and Control’, Harvard Law School John M. Olin Center for Law, Economics and Business Discussion Paper Series, Paper 260, available at: <http://lsr.nellco.org/harvard_olin/260>: Private benefits might be also nonpecuniary. Control might provide larger such benefits to the controller when the controller founded the firm, when control of the firm has always resided with the controller’s family, or when control of the firm provides the controller with prestige. Thus, other things equal, antitakeover charter arrangements should be more common in such situations. See also Coates IV, supra n. 23 at p. 692, reporting: [I]n high technology companies, … part of the incentive for innovators is their sense of ownership over the technology itself, in all its possible uses (or, more often, from their perspective, misuses), and the initial innovators are very plausibly the highest-valuing owners of the rights to dispose of technology they have created.

  55. See Gilson, supra n. 55, at p. 828.

  56. Bebchuk, supra n. 25, at p. 11. See also Rejie George and Rezaul Kabir, ‘Business Groups and Profit Redistribution: A Boon or Bane for Firms?’, 61 Journal of Business Research (2008) p. 1004, at p. 1012 (‘The analysis shows that group-affiliated firms perform poorly relative to independent firms’); Sung Wook Joh, ‘Corporate Governance and Profitability: Evidence from Korea Before the Economic Crisis’, 68 Journal of Financial Economics (2003) p. 287, at p. 318, using a sample of 5,829 Korean firms subject to outside auditing during 1993–1997, he found evidence that: [f]irms with lower controlling family ownership or higher differences between control rights and ownership rights showed lower performance.… In addition, Korean firms affiliated with business groups in the mid-1990s showed lower profitability than independent firms did. See also An Buysschaert, Marc Deloof, Marc Jegers and An Rommens, ‘Is Group Affiliation Profitable in Developed Countries? Belgian Evidence’, 16 Corporate Governance: An International Review (2008) p. 504, at p. 514, who, using a sample that includes 247 group companies, belonging to 16 different Belgian groups, found that: [t]he results for net income/total assets confirm the findings … that (1) group companies are significantly less profitable than stand-alone companies; (2) group companies have more volatile profits than stand-alone companies; and (3) receiving group financing is negatively related to the profitability of group companies.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  57. Martin Holmén and Peter Högfeldt, ‘Pyramidal Discounts: Tunneling or Agency Costs?’, 9 International Review of Finance (2009) p. 133, at p. 172 (corporate pyramids tend ‘to systematically overinvest since they have access to a relatively inexpensive source of capital with lower and softer return requirements than the external capital markets’). See also Abe De Jong, Douglas V. DeJong, Ulrich Hege and Gerard Mertens, ‘Leverage in Pyramids: When Debt Leads to Higher Dividends’, ECGI — Finance Working Paper No. 261/2009 (2010), at p. 8, available at: <http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1461492> (finding that, when the holding company is highly leveraged, the ‘dividend payouts [necessary to repay the controller’s debt] may exceed the efficient payout level for the bottom company’).

    Article  Google Scholar 

  58. Enriques, supra n. 37, at p. 507.

  59. Simon Johnson, Rafael La Porta, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes and Andrei Shleifer, ‘Tunneling’, 90 American Economic Review (2000) p. 22. See also Vladimir Atanasov, Bernard Black and Conrad S. Ciccotello, ‘Law and Tunneling’, 37 Journal of Corporation Law (2011) p. 1, at p. 13 (‘[P]yramidal and circular ownership structures … provide both incentives and opportunities for the controller to tunnel profits up to the top level of the pyramid’); Jae-Seung Baek, Jun-Koo Kang and Inmoo Lee, ‘Business Groups and Tunneling: Evidence from Private Securities Offerings by Korean Chaebols’, 61 Journal of Finance (2006) p. 2415; Kee-Hong Bae, Jun-Koo Kang and Jin-Mo Kim, ‘Tunneling or Value Added? Evidence from Mergers by Korean Business Groups’, 57 Journal of Finance (2002) p. 2695; Marianne Bertrand, Paras Mehta and Sendhil Mullainathan, ‘Ferreting out Tunneling: An Application to Indian Business Groups’, 117 Quarterly Journal of Economics (2002) p. 121.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  60. Christian Leuz, Karl V. Lins and Francis Warnock, ‘Do Foreigners Invest Less in Poorly Governed Firms?’, 22 Review of Financial Studies (2009) p. 3245, at pp. 3253–3254: Understanding these control structures and the family motives requires intricate social and institutional knowledge, which many foreigners lack or find costly to obtain. As a consequence, firms with potentially problematic governance structures are particularly taxing to foreign investors in terms of their information and monitoring costs.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  61. Ibid., at p. 3246.

  62. See Tatiana Nenova, ‘The Value of Corporate Voting Rights and Control: A Cross-country Analysis’, 68 Journal of Financial Economics (2003) p. 325, at p. 334 (Table 3); Alexander Dyck and Luigi Zingales, ‘Private Benefits of Control: An International Comparison’, 59 Journal of Finance (2004) p. 537.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  63. Holmén and Högfeldt, supra n. 60, at p. 144; Kosenko, supra n. 50, at p. 89 (in Israeli corporate pyramids ‘the financial value of affiliated companies is significantly lower. These findings are indicative of market discounting with respect to affiliated companies’).

  64. Bebchuk, supra n. 25, at p. 18; Randall Morck and Masao Nakamura, ‘Business Groups and the Big Push: Meiji Japan’s Mass Privatization and Subsequent Growth’, 8 Enterprise & Society (2007) p. 543, at p. 548 (‘State orchestrated collusion, protectionism, and ready subsidies limit the competitive pressures on business groups, permitting inefficient operations to survive and compromising economic growth’); Tarun Khanna and Yishay Yafeh, ‘Business Groups in Emerging Markets: Paragons or Parasites?’, 45 Journal of Economic Literature (2007) p. 331, at p. 359 (‘[A]s business groups accumulate political and economic influence, the nature of their relations with government tends to change — from government protégés to a strong lobby with often captured regulators’); Randall Morck, Daniel Wolfenzon and Bernard Yeung, ‘Economic Entrenchment and Growth’, 43 Journal of Economic Literature (2005) p. 655, at p. 657 (‘[E]ntrusting the governance of huge slices of a country’s corporate sector to a tiny elite can bias capital allocation, retard capital market development, obstruct entry by outsider entrepreneurs, and retard growth’).

  65. Bebchuk, supra n. 25, at p. 18; see Morck, Wolfenzon and Yeung, supra n. 67, at pp. 693–699.

  66. Paul Rosenstein-Rodan, ‘Problems of Industrialisation of Eastern and South-Eastern Europe’, 53 Economic Journal (1943) p. 202.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  67. Morck and Nakamura, supra n. 67, at p. 547; Morck, supra n. 27.

  68. Ronald W. Masulis, Peter K. Pham and Jason Zein, ‘Family Business Groups Around the World: Financing Advantages, Control Motivations, and Organizational Choices’, 24 Review of Financial Studies (2011) p. 3556, at p. 3572; Stijn Claessens, Joseph P.H. Fan and Larry H.P. Lang, ‘The Benefits and Costs of Group Affiliation: Evidence from East Asia’, 7 Emerging Markets Review (2006) p. 1, at p. 23; Tarun Khanna and Krishna Palepu, ‘Is Group Affiliation Profitable in Emerging Markets? An Analysis of Diversified Indian Business Groups’, 55 Journal of Finance (2000) p. 867, at p. 887 (their ‘research suggests that the most diversified business groups add value by replicating the functions of institutions that are missing in … emerging market’); Tarun Khanna and Jan W. Rivkin, ‘Estimating the Performance Effects of Business Groups in Emerging Markets’, 22 Strategic Management Journal (2001) p. 45, at p. 68 (using ‘data from 14 emerging markets in Asia, Latin America and South Africa [they] find that business groups affiliates earn higher accounting profits than do otherwise comparable unaffiliated firms’).

  69. Gilson, supra n. 19, at p. 636.

  70. See Joh, supra n. 59, at p. 318 (‘As the economy develops, the potential benefits of overcoming these market imperfections decreases while the cost of agency problems and conflicts of interest between controlling family shareholders and minority shareholders can increase’); Masulis, Pham and Zein, supra n. 71, at p. 3589, note 39 (‘[I]n an unreported test, [they] find that the valuation discount of group firms is actually lower in emerging markets than in developed markets’).

  71. See supra n. 59.

  72. Lucian A. Bebchuk, Interim Report Prepared for the Committee on Increasing Competitiveness in the Economy (9 October 2011), at p. 13, available at: <http://www.law.harvard.edu/faculty/bebchuk/Policy/Bebchuk-Shani-Report.pdf> (‘If controllers continue holding their large groups using other people’s money, but switch from outside equity financing to outside debt financing, leverage levels would rise above their current high levels, exacerbating systemic risk concerns’).

  73. Stijn Claessens, Simeon Djankov, Joseph P. H. Fan and Larry H. P. Lang, ‘Disentangling the Incentive and Entrenchment Effects of Large Shareholdings’, 57 Journal of Finance (2002) p. 2741, at p. 2744 (using a sample of East Asian corporations).

    Article  Google Scholar 

  74. Institutional Shareholder Services, Sherman & Sterling and the European Corporate Governance Institute, supra n. 24, at p. 85. According to this survey the first and the second most negative CEMs are: (i) ‘priority shares’ (−0.66) (i.e., shares that ‘grant their holders specific powers of decision or veto rights in a company, irrespective of the proportion of their equity stake’); and (ii) ‘golden shares’ (-0.64) (i.e., ‘priority shares issued for the benefit of governmental authorities’).

  75. Stephen M. Bainbridge, ‘The Short Life and Resurrection of Rule 19c-4’, 69 Washington University Law Quarterly (1991) p. 565.

    Google Scholar 

  76. Bus. Roundtable v. SEC, 905 F.2d 406 (D.C. 1990).

  77. See William T. Allen, Reiner Kraakman and Guhan Subramanian, Commentaries and Cases on the Law of Business Organization (Wolters Kluwer 2012), at p. 187; Smart, Thirumalai and Zutter, supra n. 53, at p. 95; Edward Rock, ‘Securities Regulation as Lobster Trap: A Credible Commitment Theory of Mandatory Disclosure’, 23 Cardozo Law Review (2002) p. 675, at p. 698; Stephen M. Bainbridge, ‘The Scope of the SEC’s Authority over Shareholder Voting Rights’, UCLA School of Law Research Paper No. 07-16 (2007), at p. 8, available at: <http://ssrn.com.ezp-prod1.hul.harvard.edu/abstract=985707> (‘Specifically, SEC Chairman Arthur Levitt successfully pressured the three principal domestic securities exchanges — NYSE, AMEX, and NASDAQ — to adopt a uniform voting rights policy essentially tracking Rule 19c-4’).

    Google Scholar 

  78. See Gilson, supra n. 55, at p. 834; Jeffrey N. Gordon, ‘Ties That Bond: Dual Class Common Stock and the Problem of Shareholder Choice’, 76 California Law Review (1988) p. 1, at p. 40 (noting that before the amendment of the NYSE, AMEX and NASDAQ listing requirements ‘[i]n most cases this super-voting stock receive[d] reduced dividends, most commonly, 10% less than [was] paid to limited-voting stock. … After the new class of common [was] authorized, the firm conduct[ed] a one-time exchange offer, in which shareholders may exchange their ordinary common for the super-voting common, typically on a one-for-one ratio.’); Allen, Kraakman and Subramanian, supra n. 80, at p. 187.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  79. The same reasoning explains why — unlike the multiple voting rights shares — non-voting or limited-voting shares can be issued (but not exchanged) in ‘mid-stream’. In this case, the issuance of the new class of shares is not coercive, because the insiders cannot exploit the collective action problem.

  80. See Alessio Pacces, Rethinking Corporate Governance: The Law and Economics of Control Powers (Routledge 2012), at p. 210: One or more layers could be added on top of the pyramid, thereby diluting the controller’s ownership stake in any lower layer. Minority shareholders of existing layers cannot but be harmed by such a strategy; but again they are powerless. In contrast, new outside investors are more easily found on top rather than at the bottom of a pyramid.

  81. Klaus Busch, Christoph Hermann, Karl Hinrichs and Thorsten Schulten, ‘Euro Crisis, Austerity Policy and the European Social Model. How Crisis Policies in Southern Europe Threaten the EU’s Social Dimension’ (2013), at p. 22, available at: <http://library.fes.de/pdf-files/id/ipa/09656.pdf> (‘In Greece and Portugal, the granting of ESM [the European Stability Mechanism] loans was linked to extensive privatization. Spain and Italy have also announced far-reaching privatizations under pressure from the ECB and international institutions’); Laura Cabeza-García and Silvia Gómez-Ansón, ‘Post-privatization Ownership Concentration: Determinants and Influence on Firm Efficiency’, 39 Journal of Comparative Economics (2011) p. 412: Privatization became a priority on government agendas in the past few decades and remains of high importance despite the current global financial crisis. In fact, European countries such as Poland, Greece, Portugal and Spain are stepping up their divestment programs, in search of greater revenue to help reduce fiscal deficits.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  82. See Poste Italiane S.p.A. Financial Statement 2013, available at: <http://www.posteitaliane.post/resources/english/editoriali/pdf/Annual_results_for_the_year_ended_31_december_2013.pdf>.

  83. See Ferrovie dello Stato S.p.A. Financial Statement 2013, available at: <http://www.fsitaliane.it/cms-file/allegati/fsitaliane_en/Investor-relations/17_04_2014_Summary_of_the_annual_Financial_Results_for_2013.pdf>.

  84. See Enav S.p.A. Annual Report 2012, available at: <http://www.enav.it/portal/page/portal/PortaleENAV/Home_EN/Comunicazione_EN?CurrentPath=/enav/en/comunication/news/news_archive/annual_report>.

  85. See Rachel Sanderson, ‘Italy Set to Launch Privatization Drive with Fincantieri Listing’, Financial Times, 5 May 2014, available at: <http://www.ft.com/intl/cms/s/0/b7bfe22a-d462-11e3-a122-00144feabdc0.html#axzz32lnmzsZA>; Guy Dinmore and Rachel Sanderson, ‘Italy Launches Big Privatization Push’, Financial Times, 26 January 2014, available at: <http://www.ft.com/intl/cms/s/0/d3ff8c8c-8454-11e3-9710-00144feab7de.html#axzz2wduPMWGI> (‘Italy’s coalition government has embarked on what it calls its largest privatization program since the late 1990s with a plan to raise €12bn’); Christopher Emsden, ‘Italy to Privatize $16 Billion of Assets’, Wall Street Journal, 21 November 2013, available at: <http://online.wsj.com/news/articles/ SB10001424052702304791704579211751435589712>; Paolo Festuccia, ‘Poste, Ferrovie e Fincantieri, l’obiettivo è incassare 10 miliardi’, La Stampa, 24 March 2014, available at: <http://www.lastampa.it/2014/03/23/economia/poste-ferrovie-e-fincantieri-lobiettivo-incassare-miliardi-2MiuYbpX1ZVr1y62qaQr3O/pagina.html>; Laura Serafini, ‘Avanti su Poste, Fincantieri e Ferrovie’, Il Sole 24 Ore, 24 March 2014, available at: <http://www.ilsole24ore.com/art/notizie/2014-03-23/avanti-poste-fincantieri-e-ferrovie-081722.shtml?uuid=>.

  86. Jeannette Neumann, ‘Spain Launches Privatization of Bankia, Wall Street Journal, 27 February 2014, available at: <http://online.wsj.com/articles/SB10001424052702304071004579409233996132914>; Charles Penty, ‘Spain Starts Sale of Bankia to Recoup Bailout Funding’, Bloomberg, 28 February 2014, available at: <http://www.bloomberg.com/news/2014-02-27/spain-starts-sale-of-7-5-stake-in-nationalized-lender-bankia.html>.

  87. David Roman and Ana Garcìa, ‘Spanish Airport Operator Aena Eyes IPO This Year’, Wall Street Journal, 7 March 2014, available at: <http://online.wsj.com/news/articles/SB10001424052702304554004579425080790134214>; Tobias Buck, ‘Spain to Sell 49% of Airports Group Aena’, Financial Times, 13 June 2014, available at: <http://www.ft.com/intl/cms/s/0/bd8f885e-f307-11e3-85cd-00144feabdc0.html>.

  88. Angeliki Koutantou, ‘Greece to Meet 2013 Asset Sales Target, Upbeat on 2014 Plan: Privatization Chief, Reuters, 16 December 2013, available at: <http://www.reuters.com/article/2013/12/16/us-greece-privatisation-idUSBRE9BF0Y920131216> (‘Greece is aiming at total privatization proceeds of about 24 billion euros by 2020 to cut its debt, which is seen exceeding 175 percent of GDP this year, and to kick-start its austerity-hit economy as part of its 240-billion euro international bailout’); B. Bortolotti, ‘The Proposer’s Opening Remarks’, in ‘Privatisation: Opening Statements’, The Economist, 4 February 2014, available at: <http://www.economist.com/debate/days/view/1062>.

  89. Consob, supra n. 38, at p. 3 (Table 1.2) (the Consob report considers publicly held ‘[c]ompanies neither controlled by a single shareholder … nor by a shareholders’ agreement with a free float higher than 70 percent of the ordinary shares’).

  90. Faccio and Lang, supra n. 34, at p. 379; La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes and Shleifer, supra n. 26, at pp. 492–495; Panayotis Kapopoulos and Sophia Lazaretou, ‘Corporate Ownership Structure and Firm Performance: Evidence from Greek Firms’, 15 Corporate Governance: An International Review (2007) p. 144, at p. 156.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  91. Nenova, supra n. 65, at p. 334; Dyck and Zingales, supra n. 65, at p. 551.

  92. See supra section 2.2.

  93. Mark J. Roe, Political Determinants of Corporate Governance: Political Context, Corporate Impact (Oxford University Press 2003).

  94. Skadden, Arps, Slate, Meagher & Flom LLP, ‘Europe M&A: The Evolving Takeover Landscape’, 25 February 2013, available at: <http://www.skadden.com/sites/default/files/publications/Europe_MandA_The_Evolving_Takeover_Landscape.pdf>. 98 Bianchi and Bianco, supra n. 34, at p. 11.

  95. Michele Meoli, Stefano Paleari and Giovanni Urga, ‘When Controlling Shareholders Live Like Kings. The Case of Telecom Italia’ (24 January 2006), available at: <http://ssrn.com.ezp-prod1.hul.harvard.edu/abstract=883655>.

  96. John Tagliabue, ‘Move by Olivetti Backfires with Sotck Traders’, New York Times, 1 October 1999, available at: <http://www.nytimes.com/1999/10/01/business/international-business-move-by-olivetti-backfires-with-stock-traders.html>.

  97. Paul Maidment, ‘Pirelli, Benetton Team up to Grab Olivetti’, Forbes, 27 July 2001, available at: <http://www.forbes.com/2001/07/30/0730telecomitalia_print.html> (noting that Mr Tronchetti Provera was ‘effectively gaining control of Italy’s leading industrial group, with a stock market capitalization of 55 billion euros, for 7 billion euros in cash’); Greg Burke, ‘All in the Families’, Time Magazine, 13 August 2001, available at: <http://www.time.com/time/magazine/article/0,9171,170116,00.html#ixzz2QHSAb16P>: By keeping their share of Olivetti under 30%, Pirelli [a company controlled by Mr. Tronchetti Provera] and Benetton [one of his allies] were not obliged to offer the buy-out to all investors. Minority shareholders are understandably furious, especially since Olivetti dropped 15.3% the first day after the deal.

  98. Luca Enriques and Paolo Volpin, ‘Corporate Governance Reforms in Continental Europe’, 21 Journal of Economic Perspectives (2007) p. 117, at p. 121.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  99. Bebchuk, supra n. 57, at p. 37 (‘When control is valuable, leaving it up for grabs will invite attempts to grab it and will not constitute an equilibrium’).

  100. As already mentioned above, this result can be achieved by acquiring a participation in the share capital of the target company which is just below the threshold provided for the application of the mandatory bid rule. See supra n. 96.

  101. See supra section 4.2.1.

  102. See Leuz, Lins and Warnock, supra n. 63, at pp. 3253–3254.

  103. See supra n. 10.

  104. Gilson, supra n. 19, at p. 653; Rafael La Porta, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, Andrei Shleifer and Robert W. Vishny, ‘Investor Protection and Corporate Governance’, 58 Journal of Financial Economics (2000) p. 3, at p. 21 (‘What the reformers see as protection of investors, the founding families call “expropriation of entrepreneurs”. No wonder, then, that in all countries — from Latin America to Asia to Europe — the families have opposed legal reform’); Lucian A. Bebchuk and Zvika Neeman, ‘Investor Protection and Interest Group Politics’, 23 Review of Financial Studies (2010) p. 1089 (they identify several ‘factors that push toward suboptimal investor protection, including corporate insiders’ ability to use public firms’ assets to influence politicians, and institutional investors’ inability to capture fully the value of investor protection for outside investors’); Gerhard Schnyder, ‘Varieties of Insider Corporate Governance: The Determinants of Business Preferences and Governance Reform in the Netherlands, Sweden and Switzerland’, 19 Journal of European Public Policy (2012) p. 1434, at p. 1447: While electoral pressures may push parties to cater for the needs of minority shareholders where these constitute a large part of the electorate, the preferences of the business élite constitute a second channel through which ownership structures influence the politics of corporate governance reforms. Which one of these pressures ultimately prevails is an empirical question which depends on additional variables, such as the power and preferences of centre-left parties, the salience of an issue and the intensity of business lobbying.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  105. See Communication from the Commission to the Council and the European Parliament, ‘Modernising Company Law and Enhancing Corporate Governance in the European Union — A Plan to Move Forward’, Brussels, 21 May 2003, COM(2003) 284 final, at p. 14; Report of the High-Level Group of Company Law Experts on Issues Related to Takeover Bids, Brussels, 10 January 2002; Tobias Buck, ‘EU to Endorse “One-share, One-vote” Principle’, Financial Times, 16 October 2005, available at: <http://www.ft.com/intl/cms/s/0/2f2a10c0-13cb-11dc-9866-000b5df10621.html#axzz2QJ6ajbPU> (reporting that Charlie McCreevy — the EU Internal Market Commissioner — publicly said: ‘It is my goal to get the one-share, one-vote principle accepted across the 25 member states’).

  106. Schnyder, supra n. 108, at p. 1445; ‘Keeping Shareholders in Their Place: Bosses Around the World Celebrate a Series of Victories over Shareholder Activists’, The Economist, 11 October 2007, available at: <http://www.economist.com/node/9961252> (the European Commission had to abandon the proposed reform mainly because of the strong opposition of lobbyists for big shareholders such as Sweden’s Wallenberg family, which uses special shares to retain control of the dynasty’s businesses); André Nilsen, ‘The EU Takeover Directive and the Competitiveness of European Industry’, The Oxford Council on Good Governance, OCGG Analysis, No. 1 (2004), at p. 4 (reporting that the proposal for ‘expanding the scope of Article 11 [of the EU Takeover Directive] to outlaw multiple classes of common stock carrying different voting rights’ was abandoned ‘[f]ollowing intense lobbying by the Wallenberg family and the rest of the Swedish establishment in 2003’).

  107. Bank of Israel Annual Report 2009 (Jerusalem, 2010), at p. 174, available at: <http://www.boi.org.il/en/NewsAndPublications/RegularPublications/Documents/Doch2009/pe_4.pdf>.

  108. Bebchuk, supra n. 75, at pp. 9–10.

  109. Ibid., at p. 10.

  110. Ibid., at p. 8.

  111. Ibid., at p. 11.

  112. Among the opponents of the proposals contained in the Interim Report were Professors Ronald J. Gilson and Alan Schwartz, who had been retained by Israeli corporate groups Norstar Holdings Inc., Gazit Globe Ltd. and Alony Hetz Properties & Investments Ltd. to write a divergent report that highlights the possible drawbacks of Bebchuk’s solutions and in which they propose to contrast the agency costs created by Israeli pyramids by strengthening the ex post judicial review; and Professor William T. Allen, who had also been asked by the Association of Publicly Traded Companies to review the Interim Report. See Gilson and Schwartz, supra n. 21; Allen, supra n. 56.

  113. The Committee on Increasing Competitiveness in the Economy, Final Recommendations and Supplement to the Interim Report (18 March 2012), at p. 14, available at: <http://www.israeltrade.org.au/final-recommendations-and-expert-opinions-of-the-committee-on-increasing-competitiveness-in-the-economy>.

  114. Bebchuk, supra n. 25, at pp. 21–25.

  115. Ibid., at p. 24.

  116. See Freshfields Bruckhaus Deringer LLP, ‘Israel Passes Landmark Legislation Aimed at Breaking up Conglomerates’, available at: <http://www.freshfields.com/uploadedFiles/SiteWide/Knowledge/Israel%20concentration%20law.pdf>; David Shamah, ‘New Law Makes Business “Pyramids” History’, Times of Israel, 10 December 2013, available at: <http://www.timesofisrael.com/new-law-makes-business-pyramids-history>.

  117. See Kandel, Kosenko, Morck and Yafeh, supra n. 29 (‘[I]n developed democracies, the dominant factor that delays the implementation of reform measures is extended legal battles, especially in cases where regulatory changes are perceived as infringing on property rights and other fundamental freedoms. This was certainly the case in the United States in the 1930s and 1940s’).

  118. Bebchuk, supra n. 25, at p. 18.

  119. Steven Davidoff, ‘Overhaul of Israel Economy Offers Lessons for United States, Int. New York Times, 7 January 2014, available at: <http://dealbook.nytimes.com/2014/01/07/overhaul-of-israels-economy-offers-lessons-for-united-states/?_php=true&_type=blogs&_php=true&_type=blogs&_r=1> (reporting that ‘a furious battle broke out as the big pyramids hired a slew of lobbyists and law firms to persuade lawmakers to either kill the bill or remove their own pyramid from its strictures’). See also Guy Rolnik, ‘Could Judge Kabub Be the Great Reformer of the Israeli Finance System?’, Haaretz, 25 September 2014, available at: <http://www.haaretz.com/business/premium-1.617219>.

  120. See Case C-127/97 Centros Ltd. v. Erhvervs-og Selskabsstyrelsen [1999] ECR I-1459; Case C-208/00 Überseering B.V. v. Nordic Construction Baumanagement GmbH [NCC] [2002] ECR I-9919; Case C-167/01 Kamer van Koophandel en Fabrieken voor Amsterdam v. Inspire Art Ltd. [2003] ECR I-10155; Case C-210/06 Cartesio Oktató Szoláltató bt [2008] ECR I-9641. See also Wolf-Georg Ringe, ‘Corporate Mobility in the European Union — A Flash in the Pan? An Empirical Study on the Success of Lawmaking and Regulatory Competition’, 10 European Company and Financial Law Review (2013) p. 230, at pp. 235–236: The Centros case law has had a significant impact on company activity in Europe. With every free movement judgment handed down from Luxembourg, enterprises became increasingly assured that the freedom of establishment indeed allowed them to register in Member State A, while conducting their business exclusively in Member State B. In this manner, the Court of Justice has created a market for corporate forms within the European Union, granting de facto a choice between the legal forms of Member States.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  121. In these two countries, for example, insiders can use both corporate pyramids and multiple voting rights shares to secure their control over the company. See Institutional Shareholder Services, Sherman & Sterling and the European Corporate Governance Institute, supra n. 24.

  122. Ronald J. Gilson, Henry Hansmann and Mariana Pargendler, ‘Regulatory Dualism as a Development Strategy: Corporate Reform in Brazil, the U.S. and the EU’, 63 Stanford Law Review (2011) p. 475, at p. 478.

    Google Scholar 

  123. Ibid., at pp. 482–486.

  124. Ibid., at p. 486; Bernard S. Black, Antonio Gledson De Carvalho and Joelson Oliveira Sampaio, ‘The Evolution of Corporate Governance in Brazil’, Northwestern Law & Economics Research Paper No. 12-22 (2012), available at: <http://ssrn.com.ezp-prod1.hul.harvard.edu/abstract=2181039>.

  125. Black, Gledson De Carvalho and Oliveira Sampaio, supra n. 130, at p. 5; Gilson, Hansmann and Pargendler, supra n. 128, at p. 489.

  126. Gilson, Hansmann and Pargendler, supra n. 128, at p. 495.

  127. If the state owns just a controlling block of a listed firm, and the ‘equal opportunity’ rule does not apply, the private placement of the participation will usually create more value than the dispersion of the stock in the market, because the seller receives the controlling premium without sharing this value with outside investors. In this scenario, since this premium is closely related to the private benefit of control that the buyer can extract, in order to maximise the price received, it would be better for the seller to avoid any improvement of outside shareholders rights. Therefore, firms that are controlled by the state and could be sold at a higher price through private placement should not be listed in the new market with improved corporate governance standards.

  128. In 2012, only 279 Italian companies were listed on the Milan stock exchange, while in Frankfurt 665 German companies were listed, in Paris 862 French companies and in London 2,179 British companies. In the same year, the market capitalisation divided by the GDP was only 23.9% in Italy, while in the UK this was 124%, in France 69.8% and in Germany 43.7%. These numbers are particularly impressive if we consider that, according to Assonime (Association of Italian Companies), more than one thousand Italian companies already have the characteristics required for listing on a stock market but prefer to remain private. In Portugal and Greece, the market capitalisation divided by the GDP is also considerably low (30.8 in Portugal and 17.9 in Greece in 2012), while Spain is the only economy among the GIPS with a relatively developed capital market (73.7% of GDP in 2012). See data available on the World Bank website: <http://data.worldbank.org/indicator/CM.MKT.LCAP.GD.ZS/countries/1W?display=default>; Luigi Abete, ‘Audizione del Presidente dell’Assonime: Indagine Conoscitiva sui Mercati degli Strumenti Finanziari’ (3 May 2011), available at: <http://www.assonime.it/AssonimeWeb2/servletAllegati?numero=3772>.

  129. Bernard S. Black and Ronald J. Gilson, ‘Venture Capital and the Structure of Capital Markets: Banks Versus Stock Markets’, 47 Journal of Financial Economics (1998) p. 243, at p. 245: Other countries have openly envied the U.S. venture capital market and have actively, but unsuccessfully, sought to replicate it. We offer an explanation for this failure: We argue that a well developed stock market that permits venture capitalists to exit through an initial public offering (IPO) is critical to the existence of a vibrant venture capital market.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  130. Bebchuk, supra n. 75, at p. 11.

  131. On the possible use of equity derivatives in order to separate investors’ voting rights from their ultimate economic exposure in the same firm, see Henry T. C. Hu and Bernard Black, ‘The New Vote Buying: Empty Voting and Hidden (Morphable) Ownership’, 79 Southern California Law Review (2006) p. 811; Henry T.C. Hu and Bernard Black, ‘Equity and Debt Decoupling and Empty Voting II: Importance and Extensions’, 156 University of Pennsylvania Law Review (2008) p. 625.

    Google Scholar 

  132. In Italy, the Investor Protection Act (Legge sul Risparmio), introduced in 2005, requires all listed companies to adopt a voto di lista mechanism that allows minority shareholders to elect at least one member of the board. In Spain and in Portugal, the adoption of mechanisms similar to the voto di lista is authorised but not required. See, for Italy, Article 147-ter of the Financial Markets Consolidated Act (Testo Unico della Finanza) as amended in 2005; for Spain, Article 137 of the Anonimous Companies Act (Ley de Sociedades anonimas, Royal Legislative Decree 1564/1989); see also Simone Alvaro, Giovanni Mollo and Giovanni Siciliano, ‘Il voto di lista per la rappresentanza di azionisti di minoranza nell’organo di amministrazione delle società quotate’ (2012), Consob, Quaderni Giuridici, at pp. 16–17, available at: <http://www.consob.it/main/consob/pubblicazioni/studi_analisi/quaderni_giuridici/qg1.html>.

  133. Among other European countries, Denmark, Finland, Poland, Sweden and the Netherlands allow the issuance of multiple voting rights shares. See Institutional Shareholder Services, Sherman & Sterling and the European Corporate Governance Institute, supra n. 24.

  134. See supra section 4.3.

  135. As an example of CEMs that provide for additional votes for certain shareholders, see the ‘loyalty shares’, which have been permitted in France for a long time and have recently been introduced also in Italy. This CEM grants up to two votes per share to those shareholders who request registration of their shares in a special register and have continuously held these shares for at least two years. In both countries, this CEM can be adopted even following the IPO of the company, despite the fact that it provides a clear advantage to the incumbent controlling shareholders to the detriment of minority investors. As for France, see L.225-123 of the Code de Commerce. See also Simone Alvari, Angela Ciavarella, Doina D’Eramo and Nadia Linciano, ‘La deviazione dal principio “un’azione — un voto”’ (2014), Consob, Quaderni Giuridici, available at: <http://www.consob.it/main/consob/pubblicazioni/studi_analisi/quaderni_giuridici/qg5.html> (reporting that more than half of the CAC40 companies — i.e., the 40 French companies with the highest free float market capitalisation — have taken advantage of this CEM); Koen Greens and Carl Clottens, ‘One Share One Vote: Fairness, Efficiency and EU Harmonization Revisited’, in Koen Geens and Klaus J. Hopt, eds., The European Company Law Action Plan Revisited: Reassessment of the 2003 Priorities of the European Commission (Leuven University Press 2010) p. 145, at p. 175. As for Italy, see Article 127-quinquies of Italian Legislative Decree No. 58 of 24 February 1998, as amended by Law Decree No. 91, dated 24 June 2014, converted into Law No. 116, dated 11 August 2014.

  136. Simeon Djankov, Rafael La Porta, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes and Andrei Shleifer, ‘The Law and Economics of Self-dealing’, 88 Journal of Financial Economics (2008) p. 430.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  137. Andrei Shleifer and Robert W. Vishny, ‘A Survey of Corporate Governance’, 52 Journal of Finance (1997) p. 737, at p. 760.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  138. Louis D. Brandeis, Other People’s Money and How the Bankers Use It (Augustus Kelley, ed., 1971) (1914), at p. 92. The importance of disclosure in related party transactions has also been recognised by the European Commission, which, in a recent proposal to amend the Shareholders Rights Directive, recommended requiring that ‘in case of transactions with related parties that represent more than 1% of their assets, [companies] publicly announce such transactions at the time of the conclusion of the transaction, and accompany the announcement by a report from an independent third party assessing whether or not it is on market terms and confirming that the transaction is fair and reasonable from the perspective of the shareholders, including minority shareholders’. See European Commission, Proposal for a Directive of the European Parliament and of the Council amending Directive 2007/36/EC as regards the encouragement of long-term shareholder engagement and Directive 2013/34/EU as regards certain elements of the corporate governance statement, COM(2014) 213, at p. 24, available at: <http://eur-lex.europa.eu/legal-content/EN/TXT/PDF/?uri=CELEX:52014PC0213&from=EN>.

  139. In Italy, Consob Regulation 17221 on Related Party Transactions, introduced in 2010, has already substantially improved the corporate governance rules on this issue. However, Italian listed companies still enjoy some degree of freedom in ‘opting up’ or ‘opting down’ from some of the default rules provided in the new regulation. In this case, the new market should restrict the companies’ freedom to ‘opt down’ from the default rules and require the adoption of the strictest procedures aimed at avoiding tunneling through related-parties transactions. See Magda Bianchi, Angela Ciavarella, Luca Enriques, Valerio Novembre and Rossella Signoretti, ‘Regulation and Self-regulation of Related Party Transactions in Italy’ (2014), Consob, Quaderni Giuridici, available at: <http://www.consob.it/main/consob/pubblicazioni/studi_analisi/quaderni_finanza/qdf75.html>. See also the proposal of the European Commission to require that Member States ‘ensure that transactions with related parties representing more than 5% of the companies’ assets or transactions which can have a significant impact on profits or turnover are submitted to a vote by the shareholders in a general meeting’. See European Commission, supra n. 145, at pp. 24–25.

  140. Lucian Bebchuk and Assaf Hamdani, ‘Vigorous Race or Leisurely Walk: Reconsidering the Competition over Corporate Charters’, 112 Yale Law Journal (2002) p. 553, at p. 567 (reporting that at the end of 1999, 3,771 of 6,530 US public companies were incorporated in Delaware).

    Article  Google Scholar 

  141. Ronald J. Gilson, Charles Sabel and Robert E. Scott, ‘Contract and Innovation: The Limited Role of Generalist Courts’, 88 New York University Law Review (2013) p. 170, at pp. 207–208: The specialization of the [Delaware] court together with its equitable powers assure parties that, despite the impossibility of codifying particularized decision rules, judicial decisions will be taken with the fullest possible awareness of current and evolving understandings of good practice.

    Google Scholar 

  142. A study conducted by Professors La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes, Shleifer and Vishny measured the efficiency of judicial systems across several legal systems. From this study it emerges that, while the United States, the United Kingdom, Japan, Switzerland and other developed economies receive the highest score (i.e., 10 points), the GIPS’ judicial systems receive much worse evaluations (i.e., Italy 6.75, Spain 6.25, Portugal 5.5 and Greece 7.00). See Rafael La Porta, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, Andrei Shleifer and Robert W. Vishny, ‘Law and Finance’, 106 Journal of Political Economy (1998) p. 113, at pp. 142–143 (Table 5). More recently, another study, realised in June 2013, ranked 189 countries’ efficiency in enforcing contracts. Even in that study, the GIPS performed considerably worse (i.e., Italy 103rd, Spain 59th, Portugal 24th and Greece 98th) than other developed economies, such as the United States (11th). See Doing Business 2013, data available at: <http://www.doingbusiness.org/data/exploretopics/enforcing-contracts>.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  143. Guido Ferrarini and Paolo Guidici, ‘Financial Scandals and the Role of Private Enforcement: The Parmalat Case’, in John Armour and Joseph A. McCahery, eds., After Enron: Improving Corporate Law and Modernising Securities Regulation (Hart Publishing 2006) p. 158, at p. 194; Gianluca Esposito, Sergi Lanau and Sebastiaan Pompe, ‘Judicial System Reform in Italy — A Key to Growth’, IMF Working Paper No. 14/32 (February 2014), at p. 14, available at: <http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2407525##> (reaching the conclusion that ‘[t]he performance of Italy’s judicial system is below European averages in many respects. The weaknesses in the judicial system contribute to Italy’s poor business environment and low growth’).

  144. On the importance of requiring a strong commitment from the listed firms to comply with the high standards of corporate governance imposed by the new market, see Rock, supra n. 80: [He] argue[s] that the existing SEC system can be understood as providing issuers with a mechanism for making a credible commitment to high quality, comprehensive disclosure for an indefinite period into the future. This credible commitment device is particularly useful to new domestic issuers and to foreign issuers seeking to tap the U.S. capital markets. This credible commitment justification explains the striking but little discussed practical and formal asymmetry between the ease of entry into the SEC system and the difficulty of exit from it.

  145. In case of companies’ mergers — in order to avoid hold-up problems that could jeopardise value-enhancing business combinations — the charter could also provide, as an alternative to the supermajority approval, a positive vote by a majority of the minority investors.

  146. See Gilson, Hansmann and Pargendler, supra n. 128, at p. 492 (‘Persons wishing to delist a firm from the Novo Mercado must first launch a tender offer for the firm’s shares at a price at least equal to their economic value’).

  147. Bebchuk, supra n. 75, at p. 11.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Additional information

This paper is a revised and expanded version of the author’s LLM research paper at Harvard Law School, which was awarded the Victor Brudney Prize in 2013. The author is very grateful for the helpful comments and suggestions from Professors Luca Enriques, Reiner Kraakman, Mark J. Roe and Andrei Shleifer, and from Kobi Kastiel, Jane Bestor and an anonymous referee.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Venezze, F.C. The Costs of Control-enhancing Mechanisms: How Regulatory Dualism Can Create Value in the Privatisation of State-owned Firms in Europe. Eur Bus Org Law Rev 15, 499–544 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1017/S1566752914001268

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/S1566752914001268

Keywords

Navigation